Chapter 4
A Global Inter-country Economic Model Based on Linked Input–Output Models

Robert G. Levy, Thomas P. Oléron Evans and Alan Wilson

4.1 Introduction

The objective of this chapter is to present a global economic model that can be used as the basis for assessing the impacts of future changes in trade, migration, security and development aid. Because these topics are often associated with developing countries, it is important that the model have as few coefficients as possible to enable the future addition of countries who publish little data on their economic structure. The model as it is presented here represents a first ‘proof-of-concept’ step towards these ambitious goals. At this stage, the focus is on creating a model of global trade which will form a skeleton onto which additional social science models will be added in future work. The economies of individual countries are represented as 35-sector input–output models, each of which is linked through trade flows representing imports and exports. This has recently been made feasible by the publication of the World Input–Output Database (WIOD) (Timmer et al., 2015), a collection of national input–output tables (NIOTs) for 40 (mostly OECD) countries across 17 years from 1995 to 2011. The NIOTs are linked through data from the United Nations, covering trade in both products1 and services.2

While other models of world trade based on the input–output methodology exist, the model presented here is one of the first to integrate the extremely detailed internal economic data provided by WIOD with the enormous wealth of trade data from the UN COMTRADE database, resulting in a picture of global trade that includes an unparalleled amount of empirically derived economic information. The use of such data sources and the simplicity and flexibility of the model proposed will allow for the investigation of a wide range of economic scenarios, including those involving developing countries, in future work.

The remainder of this chapter is structured as follows: Section 4.2 gives an overview of existing work in this area; Section 4.3 gives a description of the present system and outlines how data is used to calibrate the coefficients of the model; The algorithm used to calculate the output of the model is described in Section 4.4 and some preliminary results are given in Section 4.5; Conclusions and potential directions for future research are presented in Section 4.6.

4.2 Existing Global Economic Models

In the mid-1970s, the creator of input–output economics, Wassily Leontief, used the acceptance speech of his Nobel Prize in Economics to announce a very ambitious project to model the global economy:

Major efforts are underway to construct a data base for a systematic input-output study not of a single national economy but of the world economy viewed as a system composed of many interrelated parts [...] Preliminary plans provide for a description of the world economy in terms of twenty-eight groups of countries, with about forty-five productive sectors for each group.

Leontief 1974

Duchin 2004 describes how, 20 years on, Leontief's efforts in this area had largely been ignored by economists who describe his departures from the standard, neoclassical modelling in terms of price elasticity and elasticity of substitution as being ‘too great to ignore’ (see Section 4.3.2 for more on this subject).

In the years since Leontief published his global model, input–output analysis has been largely restricted to regional studies, of which Akita 1993, Khan 1999 and Luo 2013 are examples, and studies related to energy and the environment, such as Leontief 1970, Joshi 1999, van den Bergh 2002 and Hendrickson et al. 2006.

However, much more recently, attention has returned to input–output modelling in a global context more generally. Tukker and Dietzenbacher 2013 describe how several multi-regional input-output (MRIO) models have been developed in the very recent literature. These are, along with WIOD which is used in the present model, EORA (Lenzen et al., 2013), EXIOPOL (Tukker et al., 2013) and the more mature GTAP (Walmsley et al., 2012).

Each of these existing models of the global economy extends the idea of the NIOT to an international setting: where in a NIOT the magnitude of every bilateral sector–sector flow is recorded for a given country, these projects record the magnitude of every country/sector–country/sector flow. Thus, for example, the extent to which British agriculture purchases from Belgian manufacturing is recorded in dollar amounts. This results in a large matrix which, through inversion in the normal input–output manner, can be used to predict the impact of a particular exogenous change in demand. This tends to strengthen the case of those economists, mentioned by Duchin 2004, that price elasticity and elasticity of substitution are ignored by input–output economics.

The model presented in this chapter provides a framework in which the power of input–output analysis at the national level can becombined with a more subtle understanding of the dynamics of international trade. The standard MRIO of c04-math-0001 countries and c04-math-0002 sectors requires c04-math-0003 coefficients, and a major goal of this model is to minimise the number of coefficients required to model a global system. It also provides modellers with a richer set of coefficients than the standard technical coefficients of MRIOs in order to facilitate the combination of the present model with other models of human systems, such as migration, international security and development aid. Additionally, as mentioned, this reduced set of coefficients will facilitate the addition of countries vital to the study of these systems, but which do not publish data on economic structure. The mathematical estimation of the coefficients for these countries is the subject of upcoming work.

4.3 Description of the Model

4.3.1 Outline

Here, we outline the new global model. In this presentation the model has c04-math-0004 countries, the economies of which are divided into c04-math-0005 productive sectors.3 All product flows are given by value, measured in millions of (current price) US dollars.4 We start with an introduction to input–output tables which, aside from some important notation, can be skipped by the reader familiar with this topic. We then introduce the model of a single country, outline both the normal input–output coefficient sets and introduce the first new set. Finally, we show how these country models are linked with an international trade model and introduce the second new set of coefficients.

4.3.2 Introduction to Input–Output Tables

Input–output is, at its heart, an accounting methodology. The products produced by and imported into a given country in a given year are either: sold as inputs to other sectors (‘intermediate supply’); supplied to the ‘final demand’ of consumers and the government; invested or exported. The total amount imported and produced must equal the amount used, consumed, invested and exported for each sector.

By simple summation, country c04-math-0006's total production of sector c04-math-0007, c04-math-0008, can be defined as the sum of all intermediate supply plus supply to final demand, investment and export:

where c04-math-0010 is the intermediate supply from domestic sector c04-math-0011 to sector c04-math-0012 in country c04-math-0013, c04-math-0014 is the final demand for domestic sector c04-math-0015, c04-math-0016 is the investment and c04-math-0017 are exports.

Similarly, country c04-math-0018's total import of sector c04-math-0019, c04-math-0020, is the sum of all intermediate supply of imported products plus demand for and investment of imported products5

:

An input–output table, c04-math-0022, as described by Miller and Blair 1985, is a particular arrangement of these quantities, which provides a clear and compact summary of the structure of a national economy. Neglecting the c04-math-0023 superscript for clarity,6 the NIOT is defined as follows:

It will often be convenient to gather those quantities having a single subscript into vectors and those with two subscripts into matrices. We can then characterise a country's economy through the c04-math-0025-vectors c04-math-0026, c04-math-0027 and c04-math-0028 and by the c04-math-0029 matrices c04-math-0030 and c04-math-0031. In the matrix form, the input–output table may be written as

The elements of c04-math-0033 and c04-math-0034 provide each sector with a complete ‘recipe’ for making its output, describing the quantities of each product needed as input, both domestic and imported, to produce total production, c04-math-0035. We are now in a position to introduce our first coefficient set. By dividing each intermediate flow, c04-math-0036, by the total output, c04-math-0037, of the sector using the intermediate, we can arrive at a set of technical coefficients, c04-math-0038, which define the input of one sector required per unit output of another. The amount of domestically produced product c04-math-0039 required by sector c04-math-0040 to produce a single unit of output is thus

and the equivalent measure for imported c04-math-0042 is

4.6 equation

There are therefore c04-math-0044 technical coefficients for each country.7 These technical coefficients allow the intermediate demand to be calculated for any given set of final demands, investments and exports. The total domestic production of sector c04-math-0046, c04-math-0047, is given by

equation

or, in matrix representation, stacking the equations for each sector vertically:

Having calculated total domestic production, we can then calculate the import, c04-math-0050, required to satisfy intermediate and final demands as

4.8 equation

Thus, the domestic total production, the intermediate demand and the imports may be completely determined from the final demand, the investments, the exports and the technical coefficients.

4.3.3 A Single Country Model

Our country model follows the standard input–output model described in Section 4.3.2 to a large extent. Each country is represented by an input–output table, and many of the coefficients used to describe a country's economy are taken directly from WIOD. Table 4.1 shows a summary of which coefficients are used, unchanged, in our country model.8

Table 4.1 Coefficients which define the economy of country c04-math-0052 and their source in WIOD national input-output tables

Description Source in WIOD
c04-math-0053 Final demand on sector c04-math-0054 Sum of three final consumption columns: households, government and non-profit organisations
c04-math-0055 Investment of sector c04-math-0056 Sum of two investment columns labelled ‘gross fixed capital formation’ and ‘changes in inventories and valuables’
c04-math-0057 Exports of sector c04-math-0058 Column labelled ‘Exports’
c04-math-0059 Intermediate demand on sector c04-math-0060 by sector c04-math-0061 (domestic) Top-left 35 c04-math-0062 35 block, labelled ‘c1–c35’
c04-math-0063 Intermediate demand on sector c04-math-0064 by sector c04-math-0065 (imported) Bottom-left 35 c04-math-0066 35 block

a Note that domestic coefficients are labelled with a dagger superscript (c04-math-0067) and import coefficients with an asterisk (*).

Source: Reproduced with permission from Levy et al. (2014)

Notice that imports, c04-math-0068, are not present in this table. To define c04-math-0069 we now introduce the first of two new sets of coefficients.

4.3.3.1 Import Ratios

The above description treats domestic and foreign goods as complements of one another, rather than as substitutes. For example, each aeroplane produced would require some fixed quantity of domestic steel and a (different) fixed quantity of imported steel. Inspired by the description given by Duchin 2004 of Leontief's proposed global model, the present model reverses this assumption and treats foreign and domestic products as perfect complements. This assumption is important for our goal of coefficient parsimony as we shall see.

Leontief assumed that engineers in an importing country do not care where a product originated; they will simply know that domestic production does not meet their demand and instead demand a perfectly substitutable imported product. In a similar spirit, when a product in the present model arrives at the shores of an importing country, it enters a theoretical ‘national warehouse’ along with domestically produced products, at which point the two become indistinguishable.9

We assume that the proportion of domestic to imported goods in this warehouse remains constant. This fraction remains fixed per country and per sector and is called the import ratio. It is calculated directly from the country's NIOT as

where c04-math-0071, c04-math-0072 and c04-math-0073 are the total production, export and import of sector c04-math-0074 calculated via Equations (4.1) and (4.2), respectively. The term c04-math-0075 represents the products used domestically. It includes all intermediate demand, including that required to fulfil export requirements, as well as direct flows to final demand and investment, but excludes direct flows to export. This is because imports may not directly supply export demand as per Equation (4.4).

The assumption of fixed import ratios halves the number of technical coefficients that must be specified for a given country and, therefore, helps to achieve our goal of model parsimony.

Since we no longer need to track intermediate flows separately for domestic and imported goods, we can create a single matrix of intermediate flows, c04-math-0076, as follows:

4.10 equation

Now, similar to Equation (4.5), the ‘combined’ technical coefficients can be calculated by dividing each element of c04-math-0078 by an appropriate element of c04-math-0079. Following Miller and Blair 1985 in defining c04-math-0080 as a matrix whose diagonal elements are the elements of c04-math-0081, we can calculate the combined technical coefficients as

As we have seen, both c04-math-0083 and c04-math-0084 are calculated directly from data and are then fixed as coefficients of each country model. Once they are calculated, we can use them to calculate, in a similar style to Equation (4.7), total production c04-math-0085 for any set of final demands, c04-math-0086, investments, c04-math-0087, and exports, c04-math-0088:

where c04-math-0090 is an c04-math-0091 matrix whose diagonal elements are the import ratios, c04-math-0092, and c04-math-0093 is the appropriately sized identity matrix. Once c04-math-0094 is known, we can calculate imports, c04-math-0095, from Equation (4.9) as

Finally, every individual inter-sector flow can be recovered using

A further parsimony benefit of the import ratio assumption is that final demand and investment have only c04-math-0098 elements to be specified, rather than the c04-math-0099 elements shown in Equation (4.3). This implies that consumers have no preference between domestic and imported products. Rather, the import ratios will set the relationship between demand for domestic goods and demand for imported goods in an identical way to Equation (4.14).

4.3.4 An International Trade Model

The concept of the NIOT is often expanded to an international context using MRIO modelling. In standard MRIO, each sector in each country is explicit about which countries it gets its imports from. This requires each sector to have c04-math-0100 technical coefficients, an onerous data requirement and, as we have seen, a challenge to the credibility of the assumptions required.

WIOD presents all these technical coefficients in what it calls world input–output tables (WIOTs), huge MRIO tables for the whole world, but the present model instead takes a second assumption from Leontief via Duchin 2004 which Leontief referred to using the term ‘export shares’. It is this assumption which introduces our second new set of coefficients.

4.3.4.1 Import Propensities

Once import demand is fixed by the country model outlined in section 4.3.3, we make the assumption that countries get each of their imported products from their international trading partners in fixed proportions. Thus, country c04-math-0101 will always get the same proportion of its total import demand for product c04-math-0102 from country c04-math-0103. We refer to these fixed proportions as import propensities as they describe a country's propensity to import a given product from each other country. These propensities are calculated directly from empirical observation, using trade flow data provided by the United Nations in their COMTRADE database.10 This database provides bilateral flows of products at a very fine grain of detail. Using a mapping provided to us by the WIOD team, we were able to map each of these product flows to a sector and, by summation, create empirically observed total sector flows. By denoting the flow of sector c04-math-0104 from country c04-math-0105 to country c04-math-0106 as c04-math-0107, we can calculate the associated import propensity directly from data using

Given the import requirements of each country from Equation (4.13) and the import propensities from Equation (4.15), the export demand on sector c04-math-0109 in country c04-math-0110 due to demand from country c04-math-0111 can be calculated as

4.16 equation

and total export demand in country c04-math-0113 is therefore

Equations (4.9)–(4.17) thus describe a system which defines the total productions of all sectors in all countries, the intermediate input–output flows, imports and exports, given a set of technical coefficients, import ratios, import propensities and final demands,11 all of which can be derived directly from empirically observed data. Following a given set of changes to any of these latter four sets of coefficients, all of the former six categories of flow can be found.

4.3.5 Setting Model Coefficients from Data

As outlined earlier, the model takes four groups of coefficients and produces a complete set of flows within countries (input–output flows) and a complete set of trade flows (imports and exports) between countries. These four groups of coefficients are either calculated from the NIOTs provided by WIOD or from commodity and services trade data provided by the United Nations. Table 4.2 summarises the four groups of coefficients and the way in which they are set from data.

Table 4.2 The four groups of fixed coefficients in the model and their construction from data. All other flows, including imports and exports, are derived from these coefficients mathematically

Final demand c04-math-0116 quantity of a product consumed by the public and the government of a particular country. These are taken directly from the NIOTs using the columns described in Table 4.1.
Technical coefficients c04-math-0117 the quantity of product c04-math-0118 required in country c04-math-0119 to make a single unit of product c04-math-0120. Calculated from the NIOTs using Equation (4.11).
Import ratios c04-math-0121 the proportion of country c04-math-0122's total demand for product c04-math-0123 which is supplied by imports. Calculated from the NIOTs using Equation (4.9).
Import propensities c04-math-0124 the proportion of country c04-math-0125's total of import of product c04-math-0126 which comes from country c04-math-0127. Calculated from the UN trade data using Equation (4.15).

Source: Reproduced with permission from Levy et al. (2014).

4.4 Solving the Model

4.4.1 The Leontief Equation

To get production requirements from traditional WIOT, it is sufficient to invert the matrix and solve for c04-math-0128 directly via Leontief's famous equation:

4.18 equation

The elegance of Leontief's method also had an additional benefit in that it was computationally efficient. Mathematical methods existed for efficient inversion of matrices which lent the solution an extra appeal in an age of hand-wrought numerical solutions.

4.4.2 The Drawbacks of Mathematical Elegance

Behind this elegant and efficient formulation, the assumptions are as follows:

  1. i. Production functions are linear: to produce double the output, double the amount of every input is required.
  2. ii. Production possibilities are unlimited: an economy will simply produce whatever is demanded of it.
  3. iii. Markets always clear: all demand is fulfilled immediately.

The undeniable computational convenience of the traditional method of solving IO models is no longer a sufficient justification for its use if it is accompanied by assumptions which would not otherwise be made.

The model in its current form relaxes none of the three assumptions given earlier, but the separation of international trade from individual domestic economies offers the flexibility to do so in future work, simply by making the desired alterations to the country-level model. Such alterations would be more straightforward to perform and more intuitivelycomprehensible in this model than in a WIOT, where changing any individual process would require consideration of the entire system and a completely new approach to finding solutions. Recent work on complexity in economics such as Beinhocker 2006 and Ramalingam et al. 2009 supports the thesis that many of the interesting phenomena in macroeconomics happen when systems are out of equilibrium. With this in mind, we now describe a routine for solving the model iteratively, rather than through a single, large matrix inversion.

4.4.3 Algorithm for an Iterative Solution

Figure 4.1 shows a schematic version of the algorithm for calculating imports and exports from the four groups of coefficients.

nfgz001

Figure 4.1 The model algorithm: total production, imports and exports are calculated for a given set of fixed coefficients. Note that square brackets have been introduced to designate the iteration variable c04-math-0130, which tracks the quantities that are iteratively recalculated as the algorithm runs. Source: Reproduced with permission from Levy et al. (2014)

Initialisation

All export demands are set to 0.

Country-level Model

Inside each country, total demand is calculated using the export demands (which were initially set to zero), final demands, technical coefficients and import ratios, as per Equation (4.12). This step maintains the standard input–output matrix inversion. From total demand, import demand can be calculated via the import ratios as in Equation (4.13).

Iteration Condition

At this point the iteration continues unless the total level of global imports matches, to within some small tolerance c04-math-0131, total exports in each sector.12 In the first run through the iteration, this stop condition will certainly fail because exports have just been set to zero.

International Trade Model

The import demands calculated in the country-level models can be divided up into export demands using the import propensities by using Equation (4.17). These new export demands replace the export demands from the previous iteration (which were all zero the first time round). With a new set of export demands calculated, the algorithm returns to the country-level model.

The iteration continues in this way, moving between the country-level and the international-level models, until the system of imports and exports converges and the stop condition is met.13

Solving the system algorithmically rather than relying on the standard methods of linear algebra allows for a greater flexibility in the way that the model may beextended in future work. For example, provided that care was taken to maintain its stability, the algorithmic approach could be applied even if the assumption of linear production functions were to be relaxed in order to model economies of scale.

4.5 Analysis

4.5.1 Introduction

The model combining input–output country descriptions and the international trade network allows for the measurement of the total input required to make a single unit of a particular sector's product. Since WIOD reports product flows in millions of US dollars ($M), this will also be the unit of all the following analyses. In all that follows, the model was initialised using data from 2010.

4.5.2 Simple Modelling Approaches

4.5.2.1 Economic Significance

A simple way to measure the significance to the global economy (hereafter ‘significance’) of a particular sector in a given country is to artificially reduce final demand for the products of that country–sector by one unit, to recalculate all flows in the model based on this new final demand and to measure the response of each other sector in each other country in the model.

This takes account of not only the direct effects of such a change—a reduction in the output of the sector in question and of those sectors supplying that sector's intermediate demand—but also the full spectrum of indirect effects on those sectors which supplied the demand of the sectors who supplied the sector in question, on their suppliers and so on. We can formalise the final demand change in sector c04-math-0133 in country c04-math-0134 as

The simplest way to define ‘response’ is as the change of total output of all sectors, c04-math-0136, in all countries, c04-math-0137, caused by the reduction:

4.20 equation

where c04-math-0139 is the total output of sector c04-math-0140 in country c04-math-0141 after the change in Equation (4.19) has taken place and the model has been recalculated according to Figure 4.1. c04-math-0142 is thus the change in output of sector c04-math-0143 in country c04-math-0144 induced by the change in final demand for sector c04-math-0145 in country c04-math-0146.

The total response across all countries and all sectors induced by sector c04-math-0147 in country c04-math-0148 is

4.21 equation

and the average response-inducing power of the sectors in country c04-math-0150 is

4.22 equation

where c04-math-0152 is, as earlier, the number of sectors in country c04-math-0153's economy.

If a reduction in demand for a sector induces a large reduction in production globally, it follows that sectors with a larger value of c04-math-0154 must require, once the entire production network is accounted for, a larger amount of input to produce each unit of their output. c04-math-0155 can thus be thought of as a country-level significance measure, with larger values implying an economy which, averaging across the effects of each of its sectors, has a greater significance on production in the rest of the world (RoW).

Table 4.3 shows the 10 most significant modelled countries by this measure. China is the world's most significant economy, a $1M reduction in final demand leading to an average of $2.36M reduction in total output worldwide.

Table 4.3 Response to a $1M reduction in final demand in terms of the difference induced in the total output, c04-math-0156, of other sectors

(a) most significant countries (b) China's most significant sectors
Country c04-math-0157($M) Sector c04-math-0158($M)
China 2.36 Vehicles 2.47
Czech Republic 1.98 Food 2.20
S. Korea 1.95 Plastics 2.20
Russia 1.94 Metals 2.17
Bulgaria 1.92 Machinery 2.17
Japan 1.90 Wood 2.14
Italy 1.90 Electricals 2.13
Poland 1.89 Construction 2.12
Finland 1.88 Textiles 2.11
Portugal 1.87 Paper 2.10

a Only the largest 10 are shown

Source: Reproduced with permission from Levy et al. (2014)

This is perhaps a surprising result, as we might have expected the United States to be the world's most significant economy. To investigate further, we split the significance measure, c04-math-0159, into foreign and domestic effects as follows:

4.23 equation
4.24 equation

and

4.25 equation

Notice that this does indeed split c04-math-0163 into precisely two parts as

4.26 equation

Figure 4.2 shows how the average response across all sectors divides between domestic response, c04-math-0165, and foreign response,14 c04-math-0166, for each country. An OLS regression line has been added to the plot. All the countries lying close to the line have a similar total significance, c04-math-0167. The region below the line is the region of less-than-average significance and that above the line is the region of greater-than-average significance.

nfgz002

Figure 4.2 The total response of the global economy to a reduction in final demand, averaged across every sector in a country. ‘Response’ is defined as the total production lost across all sectors. Here, response has been divided into domestic, where the response is measured only in the country whose final demand has been reduced, and foreign, where the response is measured in all other countries only. Source: Reproduced with permission from Levy et al. (2014)

China is immediately visible as an outlier. Its economy is around one-third more significant (c04-math-0168) than that of Brazil (c04-math-0169) or India (c04-math-0170), but almost all of this extra significance relates to its impact on its own domestic sectors. Thus, China's significance to the world economy shows itself largely in China itself: it is significant to the extent that it uses disproportionately a large amount of its own productive output in its production technology. This may perhaps be evidence of the much-vaunted end of low labour costs in China (Li et al., 2012), (Economist, 2012), although further research would be needed to verify this.

4.5.2.2 Economic Self-reliance

Countries further to the left of Figure 4.2, such as Brazil, India, Japan, Russia, Turkey and the United States, have a lower global response to a domestic demand shock. We could therefore describe these countries as being more self-reliant than those on the right, such as Luxembourg, Belgium, the Netherlands and Denmark. This self-reliance can be made precise by measuring the ratio of domestic response to foreign response:

Figure 4.3 shows the relationship between c04-math-0172 and population in 2010 (World Bank, 2014).

nfgz003

Figure 4.3 Figure showing the positive relationship between economic self-reliance as defined by Equation (4.27) and population. More populous countries tend to be more self-reliant. Source: Reproduced with permission from Levy et al. (2014)

The positive slope of the regression line (significant at 0.1%) indicates that larger countries are generally more self-reliant. Both Brazil and Australia are more self-reliant than their populations would suggest. Belgium and the Netherlands are less self-reliant in the same sense. An interesting avenue for further research might be to investigate which sectors cause the largest share of these atypical self-reliance measures, particularly that of the largest outlier, Brazil.

4.5.3 A Unified Network Approach

The flow of products between countries can be viewed as a weighted, directed network, where countries are nodes, and the weights of each edge represents the magnitude of the flow between them (Nystuen and Dacey, 1961; Serrano and Boguñá, 2003; Bhattacharya et al., 2008; Baskaran et al., 2011). Similarly, the sector–sector flows constitute an input–output model (Blöchl et al., 2011; Fedriani and Tenorio, 2012). Network science has developed useful ways to analyse the sort of weighted, directed networks that constitute the present model, but a single network representation is required which combines the international and the sub-national networks.

Recall from Section 4.3.3 that products arriving at the shores of an importing country are put into a warehouse along with domestically produced products at which point the two become indistinguishable. If an additional assumption is made that domestic sectors take from this warehouse by means of a random sample, then the fraction of products in each sample from abroad will be identical, as will be the fraction of imported products from each exporter. These fractions will be set by the import ratios and import propensities, respectively.

This additional assumption allows us to specify a complete system of intermediate (input–output) flows, c04-math-0173, from sector c04-math-0174 in country c04-math-0175 to sector c04-math-0176 in country c04-math-0177, thereby effectively reconstructing the MRIO from which we diverted in Section 4.4:

4.28 equation

which can be understood as follows: sector c04-math-0179 in country c04-math-0180 requires an amount c04-math-0181 of sector c04-math-0182's product to produce its total output; a fraction c04-math-0183 of this will be supplied by imports; a fraction c04-math-0184 of these imports will come from country c04-math-0185. Note that since countries do not import their own exports, c04-math-0186, and the expression holds trivially for c04-math-0187.

The fractions of each type of demand for c04-math-0188 in country c04-math-0189 which was exported by country c04-math-0190 are given by similar expressions:

4.29 equation

where, as previously, c04-math-0192 is the final demand, c04-math-0193 is the export demand and c04-math-0194 are investments.

Along with the sector-to-sector flows given by Equation(4.14), this allows for the representation of all the flows in the present model as a single network, to which standard network analysis techniques can then be applied.

This reformulation demonstrates the connection between the model described in this chapter and the established WIOT approach, allowing us to visualise the individual country–sector to country–sector flows (or changes in such flows) for any model scenario, such as that calculated in Section 4.5.2 in response to a reduction of demand in China for the vehicles sector by $1M.

The change to every such flow (both between-country trade flows and within-country intermediate flows) in the eight most-affected countries is recorded and visualised in Figure 4.4. Node size is proportional to eigenvector centrality, and the edge weight is proportional to the change induced in the particular flow by the reduction in final demand. This diagram reveals the patterns and shapes of the various economies which would be hard to pick out in the raw flow matrix.

nfgz004

Figure 4.4 A network representation of the seven most-affected countries following a reduction in final demand for the Chinese vehicles sector. Node size is proportional to eigenvector centrality and edge width is proportional to the change in flow. Source: Reproduced with permission from Levy et al. (2014)

4.5.4 Comparison with a Multi-region Input–Output Model

As discussed in Section 4.2, the modelling approach presented here relaxes the somewhat rigid structure of an MRIO table. In so doing, it also reduces the amount of data required to estimate tables for countries which are not covered by WIOD. But since the present iteration of the model can be made equivalent to a MRIO (as shown in Section 4.5.3), any of the analyses presented here could equally well be performed using the WIOT directly. It is therefore important to verify that the model in its present, most simple, form behaves similarly to an MRIO before any further development is done.

To this end, the results of the experiment of Section 4.5.2, reducing demand for Chinese vehicles, is repeated using an MRIO, and the results are compared in Figure 4.5. The response to a reduction in demand for Chinese vehicles is summed over sectors in each country. The countries are then ranked according to the size of the response. The ranks produced by the MRIO are shown on the left-hand side and those produced by the present model are shown in the right. Visually, the results seem broadly comparable and have a Spearman rank correlation coefficient (Spearman, 1904) of 0.96. This gives some confidence in concluding that this first and simplest iteration of the model behaves in a similar manner to the MRIO it seeks to generalise and extend.

nfgz005

Figure 4.5 A comparison of the results of the Chinese vehicle experiment performed on an MRIO (on the left) and on the present model (on the right). Vertical position represents the rank of the country in terms of how affected it is by a reduction in demand for Chinese vehicles. *Taiwan is ranked last in the present model. This is because the United Nations provides no trade data for the territory. All Taiwan's import ratios are therefore zero (i.e. Taiwan is modelled as being entirely self-sufficient). Source: Reproduced with permission from Levy et al. (2014)

4.6 Conclusions

In this chapter, we have introduced a new model of global trade, combining two distinct modelling approaches for the internal workings of national economies and for international trade. The model incorporates information from two extremely extensive data sets, the UN COMTRADE database and WIOD, giving it a good basis in empirical observation.

The model equations are solved iteratively, thus avoiding the limitations and assumptions of the traditional multi-region input–output approach, lending the model the flexibility to accommodate a wide variety of possible extensions, such as the consideration of non-linear production functions, limited production capacities and non-clearing markets. It also introduces two new sets of coefficients for modellers to work with, which will facilitate its integration with other social science models.

We have also introduced a new measure of the global economic significance of each sector within a national economy, gauging the degree to which that sector drives economic activity across the world. In initial investigations, China was found to be a considerable outlier in terms of its economic significance, driven by high consumption of its own domestically produced products and services. Following this analysis, we introduced a measure of economic self-reliance, which was found to vary inversely with population. These results represent preliminary analyses only, with far more scope for detailed investigation of international trade patterns and alternative global economic scenarios now that the model is operational.

Finally, we have presented a method for transforming the structure of the model into that of a traditional MRIO table, allowing for both traditional MRIO approaches, and the use of the tools and analyses of the network science literature. A very simple example of this approach was presented, with further analyses to follow in future work.

The next step will be to estimate country models for those (mostly non-OECD) countries not in WIOD to facilitate the study of such human systems as migration, international security and development aid. Further work on the model will include the relaxation of its input–output assumptions, beginning with the introduction of limits on production capacity, with the goal of creating a fully dynamic version of the model to analyse the change in trade patterns over time. Upcoming work uses the model to answer specific policy questions such as how to maximise a country's GDP by manipulation of its final demand vector, import ratios and technical coefficients.

Acknowledgements

The authors acknowledge the financial support of the UK Engineering and PhysicalSciences Research Council (EPSRC) under the grant ENFOLDing—Explaining, Modelling and Forecasting Global Dynamics, reference EP/H02185X/1.

We would also like to thank Hannah Fry, Rob Downes, Anthony Korte and Peter Baudains for their invaluable input and support during the writing of this chapter.

References

  1. Akita, T. (1993) Interregional interdependence and regional economic growth in Japan: an input-output analysis. International Regional Science Review, 16 (3), 231–248.
  2. Baskaran, T., Blöchl, F., Brück, T., and Theis, F.J. (2011) The Heckscher-Ohlin model and the network structure of international trade. International Review of Economics & Finance, 20 (2), 135–145.
  3. Beinhocker, E.D. (2006) Origin of Wealth: Evolution, Complexity, and the Radical Remaking of Economics, 1st edn, Harvard Business School Press, Cambridge, Mass.
  4. van den Bergh, C.J.M. (2002) Handbook of Environmental and Resource Economics, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham.
  5. Bhattacharya, K., Mukherjee, G., Saramäki, J., Kaski, K., and Manna, S.S. (2008) The international trade network: weighted network analysis and modelling. Journal of Statistical Mechanics: Theory and Experiment, 2008 (02), P02 002.
  6. Blöchl, F., Theis, F.J., Vega-Redondo, F., and Fisher, E.O. (2011) Vertex centralities in input-output networks reveal the structure of modern economies. Physical Review E, 83 (4), 046 127.
  7. Deming, W.E. and Stephan, F.F. (1940) On a least squares adjustment of a sampled frequency table when the expected marginal totals are known. The Annals of Mathematical Statistics, 11 (4), 427–444.
  8. Duchin, F. (2004) International trade: evolution in the thought and analysis of Wassily Leontief. Wassily Leontief and Input-Output Economics, pp. 47–64.
  9. Economist, T. (2012) The End of Cheap China. The Economist.
  10. Fedriani, E.M. and Tenorio, A.F. (2012) Simplifying the input–output analysis through the use of topological graphs. Economic Modelling, 29 (5), 1931–1937.
  11. Hendrickson, C.T., Lave, L.B., and Matthews, H.S. (2006) Environmental Life Cycle Assessment of Goods and Services: An Input-Output Approach, RFF Press, Washington, DC.
  12. Joshi, S. (1999) Product environmental life-cycle assessment using input-output techniques. Journal of Industrial Ecology, 3 (2-3), 95–120.
  13. Khan, H.A. (1999) Sectoral growth and poverty alleviation: a multiplier decomposition technique applied to South Africa. World Development, 27 (3), 521–530.
  14. Lenzen, M., Moran, D., Kanemoto, K., and Geschke, A. (2013) Buxsilding Eora: a global multi-region input-output database at high country and sector resolution. Economic Systems Research, 25 (1), 20–49.
  15. Leontief, W. (1970) Environmental repercussions and the economic structure: an input-output approach. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 52 (3), 262–271.
  16. Leontief, W. (1974) Structure of the world economy. Outline of a simple input-output formulation. The Swedish Journal of Economics, 76 (4), 387–401. ArticleType: research-article / Full publication date: December, 1974 / Copyright © 1974 The Scandinavian Journal of Economics.
  17. Li, H., Li, L., Wu, B., and Xiong, Y. (2012) The end of cheap Chinese labor. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 26 (4), 57–74.
  18. Luo, J. (2013) The power-of-pull of economic sectors: a complex network analysis. Complexity, 18 (5), 37–47.
  19. Miller, R.E. and Blair, P.D. (1985) Input-Output Analysis: Foundations and Extensions, Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ.
  20. Nystuen, J.D. and Dacey, M.F. (1961) A graph theory interpretation of nodal regions. Papers of the Regional Science Association, 7 (1), 29–42.
  21. Ramalingam, B., Jones, H., Reba, T., and Young, J. (2009) Exploring the science of complexity: ideas and implications for development and humanitarian efforts.
  22. Serrano, M.A. and Boguñá, M. (2003) Topology of the world trade web. Physical Review E, 68 (1), 015 101.
  23. Spearman, C. (1904) The proof and measurement of association between two things. The American Journal of Psychology, 15 (1), 72–101.
  24. Streicher, G. and Stehrer, R. (2012) Whither Panama? Constructing a consistent and balanced world SUT system including international trade and transport margins. Economic Systems Research, 27 (2), 213–237.
  25. Timmer, M.P., Dietzenbacher, E., Los, B., Stehrer, R., and de Vries, G.J. (2015) An Illustrated User Guide to the World Input–Output Database: the Case of Global automotive production. Review of International Economics, doi: 10.1111/roie.12178.
  26. Tukker, A. and Dietzenbacher, E. (2013) Global multiregional input–output frameworks: an introduction and outlook. Economic Systems Research, 25 (1), 1–19.
  27. Tukker, A., de Koning, A., Wood, R., Hawkins, T., Lutter, S., Acosta, J., Rueda Cantuche, J.M., Bouwmeester, M., Oosterhaven, J., Drosdowski, T., and Kuenen, J. (2013) Exiopol—development and illustrative analyses of a detailed global MR EE SUT/IOT. Economic Systems Research, 25 (1), 50–70.
  28. Walmsley, T., Aguiar, A., and Narayanan, B. (2012) Introduction to the global trade analysis project and the GTAP data base, Working Paper 67, Center for Global Trade Analysis, Purdue University.
  29. World Bank (2014) World Development Indicators 2014, doi: 10.1596/978-1-4648-0163-1.

Appendix

Here, we outline some additional details of the set-up of the model.

A.1 Modelling the ‘Rest of the World’

The UN trade data records flows to and from many countries (as well as many non-country ‘trade areas’) which are not part of WIOD. If these flows were simply ignored, then countries which trade significantly with these areas would be misrepresented in terms of the extent to which they trade with the countries which are in the model. To avoid this, the model includes a ‘rest of the world’ (RoW) entity which receives all exports going to countries not explicitly modelled (‘stray’ exports) and provides all imports coming from such countries (‘stray imports’). The RoW has no technical coefficients and no import ratios.

The RoW is initialised to have a final demand, c04-math-0195, equal to the total stray exports in each sector across the whole model.15 Then, since the RoW has no import ratios, instead of solving Equation (4.13) to calculate import demand, it simply sets

4.30 equation

thus importing a fixed amount of each sector, defined by the initial level of stray exports in the data. The RoW also has a particular way of deriving its total production, c04-math-0197. It has no technical coefficients, so cannot solve Equation (4.12). Rather, it simply sets

4.31 equation

which allows it to produce ‘for free’ (in the sense that there is no intermediate demand) whatever is required of it from other countries. This also has the effect of decoupling the RoW's import side from its export side.

Other than these aspects, the RoW behaves just like a normal country: it has a set of import propensities defining its imports from each other country, and each other country will have an import propensity relating to trade with the RoW.

A.2 Services Trade Data

Data on trade in goods are based on the very detailed records kept by border agencies for gathering the appropriate taxes. For this reason, the goods trade data can be considered to be of high quality. Since the supply of services is harder to track, the data on trade in service goods16 are considerably coarser. Specifically, many countries report only the total quantity of services imported and exported, not the origin and destination of any particular bilateral trade flow. In order to estimate the bilateral flows required by Equation (4.15) for the calculation of import propensities, these flow totals must first be divided between trade partners.17

This is done using a method of iterative proportional fitting introduced by Deming and Stephan 1940. The basic algorithm for balancing c04-math-0199 totals into a matrix of c04-math-0200 bilateral flows works as follows:

  1. 1. Initialise an c04-math-0201 matrix with 1s (or any other arbitrary starting value)
  2. 2. Multiply each row vector such that the sum of the elements is equal to the required total outflow
  3. 3. Multiply each column vector in an identical manner such that they sum to the required total inflow
  4. 4. Iterate Steps 2 and 3 until the system converges (in the sense of the sum of the squared difference between each element in the matrix of the current iteration and that of the previous iteration being less than some c04-math-0202)

The procedure is followed c04-math-0203 times, producing one flow matrix per sector, with two changes specific to this situation.

A.2.1 Importing Own Exports

The commodities trade data report no flows originating from and arriving to the same country. The import propensities c04-math-0204 are therefore set to zero. To ensure that the outcome of the fitting procedure adheres to this, the initial matrix is modified to have a zero along its diagonal. Since the fitting consists only of multiplications, any zeros in the initial matrix will remain zero in the balanced matrix.

A.2.2 The Rest of the World for Sectors

Since total imports and total exports will inevitably not be equal per sector, a ‘rest of world’ (RoW) similar to that described in Appendix 1 is added to absorb any excess. If exports exceed imports, the RoW is added as an additional column (importer) and vice versa. The initial matrix is thus either wide or tall, depending on the relevant trade totals.

..................Content has been hidden....................

You can't read the all page of ebook, please click here login for view all page.
Reset
3.133.128.168