Chapter 14

The Monetary Approach

Abstract

The monetary approach to open-economy macroeconomics emphasizes the determinants of money demand and money supply. The monetary approach can be analyzed separately for fixed and floating exchange rates. If the exchange rate is fixed then the monetary approach pertains to the balance of payments, and in such a case the approach is called the Monetary Approach to Balance of Payments. In contrast, if exchange rates are floating then the approach explains exchange rate movements and is called the Monetary Approach to Exchange Rates. Both approaches are discussed thoroughly in this chapter, beginning with basic concepts and assumptions and also addressing the policy implications of these models. Sterilization, the offsetting of international reserve flows by central banks that wish to follow an independent monetary policy, is examined in detail, as is sterilized intervention in a floating exchange rate system.

Keywords

Base money; macroeconomics; monetary approach to balance of payments; monetary approach to exchange rates; monetary policy; official settlements balance; open economy; sterilization; sterilized intervention

The basic premise of the monetary approach is that any balance of payments disequilibrium or exchange rate movement is based on a monetary disequilibrium—that is, differences existing between the amount of money people wish to hold and the amount supplied by the monetary authorities. In simple terms, if people demand more money than is being supplied by the central bank, then the excess demand for money would be satisfied by inflows of money from abroad or an appreciation of the currency. On the other hand, if the central bank (the Federal Reserve in the United States) is supplying more money than is demanded, the excess supply of money is eliminated by outflows of money to other countries or a depreciation of the currency. Thus the monetary approach emphasizes the determinants of money demand and money supply. The monetary approach can be analyzed separately for fixed and floating exchange rates. If the exchange rate is fixed, then the monetary approach pertains to the balance of payments. In such a case we call the approach the monetary approach to balance of payments (MABP). In contrast, if exchange rates are floating then the approach explains exchange rate movements and is called the monetary approach to exchange rates (MAER). Both approaches will be discussed in this chapter.

Prior to the monetary approach, it was common to emphasize international trade flows as primary determinants of exchange rates. The traditional approach emphasized the role of exchange rate changes in eliminating international trade imbalances. In this context we should expect countries with current trade surpluses to have appreciating currencies, while countries with trade deficits should have depreciating currencies. It is clear that the world does not work in the simple way just considered. We have seen some instances when countries with trade surpluses have depreciating currencies, while countries with trade deficits have appreciating currencies. This chapter considers an alternative view of the cause of balance of payments disequilibria and exchange rate movements.

Specie-Flow Mechanism

The monetary approach has a long and distinguished history, so the recent popularity of the approach can be viewed as a rediscovery rather than a modern innovation. In fact, the recent literature often makes use of a quote from Of the Balance of Trade, written by David Hume in 1752, to indicate the early understanding of the problem. Hume wrote:

Suppose four-fifths of all the money in Great Britain to be annihilated in one night, and the nation reduced to the same condition, with regard to specie, as in the reigns of the Harrys and Edwards, what would be the consequence? Must not the price of all labor and commodities sink in proportion, and everything be sold as cheap as they were in these ages? What nation could then dispute with us in any foreign market, or pretend to navigate or to sell manufactures at the same price, which to us would afford sufficient profit? In how little time, therefore, must this bring back the money which we had lost, and raise us to the level of all the neighboring nations? Where after we have arrived, we immediately lose the advantage of the cheapness of labor and commodities; and the farther flowing in of money is stopped by our fullness and repletion.

Hume’s analysis is a strict monetary approach to prices and the balance of payments. If England’s money stock suddenly was reduced by four-fifths, we know from principles of economics that the price level would fall dramatically. The falling price level would give England a price advantage over its foreign competitors, so that its exports would rise and its imports fall. As the foreign money (gold in Hume’s day) poured in, England’s money supply would rise and its price level would follow. This process continues until England’s prices reach the levels of its competitors, after which the system is back in equilibrium.

The Monetary Approach

Before turning to the model, we should consider some basic concepts and assumptions. In principles of macroeconomics we learn that the Federal Reserve controls the money supply by altering base money (currency plus commercial bank reserves held against deposits). As base money changes, the lending ability of commercial banks changes. Increases in base money tend to result in an expansion of the money supply, whereas decreases in base money tend to contract the money supply. For our purposes, it is useful to divide base money into domestic and international components. The domestic component of base money is called domestic credit, whereas the remainder is made up of international reserves (money items that can be used to settle international debts, primarily foreign exchange).

The international money flows that respond to excess demands or excess supplies of goods or financial assets at home affect base money and then the money supply. For instance, if a US exporter receives payment in foreign currency, this payment will be presented to a US commercial bank to be converted into dollars and deposited in the exporter’s account. If the commercial bank has no use for the foreign currency, the bank will exchange the foreign currency for dollars with the Federal Reserve (the Fed). The Fed creates new base money to buy the foreign currency by increasing the commercial bank’s reserve deposit with the Fed. Thus, the Fed is accumulating international reserves, and this reserve accumulation brings about an expansion of base money. In the case of an excess supply of money at home, either domestic credit falls to reduce base money, or international reserves will fall in order to lower base money to the desired level.

Now we are ready to construct a simple model of the monetary approach. The usual assumption is that we are analyzing the situation of a small, open economy. A country is defined as “small” when its activities cannot affect the international price of goods or the international interest rate. Openness implies that this country is an active participant in international economic transactions. We could classify nations according to their degree of openness, or the degree to which they depend on international transactions. The United States would be relatively closed, considering the size of the US GDP relative to the value of international trade, whereas Belgium would be relatively open.

A strong assumption of the monetary approach is that there is a stable demand for money. This means that the relationship among money demand, income, and prices does not change significantly over time. Without a stable demand for money, the monetary approach will not provide a useful framework for analysis. We can begin our model by writing the demand for money as

Md=kPY (14.1)

image (14.1)

where Md is the demand for money, P is the domestic price level, Y is real income or wealth, and k is a constant fraction indicating how money demand will change given a change in P or Y. Eq. (14.1) is often stated as “money demand is a function of prices and income,” or “money demand depends on prices and income.” The usual story is that the higher the income, the more money people will hold to buy more goods. The higher the price level, the more money is desired to buy any given quantity of goods. So, the demand for money should rise with an increase in either P or Y.

Letting Ms stand for money supply, R for net international reserves (our official holdings of foreign assets less the foreign official holdings of our assets), and D for domestic credit, we can write the money supply relationship as1

Ms=R+D (14.2)

image (14.2)

Letting P stand for the domestic price level, E for the domestic currency price of foreign currency, and PF for the foreign price level, we can write the law of one price, defined in Chapter 7, Prices, Exchange Rates and Purchasing Power Parity as

P=EPF (14.3)

image (14.3)

Finally, we need the assumption that equilibrium in the money market holds so that money demand equals money supply, or

Md=Ms (14.4)

image (14.4)

The adjustment mechanism that ensures the equilibrium of Eq. (14.4) will vary with the exchange rate regime. With fixed exchange rates, money supply adjusts to money demand through international flows of money via balance of payments imbalances. With flexible exchange rates, money demand will be adjusted to a money supply set by the central bank via exchange rate changes. In the case of a managed float, where theoretically we have floating exchange rates but the central banks intervene to keep exchange rates at desired levels, we have both international money flows and exchange rate changes. All three cases will be analyzed subsequently.

Now, we develop the model in a manner that will allow us to analyze the balance of payments and exchange rates in a monetary framework. We begin by substituting Eq. (14.3) into Eq. (14.1).

Md=kEPFY (14.5)

image (14.5)

Substituting Eqs. (14.5) and (14.2) into (14.4) we obtain

kEPFY=R+D (14.6)

image (14.6)

Finally, we want to discuss Eq. (14.6), money demand and money supply, in terms of percentage changes. Since k is a constant, the change is zero, and thus k drops out of the analysis and we are left with

E^+P^F+Y^=R^+D^ (14.7)

image (14.7)

where the hat (^) over a variable indicates percentage change.2

Since the goal of this analysis is to be able to explain changes in the exchange rate or balance of payments, we should have R^image and E^image on the left-hand side of the equation. Rearranging Eq. (14.7) in this manner gives

R^E^=P^F+Y^D^ (14.8)

image (14.8)

This indicates that the percentage change in net reserves (the balance of payments) minus the percentage change in exchange rates is equal to the foreign inflation rate plus the percentage growth in real income minus the percentage change in domestic credit.

With fixed exchange rates, E^=0image, and we have the MABP. With the exchange rate change equal to zero, the monetary approach Eq. (14.8) simplifies to:

R^=P^F+Y^D^ (14.9)

image (14.9)

At the other extreme, a completely flexible exchange rate with no central bank intervention results in a reserve flow R^image equal zero, because there will not be any changes to reserves. In this case the general Eq. (14.8) is now written for the MAER as

E^=P^F+Y^D^ (14.10)

image (14.10)

The Monetary Approach to the Balance of Payments

We may draw the line in the balance of payments accounts (see chapter: The Balance of Payments for a review of balance of payments concepts) so that the current and private capital accounts are above the line and only those items that directly affect the money supply are below the line. This balance is often referred to as the official settlements balance and refers to net official holdings of gold and foreign exchange, special drawing rights, and changes in reserves at the International Monetary Fund. This allows us to concentrate on the monetary aspects of the balance of payments.

With fixed exchange rates, E^=0image, and we have the MABP. Recall that with the exchange rate change equal to zero, the MABP equation is given in Eq. (14.9). This equation indicates that the change in reserves is equal to the foreign inflation rate, plus the percentage growth of real income, minus the change in domestic credit. Therefore, with fixed exchange rates, an increase in domestic credit with constant prices and income (and thus constant money demand) will lead to a decrease in net international reserves. This means that if the central bank expands domestic credit, creating an excess supply of money, reserves will flow out, or there will be a balance of payments deficit. Conversely, a decrease in domestic credit will lead to an excess demand for money, since money demand is unchanged for a given P^Fimage and Y^image; yet because D is falling, R will increase by the central bank buying up foreign currency injecting domestic currency, to bring money supply equal to money demand.

Given the framework just developed, we can now consider some of the implications and extensions of the monetary approach. First, the assumption of purchasing power parity (PPP) implies that the central bank must make a policy choice between an exchange rate or a domestic price level. Since P=EPF, under fixed exchange rates, E is constant. Therefore, maintaining the pegged value of E implies that the domestic price level will correspond to that of the rest of the world. This is the case in which people discuss imported inflation. If the foreign price level is increasing rapidly, then our price must follow to maintain the fixed E. On the other hand, with flexible rates E is free to vary to whatever level is necessary to clear the foreign exchange market, and so we can choose our domestic rate of inflation independent of the rest of the world. If we select a lower rate of inflation than foreigners do, then PPP suggests that our currency will tend to appreciate. This issue of choosing between the domestic inflation rate or a preferred exchange rate has important economic as well as political implications and is not made without much thought and consultation among central bankers.

We might mention at this point that there are two views of how PPP operates in the short run, and these two views imply a different mechanism of adjustment to a change in the world economy like a change in the foreign price level. One view is that PPP holds strictly, even in the short run. In this case, a change in the foreign price induces an immediate change in the domestic price and a corresponding change in money demand or money supply. The other view is along the lines of the Hume quote cited previously. The idea here is that prices adjust slowly through the balance of payments effects on the money supply. Thus, if foreign prices rise relative to domestic prices, we tend to sell more to foreigners and run a larger balance of trade surplus. Since we gain international reserves from these goods sales, over time our money supply rises and our prices increase until PPP is restored.

The two approaches differ primarily with regard to timing. The first case assumes that PPP holds in the short run because international reserves flow quickly in response to new events and prices adjust quickly to new equilibrium levels. This fast adjustment is supposedly due to an emphasis on the role of financial assets being bought and sold, resulting in international capital flows. Since financial assets are easily bought and sold, it is easy to understand why many believe that PPP should hold in the short run (ignoring any relative price effects, which we are not discussing in this section). The second case also assumes that PPP holds, but only in the long run. This approach emphasizes the role of goods markets in international adjustment. Since goods prices are supposedly slow to adjust, short-run deviations from PPP will occur that give rise to the balance of trade effects previously discussed. The truth most likely lies between these two extremes. It is reasonable to expect goods prices to adjust slowly over time to changing economic conditions, so it may be reasonable to doubt that PPP holds well in the short run. On the other hand, PPP is not strictly dependent on goods markets. To ignore international capital flows is to miss the potential for a faster adjustment than is possible strictly through goods markets.

We can summarize the policy implications of the MABP as follows:

1. Balance of payments disequilibria are essentially monetary phenomena. Thus, countries would not run long-term (or structural, as they are called) deficits if they did not rely so heavily on inflationary money supply growth to finance government spending.

2. Balance of payments disequilibria must be transitory. If the exchange rate remains fixed, eventually the country must run out of reserves by trying to support a continuing deficit.

3. Balance of payments disequilibria can be handled with domestic monetary policy rather than with adjustments in the exchange rate. Devaluation of the currency exchange rate is a substitute for reducing the growth of domestic credit in that devaluation lowers the value of a country’s money relative to the rest of the world (conversely, an appreciation of the currency is a substitute for increasing domestic credit growth). Following any devaluation, if the underlying monetary cause of the devaluation is not corrected, then future devaluations will be required to offset the continued excess supply of the country’s money.

4. Domestic balance of payments will be improved by an increase in domestic income via an increase in money demand, if not offset by an increase in domestic credit.

The Monetary Approach to the Exchange Rate

Thus far we have only discussed the MABP, which is fine for a world with fixed exchange rates or a gold standard. For a world with flexible exchange rates, we have the MAER. The dichotomy between fixed and floating exchange rates is an important one. When exchange rates are fixed between countries, we will observe money flowing between countries to adjust to disequilibrium. With floating exchange rates, the exchange rates are allowed to fluctuate with the free-market forces of supply and demand for each currency. The free-market equilibrium exchange rate occurs at a point where the flow of exports just equals the flow of imports so that no net international money flows are required. International economists refer to this choice of money flows or exchange rate changes as the choice of an international adjustment mechanism. With fixed exchange rates, the adjustment to changes in international monetary conditions comes through international money flows; whereas with floating rates, the adjustment comes through exchange rate changes.

The MAER equation comes directly from Eq. (14.8). A free-market exchange rate means that no central bank intervention takes place, we have R^image equal zero, so the MAER approach becomes:

E^=P^F+Y^D^ (14.11)

image (14.11)

With the MAER, an increase in domestic credit, given a constant P^Fimage and Y^image (so that money demand is constant), will result in E^image increasing. Since E^image is domestic currency units per foreign currency unit, an increase in E^image means that domestic currency is depreciating. Under the MAER, domestic monetary policy will not cause flows of money internationally but will lead to exchange rate changes. The fact that P^Fimage and Y^image have signs opposite that of E^image in Eq. (14.11) indicates that changes in inflation and income growth will cause changes in exchange rates in the opposite direction. For instance, if P^Fimage and/or Y^image increase, we know that money demand increases. With constant domestic credit, we have an excess demand for money. As individuals try to increase their money balances, we observe a decrease in E^image or an appreciation of the domestic currency.

The Monetary Approach for a Managed Floating Exchange Rate

So far, we have discussed the case of fixed or flexible exchange rates, but what is the framework for analysis of a managed float? Remember, a managed float means that although exchange rates are theoretically flexible and determined by the market forces of supply and demand, central banks intervene at times to peg the rates at some desired level. Thus, the managed float has the attributes of both a fixed and a floating exchange rate regime, because changing supply and demand will affect exchange rates, but the actions of the central bank will also allow international reserves to change. To allow for reserve changes, as well as for exchange rate changes, we can simply return to the initial Eq. (14.8). Thus, we can see that given money demand or money supply changes, the central bank can choose to let E^image adjust to the free-market level; or, by holding E at some disequilibrium level, it will allow R^image to adjust.

Sterilization

Sterilization is the offsetting of international reserve flows by central banks that wish to follow an independent monetary policy. Under the MABP (with fixed exchange rates), if a country has an excess supply of money, this country would tend to lose international reserves or run a deficit until money supply equals money demand. Central banks often have reasons for desiring either a high money supply growth or a low money supply growth. For example, if the central bank wants to stimulate the economy it might want a high money supply growth. If for some reason the central bank desires a higher money supply and reacts to the deficit by further increasing the money supply, then the deficit will increase and persist as long as the central bank tries to maintain a money supply in excess of money demand. With an excess demand for money, the concept is reversed. The excess demand results in reserve inflows to equate money supply to money demand. If the central bank tries to decrease the money supply so that the excess demand still exists, its efforts will be thwarted by further reserve inflows, which will persist as long as the central bank tries to maintain the policy of a money supply less than money demand.

Sterilization would allow the monetary authorities to stabilize the money supply in the short run without having reserve flows offset their goals. This would be possible if the forces that lead to international arbitrage are slow to operate. For instance, barriers to international capital mobility might exist in a country. In such a case, we might expect international asset return differentials to persist following a change in economic conditions. If the central bank wants to increase the growth of the money supply in the short run, it can do so regardless of money demand and reserve flows. In the long run, when complete adjustment of asset prices is possible, the money supply must grow at a rate consistent with money demand. In the short run, however, the central bank can exercise some discretion.

The actual use of the word sterilization derives from the fact that the central bank must be able to neutralize, or sterilize, any reserve flows induced by monetary policy if the policy is to achieve the central bank’s money supply goals. For instance, if the central bank is following some money supply growth path, and then money demand increases, leading to reserve inflows, the central bank must be able to sterilize these reserve inflows to keep the money supply from rising to what it considers undesirable levels. This is done by decreasing domestic credit by an amount equal to the growth of international reserves, thus keeping base money and the money supply constant.

Recall again the fixed exchange rate MABP in Eq. (14.9). Given money demand, an increase in domestic credit would be reflected in a fall in R^image. Thus, the causality works from D^image to R^image. If sterilization occurs, then the causality implied in Eq. (14.9) is no longer true. Instead of the monetary approach equation previously written, where changes in domestic credit (D^image, on the right-hand side of the equation) lead to changes in reserves (R^image, on the left-hand side), with sterilization we also have changes in reserves inducing changes in domestic credit in order to offset the reserve flows. Sterilization means that there is also a causality flowing from reserve changes to domestic credit, as in

D^=αβR^ (14.12)

image (14.12)

where β is the sterilization coefficient, ranging in value from 0 (when there is no sterilization) to 1 (complete sterilization). Eq. (14.12) states that the percentage change in domestic credit will be equal to some constant amount (α) determined by the central bank’s domestic policy goals, minus the coefficient β, times the percentage change in reserves. The coefficient β will reflect the central bank’s ability to use domestic credit to offset reserve flows. Of course, it is possible that the central bank cannot fully offset international reserve flows, and yet some sterilization is possible, in which case β will lie between 0 and 1. Evidence has in fact suggested both extremes as well as an intermediate value for β. It is reasonable to interpret the evidence regarding sterilization as indicating that central banks are able to sterilize a significant fraction of reserve flows in the short run. This means that the monetary authorities can likely choose the growth rate of the money supply in the short run, although long-run money growth must be consistent with money demand requirements.

Sterilized Intervention

We have, so far, discussed sterilization in the context of fixed exchange rates. Now let us consider how a sterilization operation might occur in a floating exchange rate system. Suppose the Japanese yen is appreciating against the dollar, and the Bank of Japan decides to intervene in the foreign exchange market to increase the value of the dollar and stop the yen appreciation. The Bank of Japan increases domestic credit in order to purchase US dollar-denominated bonds. The increased demand for dollar bonds will lead to an increase in the demand for dollars in the foreign exchange market. This results in the higher foreign exchange value of the dollar. Now suppose that the Bank of Japan has a target level of the Japanese money supply that requires the increase in domestic credit to be offset. The central bank will sell yen-denominated bonds in Japan to reduce the domestic money supply. The domestic Japanese money supply was originally increased by the growth in domestic credit used to buy dollar bonds. The money supply ultimately returns to its initial level because the Bank of Japan uses a domestic open-market operation (the formal term for central bank purchases and sales of domestic bonds) to reduce domestic credit. In this case of managed floating exchange rates, the Bank of Japan uses sterilized intervention to achieve its goal of slowing the appreciation of the yen while keeping the Japanese money supply unchanged. Sterilized intervention is ultimately an exchange of domestic bonds for foreign bonds.

It is possible for sterilized intervention with unchanged money supplies to have an effect on the spot exchange rate if money demand changes. The intervention activity could alter the private market view of what to expect in the future. If the intervention changes expectations in a manner that changes money demand (for instance, money demand in Japan falls because the intervention leads people to expect higher Japanese inflation), then the spot rate could change.

Summary

1. The basic premise of the monetary approach is that any balance of payments disequilibrium is based on a monetary disequilibrium.

2. Specie-flow mechanism explains the adjustments to a change in money supply in one country under the fixed exchange rate environment through price movements and international trade flows.

3. According to the specie-flow mechanism, an increase in money supply in Country A will cause a balance of trade deficit in Country A, and a balance of trade surplus in Country B in the short run. In the long run, with the flow of gold from the trade deficit country to the trade surplus country, prices in two countries will adjust to bring both countries back in equilibrium again.

4. Two applications of the monetary approach are: (i) the MABP and (ii) the MAER.

5. The MABP emphasizes money demand and money supply as determinants of the balance of payments under the fixed exchange rate.

6. The MAER emphasizes money demand and money supply as determinants of exchange rate movements.

7. The money supply is composed of domestic credit and international reserves.

8. The money demand is derived from people’s willingness to hold money, which is a constant proportion of their nominal income.

9. The MABP implies that the change in international reserves equals to the foreign inflation rate plus the growth rate of domestic output minus the change in domestic money creation.

10. Under the fixed exchange rate, inflation from one country can be transmitted to the other country.

11. The MAER implies that, under the free-floating exchange rate system, a change in monetary policy in one country will not affect the other country’s money supply, only causing an adjustment of the exchange rate.

12. The monetary approach in the case of a managed floating exchange rate has attributes of both the MAER and MABP approach.

13. Sterilized intervention is the action by a central bank to offset the effect of a foreign exchange intervention, on the domestic money supply, by using the open-market operations.

Exercises

1. “Monetary disequilibrium leads to balance of payments problems under fixed exchange rates, and a currency problem under floating exchange rates.” Discuss this statement with reference to the monetary approach.

2. What are the assumptions underlying the MABP? Explain.

3. According to the MABP, what type of economic policies would help a country to resolve a balance of trade deficit?

4. Using the MABP, explain how the Bretton Woods system could break down after the United States increases its money supply too fast.

5. In a perfectly floating exchange rate regime, use the MAER to explain the effect on the dollar price of a Swiss franc ($/SFr) of the following scenarios:

a. The output in the United States decreases by 3%.

b. The price level in Switzerland decreases by 2%.

6. Assume that Mexico and the United States are in a fixed exchange rate agreement. Suppose that the Fed increases the money supply by 40%. What would happen to the international reserve position for the United States? Assume that the United States has to intervene to peg the exchange rate; how could they accomplish the intervention?

Further Reading

1. Bahmani-Oskoee M, Hosny A, Kishor NK. The exchange rate puzzle revisited. Int J Financ Econ. 2015;20:126–137.

2. Baillie RT, Osterberg WP. Why do central banks intervene? J Int Money Financ. 1997; December.

3. Connolly M, Putnam B, Wilford DS. The monetary approach to an open economy: the fundamental theory. In: Putnam B, Wilford DS, eds. The Monetary Approach to International Adjustment. New York: Praeger; 1978.

4. Dominguez K. Central bank intervention and exchange rate volatility. J Int Money Financ. 1998; February.

5. Hume D. Essays, moral, political and literary. In: Cooper RN, ed. International Finance. Middlesex: Penguin; 1752; 1969.

6. Neely CJ, Sarno L. How well do monetary fundamentals forecast exchange rates? Fed Reserve St Louis Econ Rev. 2002;51–74 September/October.

7. Sarno L, Taylor MP. Official intervention in the foreign exchange: is it effective and, if so, how does it work? J Econ Lit. 2001;39(3):839–868.

8. Taylor MP. The economics of exchange rates. J Econ Lit. 1995; March.

9. Taylor MP. Why is it so difficult to beat the random walk forecast of exchange rates. J Int Econ. 2003;60:85–107.


1We are assuming that base money and the money supply are equal. Realistically, the money supply is some multiple of base money. We assume that this multiple is 1 in order to simplify the analysis.

2In Eq. (14.7), R and D are actually the percentage change as a fraction of total money supply (R+D).

..................Content has been hidden....................

You can't read the all page of ebook, please click here login for view all page.
Reset
3.145.178.157