CHAPTER EIGHT
ORGANIZATIONAL STRUCTURE, DESIGN, TECHNOLOGY, INFORMATION TECHNOLOGY, AND SOCIAL MEDIA

The US Internal Revenue Reform and Restructuring Act of 1998 (known as RRA98) directed the IRS to redesign its structure. The IRS had operated for about half a century with the same geography-based structure; that is, the agency was organized on the basis of geographic regions and further subdivided into districts. Most of the important auditing, enforcement, and tax collection work occurred in the 33 geographic districts. The directors of these 33 districts had a lot of authority over what happened in their districts and often had considerable prestige and presence there as well. Most of the tax returns they received were sent to be processed at one of ten major service centers located around the nation.

As part of the set of reforms that RRA98 mandated, IRS executives led a major transformation in the agency's structure to a customer-focused design. The new commissioner of the IRS, Charles Rossotti, proposed the design as a version of similar approaches used by major banks. Large banks face a variety of demands from different clusters of their customers. Individual retail customers want checking accounts and small loans. Small businesses and self-employed persons have additional needs for business loans and payroll services. Very large corporations have further needs for support of their larger loans and payroll services, pension plans, and stock and bond offerings. The large banks have often designed their structures into divisions to address the needs of these different sets of customers.

The IRS developed a similar plan. The agency reorganized into four main operating divisions:

  • A wage and investment division, for taxpayers filing their individual income tax returns
  • A small business and self-employed division
  • A large and medium-sized business division
  • A tax-exempt and government entities division, which has no analog in the example about large banks; it deals with issues of concern to nonprofit organizations and tax-exempt pension programs

The IRS also established an agency-wide shared services division that handles many of the common service and support needs of the other parts of the agency, such as maintenance of personal computers and payroll processing. Many business firms and other organizations have recently established a division of this sort to handle widely shared common services.

Redesigning the IRS represented a huge undertaking, because the organization employs more than a hundred thousand people, processes more than 425 million tax returns per year, and handles well over a trillion dollars in revenue each year. The reorganization required several years and involved numerous design teams working on plans for the new organization. The new divisions came into operation in 2000 and 2001, and the success of the new design remains to be evaluated, but clearly the reorganization worked in the sense of firmly establishing the new structure.

Another organization that underwent redesign is the Brookhaven National Laboratory (BNL) on Long Island, which serves as an important scientific resource for the nation and the world (see www.bnl.gov). Scientists at BNL conduct leading research in physics, biology, chemistry, medicine, environmental science, and other areas. One major facility at BNL, the Relativistic Heavy Ion Collider, allows scientists to conduct experiments in which they use this massive particle accelerator to stage collisions between large subatomic particles and to study the results of the collisions for evidence about the fundamental characteristics of atomic particles and matter. Although scientists at BNL take pride in the lab's research in part because of its peacetime applications (as opposed to nuclear research for military applications), environmentalists and local residents have worried for a long time about the danger of environmental pollution from the lab. During the 1990s, the discovery and disclosure of a small leak of tritium, a radioactive substance, caused a public outcry. Although scientists at the lab considered the leak extremely minor and not at all dangerous, the news of the leak aggravated the long standing worries about the lab. Demonstrators conducted protests at the entrance to the lab compound. Celebrities, such as a supermodel and a famous actor, pled in public for the closing of the lab and claimed that it caused cancer in local residents. They and other activists prevailed upon political leaders in the area to do something about BNL.

Amid the controversy, the secretary of energy canceled the contract for the management of the lab. The lab is a government-owned, contractor-operated organization. Years ago, when the federal government established national laboratories, the management of the labs was contracted out. Under these contracts, private business firms or consortia of universities would manage the labs. Brookhaven had been managed for more than fifty years under a contract with a consortium of major universities. After the secretary of energy canceled the contract, the Department of Energy entered into a new contract with a partnership between a university and a major research institute, who provided the new management team for the lab.

Soon the administrative structure at BNL changed significantly. The main organizational departments, called directorates, included directorates for the major scientific programs in which the scientists conducted research, such as the directorate for high energy and nuclear physics, and for life sciences. There were also administrative directorates, such as the directorate for finance and administration. The new management group added additional administrative directorates: one for environment, safety, health, and quality, which oversees environmental protection and safety procedures at BNL, and one for community involvement, government, and public affairs. The directors who headed the directorates met regularly as a group with the director of the lab – the top administrator – and often voted on major issues. Scientists at the lab pointed out that the addition of the new administrative directorates meant that the administrative functions were receiving increased emphasis and influence. For example, more directors of administrative directorates meant more votes for administrative functions in the meetings with the lab director.

Soon the new management group also introduced requirements that employees working at BNL had to complete web-based training programs in laboratory safety procedures and waste disposal and environmental protection procedures. Many of the scientists grumbled about these requirements, because they saw them as unnecessary training in elementary procedures that they already followed. They felt that the new rules and procedures wasted time and resources because they tied up employees in completing the training instead of working on research. In addition, scientists at BNL often got grants from other sources to conduct research, and overhead expenses were taken out of their grants to pay for the added administrative functions and the additional training.

In effect, then, the new administrative directorates and the added administrative rules and procedures increased the importance of administrative controls and influences relative to scientific research priorities. Why did this occur? The new laboratory director explained that something had to be done to respond to the public controversy and outcry about the environmental dangers at BNL. Although the scientists at the lab grumbled about the new procedures, they expressed great respect for the director, a former university president and a scientist himself. The scientists acknowledged that he had to do something to respond to the political and public relations pressures on the lab.

These examples illustrate why the historical overview in Chapter Two and the discussion of organizational environments in Chapter Four show that so many factors – such as environmental complexity, public sector status (including political oversight and mandates), goals, and leadership – affect organizational structures and their design.

Organizational analysts have developed more than one definition of structure. Some management researchers distinguish organizational structure from an organization's technology and tasks. They use structure to refer to the configuration of the hierarchical levels and specialized units and positions in an organization and to the formal rules governing these arrangements. Technology and tasks refer to an organization's work processes, including the knowledge involved, that often serve as major influences on the design of organizational structure. Other definitions of structure combine elements of the organizational configuration with processes. For example, Mintzberg (1979) defines structure as the ways in which an organization divides its labor and integrates efforts.

As the historical review in Chapter Two showed, the concept of organizational structure has played a central role in organization and management theory from the beginning. Researchers have analyzed organizational technologies and tasks as important elements affecting the best structure. In spite of the constraints placed on them, public managers have considerable authority over the structure of their organizations and make many decisions in relation to technology and tasks, so current thinking on these topics is important to effective public management.

This chapter first discusses whether public organizations have distinctive structural characteristics, such as more red tape than private organizations. It then examines the importance of organizational structure and its relation to political power, strategy, and other topics. Next, it describes major concepts and findings from the research on organizational structure, technology, and design. Organization theorists have generally addressed structure from a generic perspective, devoting little attention to the distinctive structural attributes of public organizations, even though some important studies have concentrated on public agencies. These general points apply to most organizations, however, and the discussion here gives examples specifically involving public organizations. The chapter concludes by turning more directly to the evidence about whether public organizations differ in structure and design from private organizations.

Do Public Organizations Have Distinctive Structural Characteristics?

Novels, essays, and popular stereotypes have all bemoaned the absurdity and inhumanity of government bureaucracies. Their observations often focus on structural matters, such as rigid rules and hierarchies. More formal scholarship often follows suit. In a virtual tradition among some economists, government bureaucracies play the role of villain, sometimes threatening both prosperity and freedom. In probably the most widely cited book on bureaucracy ever published, Downs (1967) argues that government bureaucracies inevitably move toward rigidity and hierarchical constraints. He states a “law of hierarchy” that holds that large government organizations, with no economic markets for their outputs, have more elaborate and centralized hierarchies than do private business firms. Downs's law represents a broad consensus that government bureaucracies have exceedingly complex rules, red tape, and hierarchies, even in comparison with large private sector organizations (Barton, 1980; Bozeman, 2000; Dahl and Lindblom, 1953; Lindblom, 1977; Sharkansky, 1989).

An opposite consensus also exists, however. Organization theorists' research on organizational structure offers the best-developed concepts and empirical findings on the topic. Yet as the first several chapters of this book pointed out, most organization theorists have not regarded public organizations as a particularly distinctive category. They have usually adopted a generic perspective that contends that their concepts of structure apply broadly across many types of organizations with distinctions such as “public” and “private” regarded as oversimplified and based on crude stereotypes. Many organization theorists regard other factors, such as organizational size, environmental complexity, and technology, as more important influences on structure than public or private status. Mainstream organization theory in effect sharply disputes the view that public bureaucracies have excessive red tape and highly centralized and elaborate hierarchies.

We will further examine the evidence in this controversy later in this chapter. First, however, we will review the concepts and insights about organizational structure developed by organization theorists and how they apply to public organizations – because they do. Most of the research comparing public and private organizations' structures use these concepts and methods from organization theory. After reviewing these concepts, we will turn to the evidence comparing public and private organizational structures, which will show some very interesting developments in this research, some of them quite recent. To some people, carefully examining research on the structures of public bureaucracies and business firms sounds about as inviting as reading the telephone book. But if you like to base your thinking on well-developed evidence instead of on stereotypes and the half-baked assertions we hear in popular discourse, following and interpreting the research on this topic is an intriguing challenge.

The Development of Research on Structure

We have already seen examples of the influence of political actors and government authorities on the structures of public agencies: legislation and political pressures that force structural changes; rules and clearances imposed on federal managers by oversight agencies; micromanagement by legislators who specify rules and organizational structure; legislators and interest groups jealously guarding the structural autonomy of an agency, preventing its reorganization under the authority of another organization; and President Reagan's demotion of federal career civil servants by creating new positions above them. Presidents have created new agencies and placed them outside existing agencies to keep them away from those agencies' powerful political and administrative coalitions (Seidman and Gilmour, 1986). John Kennedy placed the Peace Corps outside the State Department, and Lyndon Johnson kept the youth employment training programs of the Office of Economic Opportunity away from the Department of Labor. Interest group pressures have led to the removal of bureaus from larger agencies. Due to such pressures, Congress removed the Department of Education from the Department of Health, Education, and Welfare, which then became the Department of Health and Human Services (HHS) (Radin and Hawley, 1988). Later, similar political pressures led Congress to remove the Social Security Administration (SSA) from HHS.

Interestingly, however, early in this century, public administration experts leading the development of the field did not emphasize such political dynamics in their most prominent analyses of government organizations. Proponents of the Administrative Management School argued that its principles of administration applied equally well in government and business organizations. These principles were to guide decisions about structure that would maximize efficiency and performance. Even though it tended to downplay distinctions between government and business, this drive toward developing efficient, effective structure drew strength from important issues in government at the time. A reform movement, which was active in the latter part of the nineteenth century and the earlier decades of the twentieth, attacked government corruption and mismanagement, particularly in urban areas. Reformers saw these principles as guidelines for efficient structuring of organizations to purge political patronage and slovenly management (Knott and Miller, 1987).

Later, government growth during the New Deal and after World War II brought a vast proliferation of government agencies. Gulick and other proponents of the principles of the administrative management school influenced major proposals for reorganizing the sprawling federal bureaucracy and played an important role in major developments in the structure of the federal government. For example, some of the reforms proposed grouping various federal agencies under larger “umbrella” agencies as a means of narrowing the chief executive's span of control. During past decades, some experts have argued that many government officials continue to hold the general view of proper organization espoused by the administrative management school (Knott and Miller, 1987; Seidman and Gilmour, 1986; Warwick, 1975).

As explained in Chapter Two, the classic approach to structure came under criticism as research on organizations burgeoned during the middle of the twentieth century. The contingency perspective on organizational structure rejected the quest for one common set of principles to guide organizational design. Contingency theorists contended that an organization's structure must be adapted to key contingencies facing the organization, such as environmental variations and uncertainty, the demands of technology or the production process, the size of the organization, and strategic decisions by managers and coalitions within the organization.

Empirical studies in the 1960s and 1970s added to this perspective, seeking to define and measure structural concepts. By the 1970s, research journals were filled with empirical studies analyzing these concepts. The activity led to the fairly typical version of contingency frameworks that we will examine next, and to the topic of organizational design, which we will take up after that.

During the 1980s and 1990s, the literature on organizations and the practice of management within them moved still further in the direction described in Chapter Two: away from bureaucratized, mechanistic structures and toward flexible, organic structures. Management mavens touted extremely loose and informal structure as the ideal (Peters, 1988). Many large corporations launched initiatives to decentralize their structure and make themselves more flexible, and business periodicals carried stories about “bureaucracy-busting” executives. By the turn of the new century, experts on organizational design were describing how many corporations had adopted “lateral,” “horizontal,” or “team-based” structures in the quest for high levels of flexibility and adaptability.

The public sector followed the lead of the private sector in these directions (Barzelay, 1992). For example, the National Performance Review (described in Chapter Six) called for a 50% reduction in agency rules, eliminated the federal personnel manual as a symbolic gesture toward reducing personnel rules, and took other steps toward decentralizing and loosening up the bureaucratic structure of the federal government. The Winter Commission, which proposed ways of revitalizing state and local public service, also proposed reducing bureaucratic rules and decentralizing procedures. Among other proposals, the commission called for “flattening” the bureaucracy by eliminating middle layers in public agencies, and “deregulating” government by eliminating many personnel rules and decentralizing procedures (Thompson, 1993). State and local governments in the US have also undertaken reforms to eliminate layers of middle management (Walters, 1996) and to loosen the rules that gave public employees merit system protections in their jobs (Walters, 2002). More recently, experts continue to advance proposals for more flexible government (National Academy of Public Administration, 2021). President Trump's efforts in 2020 to de-federalize disaster preparation provides an example. Trump called on state and local entities to fund their own training for disaster preparedness and proposed eliminating millions of grants from the Federal Emergency Management Agency.

The emphasis on decentralization and flexibility has had major influences on how practicing leaders, managers, and researchers think about the best ways to design organizations. Yet ideas and concepts developed by their predecessors continue to have relevance. Academic journal articles still address early topics about organizational structure such as centralization (e.g., see Joseph et al., 2016; 2018) and hierarchy (Keum and See, 2017). We still need such concepts to analyze organizations.

Structural Dimensions and Influences

Researchers developing definitions and measures of organizational structure have run into many complications. For example, you can measure structural features objectively (by counting the number of rules, e.g.,) or subjectively (by asking people how strictly they must follow the rules). In addition, organizations can be very complex, with different units having markedly different structures, and this makes it hard to develop an overall measure of an organization's structure.

Dimensions of Structure

Just as researchers have used varied definitions of structure, they also use different conceptualizations of what constitutes a structural dimension. Nevertheless, analysts have produced concepts that clarify the topic of structure (e.g., Hage, 1968; Porter and Lawler 1965; Pugh et al., 1968; Hall, Haas, and Johnson, 1967). Many of the dimensions identified in early research still play important roles in organizational theory (Daft, 2020; Hinings and Meyer, 2018; Hall and Tolbert, 2004; Kalleberg, Knoke, and Marsden, 2001; Kalleberg, Knoke, Marsden, and Spaeth, 1996).

These concepts include the following:

Size. Total organizational size, often measured by the number of full-time employees.

Centralization. The degree of centralization in an organization refers to the degree to which power and authority concentrate at the organization's higher levels (Prien and Ronan, 1971). Some researchers measure this dimension with questions about the location of decision-making authority (Pugh et al., 1968).

Configuration. The configuration refers to the “shape” of an organization's administrative apparatus or some aspect of it. This includes such measures as span of control (Porter and Lawler, 1965; Pugh et al., 1968), the number of levels in hierarchy (Hall et al., 1967), and the communications structure (Indik, 1968).

Specialization. This is the division of labor according to functional specialization (Sells, 1963) and/or task specialization (Indik, 1968).

Interdependence of subsystems. The degree of task interdependence or its opposite, the degree of autonomy, is identified with respect to internal functions (Sells, 1963).

Standardization of procedure. Standardization refers to the degree to which procedures are standardized (Prien and Ronan, 1971). Procedures that are not standardized are ad hoc.

Formalization of procedures. Formalization is the extent to which an organization's structures and procedures are formally established in written rules and regulations. Some researchers measure this element by asking employees how much they have to follow established rules, whether they must go through “proper channels,” and whether a rule manual exists (Hage and Aiken, 1969; see also, Pandey and Scott, 2002). Others determine whether the organization has organization charts, rule manuals, and other formal instructions (Kalleberg, Knoke, Marsden, and Spaeth, 1996; Pugh, Hickson, and Hinings, 1969).

Complexity. Organizational complexity is measured in terms of the number of subunits, levels, and specializations in an organization. Researchers break down this dimension further into sub-dimensions (Hall and Tolbert, 2004). Organizations vary in horizontal differentiation, or the specialized division of labor across subunits and individuals. To measure horizontal differentiation, some researchers have simply counted the number of subunits and individual specializations in an organization (Meyer, 1979; see also Blau and Schoenherr, 1971). Vertical differentiation refers to the number of hierarchical levels in an organization – its “tallness” or “flatness.”

The above dimensions are representative of concepts used in prominent studies. The relevance of each dimension depends on the research context. For example, in public management, a stream of research focuses on whether rules and procedures facilitate or hamper performance. These researchers distinguish between rules that provide needed guidance and rules that are more onerous than needed. A similar but distinct research stream concerns the effects of administrative burdens.

Red Tape. Red tape consists of burdensome administrative rules and requirements. Sociologists and psychologists who study organizations have not used this concept a great deal, but scholars in public administration have recently refined and applied the concept in research on organizations. In earlier work, Bozeman (1993) defined red tape as “rules, regulations, and procedures that remain in force and entail a compliance burden” but “have no efficacy for the rules' functional object” (p. 283). He later revised his definition to associate red tape with performance, defining red tape as “burdensome administrative rules and procedures that have negative effects on the organization's performance” (Bozeman, 2000). Other researchers have expanded this research (e.g., Bozeman, 2000; Bozeman and Feeney, 2011; DeHart-Davis and Pandey, 2005; Pandey and Welch, 2005; Heinrich et al., 2020; Kaufman et al., 2021).

Administrative Burdens. An administrative burden refers to an individual's experience of policy implementation as onerous (Herd and Moynihan, 2018). Burdens affect citizens' access to public services. In explaining the differences between red tape and administrative burdens, Moynihan and Herd emphasize three categories of costs that individuals experience in their interactions with government: learning costs, psychological costs, and compliance costs. These costs are discussed in more detail later in the chapter.

Influences on Structure

Research has also analyzed influences on organizational structure. The following sections describe research about influences on the structural dimensions discussed previously.

Size. Various studies have shown that larger organizations tend to be more structurally complex than smaller ones, with more levels, departments, and job titles (e.g., Kalleberg, Knoke, Marsden, and Spaeth, 1996; Pugh, Hickson, and Hinings, 1969). However, Blau and Schoenherr (1971) also concluded that the rate at which complexity increases with size falls off at a certain point; organizations that reach this point grow larger without adding new departments and levels as rapidly as they did before. In addition, this research indicates that larger organizations tend to have less administrative overhead. So, contrary to stereotypes and popular books about bureaucracy (Parkinson, 1957), larger organizations often have smaller percentages of their personnel involved in administrative work.

Argyris (1972) criticized the findings about public organizations in some studies of organizational size. He noted that Blau studied government agencies controlled by civil service systems and, in drawing his conclusions, applied the results to all organizations. Civil service regulations may have caused these organizations to emphasize task specialization and narrow spans of control and thus grow in the patterns that Blau observed. Business organizations might not follow these patterns, however. In contrast to the findings of a study of state employment agencies by Blau and Schoenherr (1971), Beyer and Trice (1979), studying a set of federal agencies, found no direct relationship between size and vertical or horizontal differentiation. Ultimately, they concluded that increased size increases the division of labor, which in turn increases vertical and horizontal complexity. In addition, the relationships among size, division of labor, and vertical and horizontal differentiation were stronger in federal units doing routine work than in those doing nonroutine work. Thus larger public organizations tend toward somewhat greater structural complexity (more levels and subunits, greater division of labor) than smaller ones. Much larger organizations almost certainly show more complexity than much smaller ones, but the effects of size are not clear-cut.

Other researchers have reported further evidence that size has little clear influence on structure. Reviewing this research, Kimberly (1976) pointed out that size is actually a complex variable with different components, such as number of employees and net assets. This complicates conclusions about the influence of size. Even so, in the National Organizations Study (Kalleberg, Knoke, Marsden, and Spaeth, 1996), described by its authors as the first analysis of organizations based on a national probability sample, size figured as one of the important correlates of organizational structural characteristics.

According to the well-known “Schumpeterian hypothesis” due to economies of scale, most innovation and technical change can be attributed to giant corporations and imperfect competitors. However, David Audretsch and his colleagues provide strong evidence that economies of scale do not play an important role in the production of output (e.g., Acs and Audretsch, 1990, 1991); their findings imply no relationship between size and innovation and suggest small organizations can be just as innovative as large organizations. This finding appears to hold for multiple sectors and countries. For example, in a sample of Austrian firms, Hutschenreiter and Leo (2013) regress R&D expenditure and innovation expenditure on organization size variables (employment and sales) and do not find a more than proportional relationship (contrary to Schumpter). Moreover, they find a lower relationship at lower levels (degressive relationship) when they model the impact of the size variables on R&D employees.

Centralization/Decentralization. Centralization is one of the earliest themes in the literature on organizational structure that continues to be of interest to researchers (e.g., see Joseph et al., 2016; for a review see Joseph et al., 2018). Siggelkow and Levinthal (2003) examined how decentralization impacts the search for high-performing activities and found that decentralization allows for the sufficient exploration of new combinations of activities; they also found that switching back to centralization (reintegration) is required to account for all interdependencies among activities. Research by Nickerson and Zenger (2002) implies similar performance advantages when an organization alternates between efficient and flexible structures. And, Joseph, Klingebiel, and Wilson (2016) find that centralized managers are more likely to change strategy associated with unsuccessful products; this finding suggests decentralized decision makers may not be in the best position to halt a losing strategy. However, environmental turbulence and complexity may be important boundary conditions for the advantages of such centralization (Siggelkow and Rivkin, 2005).

Configuration. Wu (2014) found an association between span of control and the production of high-value products. The greater the span of control (flatter organization with more intensive vertical interactions), the more likely was the production of higher value products. The same research also finds a more pronounced (positive) effect with more communication.

Specialization. Establishing hierarchies and specialization are among the ways organizations integrate (Lawrence and Lorsch, 1967). Both approaches have their advantages and disadvantages. For example, a hierarchy may impose divisions or new vocabularies. Alternatively, it may strengthen existing complementarities among subdivisions (Rafaelli, Glynn, and Tushman, 2019; see Keum and See, 2017 for a review).

Interdependence of subsystems. Aggarwal and Wu (2015) examined firms in the US defense system industry between 1996 and 2006. The scholars found that coordination across product area creates greater adaption challenges than does coordination within product interaction. That is, higher product complementarity is mitigated when interdependencies are grouped by organizational units.

Complexity. Siggelkow (2002) treats the degree of interactions between activities as complexity. Exploring the effects of managers not fully understanding the degree of interactions among activities, he finds managers' misperceptions involving complementary activities are costlier than those involving substitute activities because complements tend to amplify the performance consequences.

Red Tape. Research on red tape continues to be of interest to public management researchers. A key claim in the literature is that rules are either designed as ineffective or become ineffective during implementation (Bozeman, 1993, 2000; Bozeman and Feeney, 2011; DeHart-Davis et al., 2014). According to one review of the literature, over the last two decades, scholars have produced more than 50 articles on its effects (Bozeman and Feeney, 2011, p. 13; see also DeHart-Davis et al., 2014). Red tape research has produced several negative findings with respect to impacts on organizational performance, including reduced services to clients (Scott and Pandey, 2000), role ambiguity (Pandey and Rainey, 2006), managerial alienation (DeHart-Davis and Pandey, 2005), and lower morale (DeHart-Davis and Pandey, 2005; Pandey and Kingsley, 2000; Quratulain and Khan, 2013; Wright and Davis, 2003). One of the impediments to this research is the challenge of distinguishing between helpful rules and onerous rules (see also Maynard-Moody and Musheno, 2003; Oberfield, 2010; Walker and Brewer, 2008). In an attempt to overcome the problem, DeHart-Davis (2009) introduced a theory of green tape (effective rules). In subsequent research, DeHart Davis et al. (2014) put the theory to a partial test. They find a positive relationship between consistent rule application, optimal control, and job satisfaction.

Administrative Burdens. Recent research on administrative burdens provides another perspective on organizational design (e.g., Heinrich, 2016; Herd and Moynihan, 2018). This research has particular relevance to public organizations, to public service delivery and policy implementation, and to citizen relationships with government. It has political and psychological dimensions and draws from political science, law, and behavioral economics. Administrative burdens are similar but distinct from administrative discretion, rules, and red tape. In explaining the differences in these concepts, Herd and Moynihan point to three categories of costs that individuals experience in their interactions with government. Learning costs include time and effort to learn about a service or program and about one's eligibility status. Psychological costs include frustration at dealing with time-consuming and unfair procedures. Compliance costs involve financial costs of access, such as fees for transportation or legal representation. Research on administrative burdens conceives of organizational performance as including the quality of the relationship between the citizen and the state. Administrative burdens affect how citizens perceive their government, including whether they trust government, believe government is fair, and consider their participation worthwhile. It adds to a substantial volume of work on public sector performance measurement, such as that of Carolyn Heinrich and her colleagues (e.g., Heinrich, 2012; Heinrich and Marschke, 2003, 2012; Heinrich et al., 2020) and including their recent work on the effects of implementation processes on equity.

Information processing and decision making. Theory and research connecting organizational structure, information processing, and decision making has gained traction over the last few decades (Burton, 2013). Some authors have referred to this literature as the neo-Carnegie perspective (Gavetti et al., 2007). A good deal of the research takes the work of Herbert Simon as a starting point. Herbert Simon considered the key problem regarding organizational structure to be “how to organize to make decisions – that is, to process information” (1997, p. 240). Joseph and Gaba (2015) identify four major streams of this research: problem-skills matching, screening, learning/adaptation, and cognition. Research on problem-skills matching is grounded in organizational economics; using a decision-theoretic approach, this research focuses on coordinating the tasks and skills used to make decisions. Screening concerns the screening of information by individuals situated in different structures, including how decision rules affect the quality of decisions and how hierarchies affect psychological biases (e.g., Sah and Stiglitz, 1985, 1988, comparing the screening properties of hierarchies and polyarchies; see also Christensen and Knudsen, 2010, building upon their insights). Research in the domain of learning/adaptation focuses on how organizations adapt via trial-and-error, experiential, or reinforcement learning (indicated by updated actions in response to performance feedback), given that bounded rational individuals satisfice in their decision making (e.g., Denrell and March, 2001). The cognition stream that broadly deals with the relationship between organizational structure, individual cognition, and decision making includes such themes as knowledge sharing, hierarchy, and coupled search (e.g., Gavetti and Levinthal, 2000; Gavetti et al., 2012).

Environment. Chapter Four discussed the effects of organizational environments. One of the classic observations in organizational analysis maintains that a formalized, centralized structure performs well enough in a simple, stable environment, where it can take advantage of specialization and clear patterns of communication and authority. As the environment presents more changes and more uncertainty, however, strict rules, job descriptions, and chains of command become more cumbersome and managers are unable to evolve and process information rapidly enough. Therefore, rules and assignments have to become more flexible. Communication needs to move laterally among people and units, not strictly up and down a hierarchy. People working at lower levels must be given more authority to decide without having to ask permission up the chain of command. As its environment becomes more fragmented, an organization must reflect this complexity in its own structure, giving the people in the units that confront these multiplying environmental segments the authority they need to respond to the conditions they encounter. Although in some ways this general perspective was superseded by more recent perspectives on organizations (Aldrich, Ruef, and Lippman, 2020), it still exerts great influence on current prescriptions for managers (Daft, 2020; Galbraith, 2014).

More recent approaches, such as institutional models, contend that organizations adopt rules and structural arrangements because of prevailing beliefs about their appropriateness or because of influences from external institutions such as government. As we have seen, a number of researchers have advanced claims and evidence that governmental ownership and funding have important influences on the structures of public organizations.

Technology and Tasks. A number of studies indicate that an organization's structure also depends on the nature of its work processes, that is, its technologies and tasks. Researchers use a wide variety of definitions of technology and tasks, such as the interdependence required by and the routineness of the work. The effects on structure depend on which of these definitions one uses (Tehrani, Montanari, and Carson, 1990).

In his influential book, Organizations in Action, Thompson (1967) analyzes technology in terms of the type of interdependence among workers and units the work requires. Organizations such as banks and insurance companies have mediating technologies. They deal with many individuals who need largely the same set of services, such as checking accounts or insurance policies. Their work involves pooled interdependence because it pools together such services and sets of clients. They establish branches that have little interdependence with one another and formulate standardized rules and procedures to govern them. Long-linked technologies, such as typical assembly line operations, have a sequential pattern of interdependence. One unit completes its work and passes the product along to the next unit, which completes another phase of the work, and so on. Plans and schedules become an important coordination tool for these units. Units with intensive technologies have a reciprocal pattern of interdependence. The special units in a hospital or a research and development (R&D) laboratory need to engage in a lot of back-and-forth communication and adjustment in the process of completing the work. These units must be close together and coordinated through mutual adjustments and informal meetings. Thompson contended that organizations may have all these forms of interdependence. They will first organize together those persons and units that have reciprocal interdependence and require high levels of mutual adjustment. Then they will organize together those units with sequential interdependence, and then group units with pooled interdependence (such as the branches of a bank around a city). Analyzing many studies of structure, Tehrani, Montanari, and Carson (1990) found some support for Thompson's observations.

One can find examples of public organizations that follow the patterns that Thompson described. The SSA operates regional service centers around the country that process beneficiaries' claims, or applications for Social Security benefits. These centers provide an example of pooled interdependence and mediating technology. For a long time, within these centers, employees and units that processed the claims were organized as a long-linked technology. One large unit would perform one step or phase in the processing of a claim, such as claims authorization, in which a specialist ensures that the client's claim is legal and acceptable. Then the claim would be delivered to another department in the service center where another specialist would perform the next phase of processing the claim, which involved calculating the amount the beneficiary would receive in monthly Social Security payments. Then the claim would go through several more steps in processing, such as recording and filing the claim in the beneficiary's record. As the population of beneficiaries grew and became more complex, however, and as the Social Security eligibility rules became more complex, the people working on different parts of the claims processing procedure needed to communicate with one another more and more about individual cases. As a result, they sent cases back and forth between units, and this created backlogs. As Chapter Thirteen describes, the agency reorganized to establish modular work units, which brought together people from the different phases in single units. They could thus communicate and adjust more rapidly, an example of a more intensive technology. Other factors besides work processes influenced the reorganization, but Thompson's ideas about interdependence clearly apply.

Another very influential perspective on technology, developed by Perrow (1973), argues that work processes vary along two main dimensions: the frequency with which exceptions to normal procedures arise and the degree to which these exceptions are analyzable (that is, the degree to which they can be solved through a rational, systematic search). If a machine breaks down, often a clear set of steps can lead to fixing it. If a human being breaks down psychologically, usually few systematic procedures lead as directly to diagnosis and treatment.

Organizational technologies can rank high or low on either of these two main dimensions. Routine technologies involve few exceptions and provide clear steps in response to any that occur (high analyzability). In such cases, the work is usually programmed through plans and rules, because there is little need for intensive communication and individual discretion in performing the work. For examples of routine technology, researchers usually point to the work of many manufacturing personnel, auditors, and clerical personnel. At the opposite extreme, non-routine technologies involve many exceptions, which are less analyzable when they occur. Units and organizations doing this type of work tend toward flexible, “polycentralized” structures, with power and discretion widely dispersed and with much interdependence and mutual adjustment among units and people. Units that are engaged in strategic planning, R&D, and psychiatric treatment apply such non-routine technologies.

Between these extremes, Perrow suggests, are two intermediate categories: craft technology and engineering technology. Craft technology involves infrequent exceptions but offers no easily programmed solutions when they occur. Government budget analysts, e.g., may work quite routinely but with few clear guidelines on how to deal with the unpredictable variations that may arise, such as unanticipated shortfalls. These organizations tend to be more decentralized than those with routine technologies. Engineering technology involves many exceptions but also offers analyzable responses to them. Engineers may encounter many variations, but often they can respond in systematic, programmed ways. Lawyers and auditors often deal with this type of work. When an Internal Revenue Service (IRS) auditor examines a person's income tax return, many unanticipated questions come up about whether certain of the person's tax deductions can be allowed. The auditor can resolve many of the questions, however, by referring to written rules and guidelines. Organizations with engineering technologies tend to be more centralized than those with nonroutine technologies, but more flexibly structured than those with routine technologies. Tehrani, Montanari, and Carson (1990) also found support for Perrow's observations. They reviewed numerous studies that showed that organizational units with routine technologies had more formal rules and procedures and fewer highly educated and professional employees.

Perrow's analysis has applications to public organizations. In a study of state employment agencies, Van de Ven, Delbecq, and Koenig (1976) used questionnaire items about task variability and task difficulty based on Perrow's work. The questions asked about how much the work involves the same tasks and issues, how easy it is to know whether the work is being done correctly, and similar issues. The researchers found relationships between the structures and coordination processes in organizational units and the nature of their tasks. Some units, such as units that handled applications for unemployment compensation, had tasks low in uncertainty (low in variability and difficulty). The employees mainly filled out and submitted application forms for the persons who came in to seek unemployment compensation. These units had more plans and rules and fewer scheduled and unscheduled meetings than other units, and relatively little horizontal communication among individuals and units. Other units had tasks higher in task uncertainty, such as the unemployment counseling bureau, which helped unemployed people seek jobs. This task involved many variations in the characteristics of the clients – in their needs and skills, for example – and often there was no clearly established procedure for responding to some of these unique variations. In this bureau, employees relied little on plans and rules and had more scheduled and unscheduled meetings and more horizontal communication than other units. Units that were intermediate on the task dimensions fell in the middle ranges on the structural and coordination dimensions. So, in many government agencies, in spite of the external political controls, subunits tend toward more flexible structures when they have uncertain, non-routine, variable tasks.

Yet Perrow himself pointed out that organizations doing the same work can define the nature of it differently. Job Corps training centers for disadvantaged youths in the 1960s were first operated by personnel from the US Office of Economic Opportunity, who adopted a nurturant approach to running the centers. Serious disciplinary problems led to the transfer of some of the centers to the Department of the Interior, after which the staff increasingly emphasized strict rules and discipline and highly structured routines. The same organization in effect altered its definitions of the same task. Similarly, many organizations have purposely tried to transform routine work into more interesting, flexible work to better motivate and utilize the skills of the people doing it. The SSA changed to modular work units partly for such reasons.

Also complicating the analysis of technology, various studies have found weak relationships between structure and technology, sometimes finding that size influences structure more than technology does. Research indicates that technology shows stronger effects on structure in smaller organizations than in larger ones (Tehrani, Montanari, and Carson, 1990). Similarly, the effects of task characteristics on structure are strongest within task subunits; that is, the task of a bureau within a larger organization has a stronger relationship to the structure of that bureau than to the structure of the larger organization. In sum, factors such as size, technology, and structure have complex interrelationships.

Information Technology. Increasingly, organizational researchers and managers have to try to assess the influence of information technology (IT) on organizational design. The advent and dissemination of computers, the Internet, e-mail, and other forms of information and communication technology have transformed organizations and working life within them and continue to have dramatic effects. A later section of this chapter reviews recent literature on the effects of IT.

Strategic Choice. Managers' strategic choices also determine structure. Managers may separate an organization into divisions and departments designed to handle particular markets, products, or challenges that have been chosen for strategic emphasis. In the examples at the beginning of this chapter, the IRS's reorganizing for a more customer-oriented structure was part of a major strategic reorientation that IRS leadership sought to develop; and the changes in structure at BNL – the new directorates and new rules and procedures – represented strategic decisions about how to respond to intense challenges and pressures from the environment.

Organizational Design

Work on contingency theory led to the development of literature offering guidelines for managers and others engaged in designing organizations (Burton, Obel, and Hakonsson, 2020; Daft, 2020; Galbraith, 2014; Mintzberg, 1979, 1983). Although these authors usually do not consider the distinctiveness of public organizations, many of the concepts they discuss apply in public management.

Design Strategies

Jay Galbraith (1977) proposed a set of techniques for designing and coordinating activities in organizations that is based on an information-processing approach. Organizations face varying degrees of uncertainty, depending on how much more information they need than they actually have. As this uncertainty increases, the organizational structure must process more information. Organizations employ a mix of alternative modes for coordinating these activities. First, they use the organizational hierarchy of authority, in which superiors direct subordinates, answering their questions and specifying rules and procedures for managing the information processing load. As uncertainty increases, it overwhelms these approaches. The next logical strategy, then, is to set plans and goals and allow subordinates to pursue them with less referral up and down the hierarchy and with fewer rules. They can also narrow spans of control so that superiors must deal with fewer subordinates and can process more information and decisions.

Many contemporary organizations operate under such great uncertainty that these basic modes become overloaded, so they must pursue additional alternatives. First, managers can try to reduce the need for information. They can engage in environmental management to create more certainty through more effective competition for scarce resources, through public relations, and through cooperation and contracting with other organizations. They can create slack resources (that is, create a situation in which they have extra resources) by reducing the level of performance they seek to attain, or they can create self-contained tasks, such as profit centers or groups working independently on individual components of the work. Alternatively, managers can increase information-processing capacity by investing in vertical information systems, such as computerized information management systems, or by creating lateral relations, such as task forces or liaison personnel. Thus, managers have to adopt coordination modes in response to greater uncertainty and information processing demands. In recent work, Galbraith (2014) exemplifies the movement among organizations and organization design experts toward increasing emphasis on flexibility and rapid adaptation to complex and quickly changing challenges. He emphasizes processes for lateral coordination, including e-coordination, greater utilization of teams, and methods of designing reconfigurable organizations amenable to continuous redesign, as well as virtual corporation models, wherein an organization contracts out all activities except those at which it is superior (Galbraith, 2014).

Mintzberg's Synthesis

Mintzberg (1979) presented one of the most comprehensive reviews of the literature on structure, summarizing the set of structural alternatives that managers can pursue. Although his synthesis has grown somewhat dated in relation to the sorts of developments that Galbraith covered, many of the fundamental challenges for organization designers remain the same and Mintzberg's review still provides a valuable analysis of alternatives and distinctions. He began by setting forth his own scheme for describing the major components of organizations. They have an operating core, including members directly involved in the organization's basic work: police officers, machine operators, teachers, claims processors, and so on. The strategic apex consists of the top managerial positions: the board of directors, chief executive officer, president, and president's staff. The middle line includes the managers who link the apex to the core through supervision and implementation: the vice presidents down through the supervisors. Finally, two types of staff units complete the set of components. The technostructure consists of analysts who work on standardizing work, outputs, and skills: the policy analysts and program evaluators, strategic planners, systems engineers, and personnel training staff. The support staff units support the organization outside the workflow of the operating core: e.g., mail room, food service, and public relations personnel.

Design Parameters. Organizations establish structures to divide and then coordinate work within and among these units through the design of four different structural categories: positions, superstructures, lateral linkages, and decision-making systems.

Design of Positions. Individual positions can be established through job specialization, behavior formalization (written job descriptions, written work instructions, general rules), and training and indoctrination (in which individuals learn the skills they will apply using their own judgment).

Design of Superstructures. The different positions must be coordinated through the design of the organization's superstructure. All organizations do this in part through unit grouping, which is based on any of a number of criteria: knowledge and skill (lawyers, engineers, social workers), function (police, fire, and parks and recreation employees; military personnel), time (night shift, day shift), output (the products produced by the different divisions of a corporation), clients (inpatients or outpatients, beneficiaries of insurance policies), or place (the regional offices of business firms, the federal government, and many state agencies; precincts in a city police department).

Managers choose among these bases or some combination of them. We have little conclusive scientific guidance for those choices, but Mintzberg offered suggestions about criteria for grouping. It can follow workflow interdependencies, in which natural phases in the work require certain people to communicate closely or to be located near one another. Process interdependencies make it useful to group together people who perform the same type of work (attorneys, claims eligibility experts), so they can learn from one another and share tools and materials. Because of scale interdependencies, certain units may become large enough to need their own functional categories – their own set of attorneys, for example. Also, social interdependencies may make it useful to group individuals to facilitate social relations, morale, and cohesiveness. Military units that have trained together are often kept together for these reasons.

Design of Lateral Linkages. Mintzberg suggested that coordination also requires linking operations laterally. For this purpose, organizations can use performance-control systems, action-planning systems, or liaison devices. Performance-control systems specify general results to be attained as indications that operations are effectively coordinated. For example, as described in Chapter Thirteen, in large service centers operated by the SSA, employees are organized into “modules.” A module is a work unit that includes all the personnel required to handle a client's application for Social Security benefits (as well as other types of services), including people who authorize the benefits, people who calculate what the benefit payment will be, file clerks, typists, and other specialists. Administrators keep track of the average time the modules take in handling clients' requests: For example, how many days, on average, does each module take to complete the handling of a client's application? They can compare these times across modules and to national standards. A low average time (that is, fast processing of the requests) indicates effective coordination within the module. Good average times for all the modules suggest that the service center is effectively coordinated – that all modules are performing well. When a module falls behind the others and has backlogs of applications and slower times, however, this indicates a possible coordination problem – not just in that module, but among the modules. Sometimes a module may have an overload of particularly difficult cases or some personnel problems such as high absenteeism or a lot of newer employees who need training. The slower time for the module may thus indicate that the assignment of cases and personnel is not effectively coordinated among the modules, and administrators may shift some of the caseload to other modules or transfer some personnel among modules temporarily so as to better coordinate the work of the modules. Thus, the performance-control information provides evidence about coordination within and among units. (Of course, simple reviews of limited performance information, such as time taken to complete the processing of an application, can have serious pitfalls as an evaluation system, and managers must be sensitive to these weaknesses.)

An action-planning system, by contrast, specifies not the general result or standard but the details about actions that people and groups are to take. In the modules just mentioned, the applications from clients are placed in file folders that move from point to point in the modules as different people do their part of the work on the case. The filing clerks are trained in a system for moving and keeping track of the many thousands of files for each module, so they will not be lost and can be located at any given time. As the clerks move the files around the module, they log them in when they arrive at certain points, using a bar code scanner similar to those used in supermarkets. The careful specification of the actions of the file clerks in this file-tracking system is essential to coordinating the different specialists in the module and to assessing the coordination of the work among all the modules.

Liaison devices include such arrangements as having a person serve in a special position as “ambassador” to another unit, keeping track of developments there and facilitating communication with the other unit. Task forces or standing liaison committees can also address problems of coordination. One of the service centers used a task force to respond to a major coordination problem. The first three digits of a person's Social Security number indicate where that person was born or where he or she was when the number was issued. In the service centers, cases are usually assigned to modules on the basis of these first three digits. That alone can create coordination problems, because certain regions of the country produce more cases that are difficult to handle than other regions. Modules assigned to certain geographical areas may thus get more difficult cases than other modules. One service center considered moving its modules to “terminal digit case allocation” – that is, allocating cases on the basis of the last four digits of the Social Security number to achieve a fairer distribution. Yet moving to this new allocation system required extensive coordination among the modules because they had to transfer all the files among themselves to redistribute them according to the new system. The director of the center appointed a task force to consider and plan the new system. The task force was highly representative, with people from all levels and many different modules and units. Empowered by the director to plan and implement the new system as they saw fit, the task force effectively managed the transition to the new system.

Design of Decision-Making Systems Through Decentralization. Organizations can also decentralize. Vertical decentralization involves pushing decision-making authority down to lower levels. Horizontal decentralization involves spreading authority out to staff analysts or experts or across individuals involved in the work of the organization.

Types of Organizational Structures. Mintzberg also proposed a typology of five types of organizational structures, based on the employment of these design alternatives and shifts in the roles of the components described earlier. Simple structures are usually adopted by new, small government agencies, small corporations run by an entrepreneur, and other new, small, aggressive organizations headed by strong leaders. They tend toward vertical and horizontal centralization and coordination by means of direct supervision from a strong strategic apex. Machine bureaucracies include the prototypical large bureaucracies in the public and private sectors. They evolve from simple structures as growth, age, or external control lead to greater emphasis on standardizing work processes. The techno-structure becomes more important as experts and staff specialists assume roles in this process. Mintzberg suggested a subcategory—public machine bureaucracies—consisting of government agencies that assume this form because they are required to standardize for political oversight. Alternatively, simple structures with a strong professional component (law firms, research organizations) evolve toward professional bureaucracies, with a profession that dominates their operating core, coordination primarily through standardization of skills (through professional training) rather than standardization of tasks, and general decentralization. Machine bureaucracies may further evolve into divisionalized forms as further growth leads to economies of scale for product-oriented subunits. It becomes more cost-effective to break the organization up into product divisions with their own versions of the various functional components – e.g., their own manufacturing and marketing divisions. Mintzberg (1989) observed that public machine bureaucracies cannot do this. Without profit and sales measures by which their general performance can be monitored, and because they operate under more intensive, political oversight, public machine bureaucracies face more constraints on their ability to decentralize to relatively autonomous divisions than their private counterparts do. Finally, an adhocracy, such as NASA, or an innovation-oriented firm, has a very organic structure, with great emphasis on fluid communication and flexibility, largely through decentralization to project teams.

Major Design Alternatives

Functional Structures. Management writers also contrast the pros and cons of the major design alternatives from which organizations choose (Burton, Obel, and DeSanctis, 2011; Chichocki and Irwin, 2011; Daft, 2020; Galbraith, 2014). Functional structures, the classical prototype, organize according to major functions: marketing and sales, manufacturing, finance, R&D. The advantages include economies of scale within the functional units (e.g., all the attorneys in the legal department can use the same law library; the manufacturing personnel share plants and machinery). Departments concentrate on their functions and enhance their specialized skills. Yet this may weaken coordination with other functions to ensure overall product quality or the implementation of needed changes.

Product and Hybrid Structures. As organizations grow, producing more diverse products and competing in more diverse, rapidly changing markets, the functional structure proves too slow in responding to changes and too hierarchical to allow rapid coordination across functional divisions. Large corporations, such as the major automobile manufacturers, thus adopt product structures, with separate divisions, each responsible for its own product line. Each division possesses its own units to perform major functions such as sales and manufacturing (e.g., the Oldsmobile, Chevrolet, and Buick divisions of General Motors or, in a high-technology firm, divisions for medical instruments, personal computers, and electronic instruments). This approach sacrifices some of the advantages of the functional form, but it provides for more rapid responses to environmental changes (in product technology, customer demands, competitors) and greater concentration on the quality of the products rather than on individual functions. In fact, many corporations actually employ hybrid structures, with major product divisions (e.g., chemicals, fuels, lubricants; see Daft, 2020) but also some major functional units (finance, human resources).

Matrix Designs. During the past century, some firms developed a matrix structure in response to demands for both high-quality products in highly technical areas (product emphasis) and rapid and reliable production (functional emphasis). The sort of mixing or crosshatching of different types of responsibility and authority characteristic of matrix organizations evolved into different alternatives, but still occurs quite frequently. Military weapons manufacturers, e.g., faced pressure to produce highly technical weapons systems according to demanding standards, and to do so within sharp time constraints. Matrix structures purposely violate the classic prescriptions for “one master” and clear chains of authority. High-level managers share authority over the same activities, with some exercising functional authority (such as vice presidents for product development, manufacturing, marketing, procurement) and others having responsibility for the particular products or projects that cross all those functions. Thus, one manager may have responsibility for pushing the completion of a particular aircraft project, while others may share responsibility for the particular functions involved in getting the craft built. The authority of the product executives crosses all the functions, whereas the functional executives have authority over their functions across all the products. Diagrammed, this structure appears as a matrix of two sets of executives with crosshatched lines of authority. It offers the advantage of the ability to share or shift personnel or other resources rapidly across product lines and to coordinate the organization's response to dual pressures from the environment. However, it requires a heavy investment in coordination, liaison activities, and conflict resolution. Successful matrix designs often require a lot of training and good interpersonal skills on the part of managers, because such designs typically produce high levels of stress and conflict that must be resolved.

Some structures in the public sector have been equated with matrix structures. Simon (1983) described the use of a matrix management arrangement at the US Consumer Product Safety Commission. This commission was organized into functional bureaus, including the Bureau of Engineering, the Bureau of Economics, the Bureau of Biomedical Science, and so on. Each bureau had partial responsibility for developing regulations issued by the commission, but none had overall responsibility. The matrix arrangement involved six functional directorates and the Office of Program Management. The Office of Program Management had a program manager for each of a set of new product-oriented programs, including a chemical products program, an electrical products program, and a children's products program. These program managers chaired program teams made up of representatives from the various functional directorates. The teams managed the overall development of regulations for the products for which their programs were responsible, and they coordinated the work of the functional directorates pertaining to those programs. The commission's executives felt that the matrix arrangement would improve productivity, morale, effective use of resources, communication, and accountability, but it also increased stress and turf battles and evoked some resistance, as matrix arrangements usually do.

The executive director of the commission observed that public managers face particular challenges in adopting matrix designs. He felt that private executives have more authority over rewards and have profit targets to use as incentives for cooperation. Public executives can impose fewer sanctions and have weaker authority to reassign those who resist a new design. Here again we see that a design developed in industry has potential value in government but requires skillful implementation within the constraints imposed by the public sector. Swiss (1991) provided further examples of the use of matrix organization in city governments.

Market and Customer-Focused Designs. According to Galbraith (2014), many corporations have moved toward a market structure, in which the main organizational units are organized on the basis of their orientation to groupings of customers, markets, or industries. The IRS reorganization described at the beginning of the chapter exemplifies a customer-focused version of this alternative. The more frequent adoption of this structural form has been driven by the rise of the service industry, which increases the value of knowledge of market segments and customers, and by the increasing tendency to contract out functions and services, which reduces demands for large-scale production operations that used to force an organization toward functional divisions or large-scale product divisions.

Geographical Designs. Organizations have employed geographical structures, such as the emphasis on geographic regions and districts in the original IRS structure described at the beginning of the chapter. Although the IRS has moved away from that alternative, organizations continue to utilize it, sometimes as part of a hybridized combination with another structural emphasis, as in the case of a global matrix structure for a business firm's international operations (Daft, 2020). This alternative can reduce transportation and logistics costs and challenges. It can bring services closer to customers and allow service delivery on site, and it can enhance the perception that the organization is local (Galbraith, 2014). In addition, organizations often face major geographical imperatives because of such developments as globalization and internationalization of organizational activities. Such developments virtually require emphasis on geography in organizational design, through such obvious alternatives as headquarters or centers of operation on different continents or in different nations (Daft, 2020).

Process Structures. Still another contemporary approach to organizational design involves the process structure: Divisions are organized around processes, such as the new product development process, and customer acquisition and maintenance processes, in which customer service teams focus on segments or groupings of customers.

Given all these alternatives, it should not be surprising that structures in organizations show a great deal of variation. These alternatives actually serve as prototypes that organizational designers choose among and blend using heavy doses of pragmatism, because obviously no scientific method exists for designing organizations. As discussed earlier, management experts currently propose that many organizations should adopt highly adaptive, permeable, fluid, loosely arranged structures, and they observe that organizations increasingly attempt to do so.

The literature on organization structure and design provides many illustrations of the employment of teams – including shifting teams in “reconfigurable” organizations – and of designs for lateral and horizontal coordination in and among organizations. The heavy emphasis on the accountability of public organizations to external authorities may impede the use of some flexible structures in government agencies, but these alternatives are often applicable in some form. A geologist with the US Geological Survey, e.g., works with officials of the nation of Afghanistan to develop that war-ravaged nation's geological resources, such as water, oil, and mineral deposits. A project assessing the potential for such resources and their development will involve an ad hoc team representing different organizational units, including experts on water resources, mineral resources, oil and gas resources, and other resources and related issues (such as earthquakes). The team will be flexible and “reconfigurable” over time. In many other instances as well the more contemporary design alternatives apply to government and its organizations.

Holacracy. A holacracy refers to a decentralized management and organizational structure of governance, a sort of “no-structure structure” that claims to distribute authority and decision making via self-organizing teams. The term “holarchy” was first coined by Arthur Koestler (1967) in “The Ghost in the Machine” wherein Koestler describes a holocracy as comprised of holons (from the Greek), autonomous and self-reliant units, and at the same time, dependent on the greater whole. Puranam and Hakonsson (2015) describe a holocracy as an organizational form without a formal hierarchy, job titles, or job descriptions. Organizational analysts have advanced similar ideas, such as “postbureaucratic,” “poststructuralist,” “information-based,” and “organic” organizations. Holacracy has been adopted by businesses in several countries and in non-profit organizations. The online shoe company Zappos has been described as a holocracy (Groth, 2016). In its early phase, the online publisher Medium was also structured as a holacracy. However, in 2016, the company reportedly abandoned the form because of difficulty coordinating large-scale projects (Boyd, 2013; Stirman, 2013; Doyle, 2016).

In a Harvard Business Review article, “Beyond the Holacracy Hype,” Bernstein et al. (2016) argue that organizations are attracted to the holacracy form as a way to balance reliability and adaptability. They describe the holacracy as the latest variation of self-managing teams and an extension of adhocracy – e.g., a flexible informal management form, observed by Warren Bennis and Henry Mintzberg in the 1980s. They also predict that despite the challenges associated with holacracies, elements of self-organization will become valuable tools for all organizations in the future. In 2020, the Covid-19 pandemic made work-from-home arrangements widespread. Companies increasingly grapple with novel ways to communicate, integrate, and coordinate. The lessons from Zappos and other organizations, which have structured their organizations as holacracies, deserve attention.

Organizational Structures in Public Organizations

The question of alternative designs for public organizations brings us back to whether public organizations have distinctive structures. As mentioned earlier, some academic theories and observations suggest that public organizations are inherently different from private organizations, because governmental oversight and the absence of performance indicators such as sales and profits cause them to emphasize rules and hierarchy. If this is true, it suggests that public organizations cannot adopt some structural forms, such as decentralized and flexible designs, or that they can do so only with great difficulty. Conversely, many organization theorists regard public sector status as unimportant (in part because their research has often found little evidence that public organizations have distinctive structures). Pugh, Hickson, and Hinings (1969), e.g., predicted that government organizations in their sample would show higher levels of formalization (they used a measure called “structuring of activities”), but they did not. Over the years, additional studies have concurred. Buchanan (1975) also sought to test the proverbial red-tape differences by comparing federal managers to business managers on a “structure salience” scale. Unexpectedly, the public managers perceived that a lower level of salience was assigned to structure in their organizations. Bozeman and Loveless (1987) found that public sector R&D units differed only slightly from private sector R&D units in the amount of red tape with which they had to contend. Langbein (2000) analyzed the results of a 1994 survey of 2,750 members of the Institute of Electrical and Electronics Engineers and compared those who worked in the public sector to those employed in the private sector on the degree to which they felt they had discretion – autonomy in decision making – in their work. She found no significant difference between the two groups (although she concluded that conditions that the engineers perceive as constraining discretion, such as disagreement among higher-level authorities, were more likely to prevail in the public sector). Kurland and Egan (1999) analyzed a small sample of organizations, comparing responses from members of two public agencies to those in seven private firms, and found little difference between the two sets of employees on perceptions about the formalization of their jobs and their communication patterns.

Yet other evidence suggests that public organizations do differ. Although Pugh, Hickson, and Hinings (1969) did not find greater “structuring of activities” in government organizations, in those organizations authority was more concentrated at the top of or outside the organization, especially concerning personnel procedures. The researchers concluded that an organization's size and technological development act as the main determinants of how the organization structures its activities, but government ownership exerts an influence independent of size and technology, causing this concentration of authority at the top or with external authorities. The study included only eight public organizations, all local government units with tasks similar to those of many business firms, including a local water department and a manufacturing unit of a government agency. This might explain why these organizations did not show as much bureaucratic structuring as anticipated. It also indicates, however, the effects of government ownership even on organizations that are much like business firms. A public manager would probably comment that the researchers simply observed the effects of civil service systems.

Mintzberg (1979) cited this evidence from Pugh, Hickson, and Hinings when he designated public machine bureaucracies as a subtype within the machine bureaucracy category in his typology of structures. He argued that many public bureaucracies tend toward the machine bureaucracy form because of external governmental control. Other studies have come to similar conclusions. Warwick (1975) concluded from his case study of the US Department of State that public bureaucracies inherently incline toward elaborate hierarchies and rules. Meyer (1979) analyzed a national sample of state and local finance agencies and found their vertical hierarchies to be very stable over time. Political pressures forced frequent changes in their subunit composition, however, and pressures from the federal government led to formalization of their personnel systems. Meyer concluded that public bureaucracies have no alternative to elaborate hierarchies. Their managers' political strength and skill, however, determine how well they can defend themselves from external forces that can strip away their subunits and assign them to some other organization.

Holdaway, Newberry, Hickson, and Heron (1975) found, in a study of Canadian universities, that higher degrees of government control are related to correspondingly higher levels of formalization, standardization of personnel procedures, and centralization. Chubb and Moe (1990) reported that public school employees in the United States perceive more externally imposed formal constraints on personnel procedures and school policies than do private school employees. Rainey's sample of middle managers in state agencies (1983) perceived more organizational formalization, particularly concerning going through channels and adhering to standard operating procedures, than did middle managers in business firms. This study and a number of others found that government managers report much stronger constraints on the administration of extrinsic rewards such as pay and promotion under the existing personnel rules for their organizations than do business managers. Chapters Nine and Ten cite various studies that have found this difference at all levels of government. Also indicating the effects of public sector status on personnel procedures, Tolbert and Zucker (1983) showed how federal pressures influenced the diffusion of civil service personnel systems across governments in the United States. Light (2002b) compared the results from a survey of 673 US federal employees to those of a survey of 505 private employees and found that federal employees perceived more layers of supervisors in their organizations. Zaffane (1994) compared survey responses of 474 public sector managers and 944 private sector managers in 238 organizations operating in Australia. The public managers perceived more emphasis on rules and regulations in their organizations than did their private counterparts.

Studies by professional associations and government agencies, and the testimony of public managers, paint a similar picture. A National Academy of Public Administration (1986) report lamented the complex web of controls and rules governing federal managers' decisions and the adverse effects of these constraints on their capacity and motivation to manage. The report complained that managers in charge of large federal programs often face irritating limits on their authority to make even minor decisions. The head of a program involving tens of millions of dollars might have to seek the approval of the General Services Administration before he or she can send an assistant to a short training program. Very large surveys of federal employees have found that a large percentage of federal managers and executives say they do not have enough authority to remove, hire, promote, and determine the pay of their employees. Large percentages have also expressed the opinion that federal personnel and budgeting rules create obstacles to productivity (US Office of Personnel Management, 1979, 1980, 1983). Executives who have served in both business and government say similar things about the constraints on the authority of managers in government positions imposed by overarching rules and oversight agencies (Allison, 1983; Blumenthal, 1983; Chase and Reveal, 1983; IBM Endowment for the Business of Government, 2002). The National Performance Review during the Clinton administration sought to enact a number of reforms aimed at reducing rules and red tape in the federal government. President Clinton issued an executive order instructing all federal agencies to reduce their rules by 50% (an order that appears to have had virtually no impact), and other initiatives sought to decentralize and reduce the rules and constraints in federal human resource management and procurement procedures. These efforts reflect a widespread conviction that government organizations are subject to extensive and excessive rules and hierarchical controls.

Research on red tape also generally supports this view. Sociologists and psychologists who study organizations have not made much use of the concept of red tape, probably because they regard it as a vague, colloquial idea that supports crude stereotypes about organizations. Because the problem of red tape has been a classic and proverbial topic in government, however, researchers in public administration have done more in recent years to develop the concept. It derives from the practice in the British civil service of binding official documents in red tape, and it generally refers to cumbersome organizational rules and procedures, frequently associated with government. A topic of satire and ridicule at least since Charles Dickens wrote an essay about it, the red tape problem has over the years led to many initiatives aimed at reducing red tape in government. These efforts have tended to make little headway, often because even as one person or group may regard a rule as burdensome and absurd, another person or group defends it as an essential protection of the public interest (Kaufman, 1977). Bozeman and others (Bozeman, 2000; Bozeman and Feeney, 2011) have developed the concept for use in research, however, and their research tends to support the generalization that public organizations have more red tape than private ones—a finding consistent with the findings about greater levels of formalization in public organizations. Bozeman defines red tape as “rules, regulations, and procedures that … entail a compliance burden but do not advance the legitimate purposes the rules were intended to serve” (2000, p. 12). Thus, red tape differs from formalization (formal rules and procedures) in that red tape involves excessive and unduly expensive or burdensome rules and regulations. Bozeman also develops concepts for dimensions and types of red tape, such as rule inception red tape, which originates when the rule is established because of such problems as inaccurate forecasts about the effects of the rule, or because managers make excessive attempts at control. Rule-evolved red tape occurs when rules drift away from their original form because of how they are implemented or because they are incompatible with other rules. Pandey and Scott (2002) and Pandey and Kingsley (2000) further show empirical evidence that red tape should be regarded as a concept distinct from formalization.

Most important, when surveys have asked government and business managers about the extent of red tape in their organizations, the public managers have consistently reported higher levels than the business managers (Rainey, Pandey, and Bozeman, 1995). In other studies, in which public and private managers have responded to questions about how long it takes to finish certain administrative functions, such as hiring a new person, firing an employee, or purchasing a piece of equipment, the public managers have reported longer times than the business managers (Scott and Falcone, 1998; Bozeman and Rainey, 1998).

All of these studies and reports provide increasing evidence that public sector status influences an organization's structure in a number of ways, particularly in regard to rules and structural arrangements over which external oversight agencies have authority, such as personnel and purchasing procedures. The stream of research does show some inconsistencies, however, on such dimensions as formalization, in which some studies find differences between the two sectors and some do not. A very interesting and important interpretation of these inconsistencies involves a distinction between formalization and red tape in general and formalization and red tape in such areas as personnel and purchasing, in which government agencies are subject to control by external authorities that impose the rules on them. This interpretation takes on importance because it contrasts with the common assertion that a lot of rules and red tape originate inside public bureaucracies because bureaucrats have an affinity for rules and because higher-level government bureaucrats issue a profusion of rules in attempts to control lower-level bureaucrats (e.g., Downs, 1967; Lynn, 1987; Warwick, 1975).

Bozeman and Bretschneider (1994) provided explicit evidence of these patterns. They analyzed them in R&D laboratories on the basis of the labs' public or private status and on the amount of government funding they received. The government labs had highly structured personnel rules. The private labs did not, even when they received high levels of government funding. The private labs did, however, receive more contacts and communications from government officials when they received more public funding. This suggests that government funding brings with it a different pattern of governmental influence than does governmental ownership. Ownership brings with it the formal authority of oversight agencies to impose rules, usually governing personnel, purchasing, and accounting and budgeting procedures. Bretschneider (1990) provided more evidence in an analysis of decisions about computer systems in public and private organizations. Managers in the public organizations experienced longer delays in getting approval to purchase computer equipment and in the processing of those purchases. The delays apparently reflect the procurement rules imposed by central procurement agencies such as the General Services Administration. In sum, these studies provide evidence, consistent with the pattern that began to emerge with the Pugh, Hickson, and Hinings (1969) study, that government ownership often subjects organizations to central oversight rules over such matters as personnel, purchasing, and budgeting and accounting procedures.

More recent survey evidence supports this observation more strongly than ever. Feeney and Rainey (2010) reported results of surveys in several different states, involving all levels of government and many different organizations, at different points across a thirty-year period. They compared the responses of public and private managers to numerous questions about constraints under personnel rules. They asked whether the rules made it hard to fire a poor manager or reward a good manager with higher pay, and similar questions. The differences between the public and private managers were huge by the standards of survey research. Roughly 90% of the public managers agreed that their organization's personnel rules make it hard to fire poor managers and hard to reward good managers with higher pay, whereas 90% of the business managers disagreed. These differences shape the context of leadership and motivation in public organizations discussed in later chapters.

Another recent study provides further evidence of distinctive structural characteristics of public organizations, with findings based on a large representative sample of work organizations in the United States (Kalleberg, Knoke, and Marsden, 2001; Kalleberg, Knoke, Marsden, and Spaeth, 1996). The study also supports the interpretation that higher levels of rules and formalization in public organizations tend to be concentrated in areas such as personnel and purchasing, which are subject to controls by external authorities. The researchers undertook the National Organizations Study (NOS) project in part because the samples in most studies of organizations are not large, representative ones, in that such samples are expensive and hard to attain. Chapter Three of this book, in the section headed “Findings from Research,” described a study by Pugh, Hickson, and Hinings (1969) that sought to develop a taxonomy of organizations. Pugh and associates did not find that the public organizations in their sample differed sharply from their sample of private organizations, although they did find some distinctive attributes of the public organizations. The researchers included only eight public organizations in their sample of nearly sixty organizations, however, and they expressed reservations about their findings for the public organizations. The NOS, by contrast, surveyed a carefully designed representative sample consisting of 725 work organizations, about 94 of which were state, local, or federal government agencies. Status as a public agency turned out to be one of the strongest correlates of structural characteristics in the study.

The NOS researchers asked the respondents in the organizations they surveyed to reply to questions aimed at measuring the structural characteristics of their organizations, including decentralization and formalization (defined earlier in this chapter). Status as a public organization was among the variables most strongly related to these two structural characteristics. The public organizations tended to be less decentralized (thus more centralized) and more formalized (Kalleberg, Knoke, and Marsden, 2001; Marsden, Cook, and Kalleberg, 1994). In addition, the method of measuring formalization makes this finding consistent with the evidence mentioned earlier about the formalization of personnel rules and procedures in public organizations that appears to result from government civil service personnel systems. The researchers followed a procedure similar to that of Pugh, Hickson, and Hinings (1969), in which they asked whether the organization had written documentation for various important organizational matters. In the NOS, almost all of the questions used to measure formalization asked about written documentation of personnel matters: documentation on fringe benefits, hiring and firing procedures, personnel evaluation, and the requirement for written job descriptions and written performance records (Kalleberg, Knoke, and Marsden, 2001; Marsden, Cook, and Kalleberg, 1994). Thus, this study of a nationally representative sample of organizations, although not intended as a study of public organizations, provides evidence of the tendencies toward distinctive structural characteristics on the part of public organizations in the United States.

All of this evidence supports the interpretation that the heavier dose of rules and regulations in public organizations originates mostly from external sources and not from the bureaucrats within the agencies. Adding to this evidence, Bozeman and Rainey (1998) reported a survey that showed that managers in government, compared with business managers, would prefer their organizations to have fewer rules. This contradicts the view that managers in government generate excessive rules.

As indicated earlier, researchers have also found distinctive structural characteristics of public organizations that are not tied to rules imposed by oversight agencies. Tolbert (1985) found differences in the subunit structures of public and private universities related to external influences from public and private institutions and the universities' dependence on them for resources. Crow and Bozeman (1987) and Emmert and Crow (1987, 1988) reported that public R&D units differ from private units in the size and structure of the administrative component of the organization and the way the research teams were organized. The public labs actually had more team-based organization. This again emphasizes that government organizations vary a great deal from one another, and that by no means do all follow a rigid bureaucratic pattern. In fact, these government labs appeared to respond more directly than the private labs to task contingencies of the sort discussed earlier.

The Macrostructure of Public Organizations

The evidence of the influence of government ownership on the structures of public organizations brings up another structural topic, one that needs much additional attention from both researchers and managers. Structure within public organizations cannot easily be separated from structures outside the organization that are an inherent part of government. In other words, the internal structures of public agencies reflect, in part, the jurisdictional structures of the government body under which they operate. Legislatures, oversight agencies, and other governmental institutions impose system-wide rules and configurations on all the agencies within their jurisdiction (Hood and Dunsire, 1981; Meyer, 1979; Warwick, 1975). In addition, different units of government differ in the structural arrangements of their major institutional attributes, such as their formal, constitutional powers. In some states the governor has less formal power than in others, and the legislature has more formal authority. The governor of Florida, e.g., appoints fewer of the cabinet officers of the state government than do governors in other states. Instead, some of these officers have to run for independent election, and consequently the agencies they head tend to have more independence from the governor than in other states. Meyer (1979) found that independently elected heads of finance agencies more effectively defend their agencies against the loss of subunits than do political appointees. Such characteristics of the complex macrostructural terrain support the observation that public organizations operate within larger structures that heavily influence their own.

Summing Up the Literature on Structure

The researchers on organizational structure who reject a public–private distinction have shown us that structure is multidimensional and that both types of organization vary widely on different structural dimensions. Often these variations are related to the major contingencies of size, strategy, technology and tasks, and environmental uncertainty and complexity. Obviously, technological similarities cause government-owned electric utilities, hospitals, railroads, airlines, R&D labs, and manufacturing units to show stronger structural similarities to private or nonprofit versions of the same types of organizations than to other types of government organizations. The same holds true for organizations or organizational units engaged in similar tasks, such as R&D labs and legal offices. Indeed, the general structure of subunits of public organizations often resembles the structure of their private sector counterparts more than it resembles that of other units in the parent organization. Also, relatively small, independent organizations usually have simpler structures than larger organizations, so a smaller unit of government may exhibit less red tape or hierarchical complexity than a large private firm. Obviously, government agencies respond to environmental complexities and uncertainties just as private organizations do, as the examples at the beginning of this chapter illustrate. Thus, we can see that it is incredibly simplistic to treat all public organizations as a uniform mass that is inherently subject to intensive red tape and bureaucracy.

However, research on the structures of government organizations and research comparing government and business organizations supports a balanced conclusion. This research suggests that public organizations generally tend toward higher levels of internal structural complexity, centralization, and formalization – especially in such areas as personnel and purchasing – than do private organizations. Size, task, technology, and environmental contingencies make a difference, often figuring more importantly than public or private ownership. Within given task categories, however, public organizations tend toward stable hierarchies and centralized and formalized rules, especially rules pertaining to the functions governed by oversight agencies: personnel, purchasing and procurement, and budgeting and accounting. Government organizations may not have more formalized and elaborate rules than private organizations of similar size, but they often have more centralized, formalized rules for functions such as personnel and procurement. Comparisons of government and nongovernment organizations engaged in the same type of work tend to support such conclusions.

Still, wide variations are likely. For example, R&D labs or other special units may have even more general structural flexibility under government ownership. In addition, government ownership and influence are multidimensional in that hybrid organizations such as public enterprises may be owned by government but privately funded and exempt from some central rules and controls. Privately owned organizations with extensive public funding often show heavy governmental influences on certain aspects of their structures; e.g., defense contractors have small armies of government auditors on-site, making sure their spending and record-keeping practices adhere to government regulations. Here again, government rules tend to follow from government ownership or funding.

All managers must deal with structural complexity and with external influences on their authority. Public managers usually face more elaborate structural arrangements and constraints, however, and must learn to work with them. Their understanding of the elaborate macrostructural patterns in government, of the structures of their own agencies, and of the origins and purposes of these arrangements can serve as a valuable component of their professional knowledge as public managers. Among other challenges, they must find ways to reward and encourage people working within these complex structures, even when the personnel rules they must follow do not readily provide much flexibility. The next chapter further considers that topic. Later chapters discuss how public managers can and do make valuable changes, in part through effective knowledge of the structure of government and its agencies and in part through effective applications of the general body of knowledge on organizational structure.

Information Technology and Public Organizations

Information technology (IT) has been the most rapidly developing topic related to technology, with the developments coming so fast that everyone has had difficulty keeping up with them and providing conclusive interpretations about their effects on organizations. The rapid advent of computer applications, the internet, social media, and other forms of information and communication technology have had major implications for organizations and their management, but people have had trouble saying exactly what effects they have. As for effects on public organizations, especially until close to the turn of the new century, little research had been done (Kraemer and Dedrick, 1997).

Public managers are also starting to realize potential benefits of adopting artificial intelligence (AI) systems (Kankanhalli et al., 2019). The United States and India are at the forefront of this effort. Although academic research on AI is still in short supply, the literature discusses application associated with public sector functions. These include public health (Qian and Medaglia, 2019; Ziuziański, Furmankiewicz, and Sołtysik-Piorunkiewicz, 2014), transport (Kouziokas, 2017), education (Fernandes et al., 2018), security (Ku and Leroy, 2014), and communications (He et al., 2010). In the United States, the Ash Center for Democratic Governance and Innovation at Harvard Kennedy School is conducting ongoing research on AI and sharing it with government officials interested in AI solutions.

Experts on IT tend to report that the more salient effects in industry include the extension of computing technology into design and production applications, such as computer-aided design, in which computer programs carry out design functions, and computer-aided manufacturing, in which computers actually control machinery that carries out the manufacturing process. Computer-integrated manufacturing links together the machinery and the design and engineering processes through computers. Ultimately, an integrated information network links all major components of the organization, including inventory control, purchasing and procurement, accounting, and other functions, in addition to manufacturing and production. These developments supported an evolution from mass production to mass customization, whereby manufacturers and service organizations produce large quantities of goods and services that are more tailored to the preferences of individual customers than previously possible. In addition, observers suggest that computerized integration of production processes has effects on organizational structures and processes. Computer-integrated manufacturing reportedly moves organizations toward fewer hierarchical levels, tasks that are less routine and more craft-like, more teamwork, more training, and more emphasis on skills in cognitive problem solving than in manual expertise (Daft, 2020).

While computer-aided manufacturing and terms such as digital corporation might not apply in many public and nonprofit organizations, similar developments have led to the international usage of such concepts as digital government and e-government. E-government is now institutionalized in many countries, with 94% of countries in the world possessing infrastructures to support e-government systems (Ramnarine and Endeley, 2008, p. 14). Practices and levels of implementation vary across governments, because each government identifies its needs and resources for information and communication technologies (ICT) in different ways. Commonwealth countries, e.g., have used three approaches to adopting and developing e-government: benchmarking (comparing projects against other projects), best practices (identifying the best alternatives), and technology transfer through such procedures as training and consultation (Ramnarine and Endeley, 2008, pp. 9–14).

Computer technology and the internet have also become more influential in organizational decision-making processes. For many years organizations have been using computers to store large data sets and retrieve information from them, but more recently the capacity for active utilization of that data has advanced, so that computer-based management information systems (MISs) have become very common. An MIS typically provides middle-level managers with ready access to data they can use in decision making, such as sales and inventory data for business managers, and client processing and status data for managers in public and nonprofit organizations. Decision support systems provide software that managers can use interactively. Such a system may, e.g., provide models that enable managers to assess the effects of certain decisions or changes they may be considering. Executive information systems provide MIS-type support, but at a more general, strategic level, for the sorts of decisions required at higher executive levels. Many government organizations currently use geographic information systems (GISs), which provide information about facilities or conditions in different geographic locations. A GIS might allow a planner to designate any particular geographic location in a city and pull up on the computer screen a diagram showing the underground utility infrastructure, such as pipelines and electric cables, at that location. State employment training agencies have used a GIS to store and retrieve data on clients and potential clients at different locations in the state for use in planning the location of their facilities and programs. In a case study of a regional development project in the Netherlands, Bekkers and Moody (2006, pp. 113–118) describe how GISs played an important role in the policy formulation process by integrating economic, residential, and ecological information. GIS technology allowed town and country planners, civil engineers, regional board members, and representatives of the province to visualize potential effects of the project and to analyze complex policy problems. Computers, the internet, electronic mail, and other forms of information and communication technology have made possible more elaborate and interactive networking of people and organizational units, both within and between organizations. Some organizations have moved away from traditional hierarchical and departmental reporting relationships to forms of virtual organization and dynamic network organization, in which a central hub coordinates other units that formally belong to the same organization, as well as organizations formally outside the hub organization (such as contractors or agencies with overlapping responsibility for public agencies), via e-mail and the internet. Advances in IT reportedly lead to more decentralized organizations, better coordination internally and with external entities, more professional staff and professional departments for developing and maintaining the information systems, and more employee participation.

Over the past several decades, researchers have sought evidence about just how widely and deeply these generalizations apply to government organizations, but examples clearly indicate that they definitely apply in certain cases. Concerning evolution toward smaller organizations, e.g., few Americans are aware that during the 1970s and 1980s the SSA went through Project 17,000, in which the agency eliminated 17,000 jobs, due largely to the computer taking over large portions of the processing of client claims that human beings had formerly handled.

As for effects on professional staff, governments and government agencies, like business firms, have increasingly appointed chief information officers (CIOs) to lead the development and maintenance of IT and information systems (IS), with staff to support the CIO. Governments often face challenges in attracting and retaining the professionalized personnel required for IT, due to such conditions as lower compensation levels in government and cumbersome recruiting and hiring procedures (McKinsey and Company, 2010; National Academy of Public Administration, 2010).

In government, of course, the multiple levels of authority create special issues and challenges for IT professionals. In 2009, President Obama appointed the first federal government CIO (Williams, 2009). This new federal CIO oversees information technology investments and spending by the federal government. While one might expect various IT-related activities by industry associations, can anyone imagine a national CIO with authority over IT matters in all corporations in the United States or in most other nations? Significantly, in relation to levels of government, state CIOs, as represented by the National Association of State Chief Information Officers, paid close attention to this official's work. The state CIOs are very interested in the coordination of federal agencies' programs that provide funding for state-level IT initiatives, among other issues (Newcombe, 2009).

Concerning internal and external coordination, most large government agencies, like business firms and nonprofit organizations, now have an intranet: a network within the organization with access restricted to designated organizational members. To maintain security of data about individual citizens and about such sensitive matters as national security, these intranet arrangements usually require elaborate provisions for controlled access. Some government employees carry with them devices that periodically inform them of newly assigned access codes for their agency's intranet because the codes are changed periodically as a security precaution. Access to information raises additional issues concerning internal and external coordination. The federal CIO emphasized “democratic” access to federal government data and launched www.data.gov to begin to provide such access.

All federal agencies and virtually all state and local government agencies of any reasonable size now have websites that provide a lot of information to clients and citizens, and more and more public services are handled through the internet and website-based operations, just as more and more business organizations relate to customers and suppliers through e-commerce. For example, because of federal laws that resulted from abuses of human beings in research projects in the past, the Centers for Disease Control requires researchers proposing research on human subjects to go through a “human subjects review” of their proposal. Researchers can obtain forms for such a review and submit the required information via the agency's website. As another example, Congress directed the IRS to increase the number of tax returns submitted electronically. The IRS did so with considerable success, because in customer satisfaction studies of federal agencies, the IRS has gotten much higher customer satisfaction ratings from taxpayers who filed electronically than from those who filed through surface mail. This development contributed to the IRS receiving its all-time highest customer satisfaction rating in 2012. In 1998, 32% of respondents to the American Customer Satisfaction Survey expressed satisfaction with their experience in filing taxes. In 2012, 73% expressed satisfaction (Insight, 2013).

To enhance internal coordination and communication, some governmental executives and managers have actively encouraged employees to contact them with questions and comments. For example, as part of the National Performance Review during the Clinton years, the administration encouraged federal agencies to establish or designate “reinvention laboratories,” organizational units that would try new ways of improving and streamlining the agency's services and administrative procedures. In one such unit in the Department of Defense, the leaders invited employees to submit questions and suggestions to them via e-mail and promised to respond to each e-mail within several days. During his widely praised service as commissioner of the IRS, Charles Rossotti developed a reputation for reading, and frequently responding to, e-mail from employees at many organizational levels.

These examples indicate that IT has provided significant improvements and opportunities for government, its employees, and the clients of government agencies. As one might expect, however, IT has raised many challenges for managers in government. These challenges involve the topics covered in this book and challenges similar to those encountered in managing any significant operation or initiative (McKinsey and Company, 2010, p. 40). Fountain (2001; see also Dawes, 2002) has analyzed developments in and challenges of IT in government by using a technology enactment framework based on an institutional perspective similar to the one described in Chapter Four. The framework treats IT developments as emerging from interactions among objective technologies such as computer hardware and software, organizational forms such as bureaucracies and networks, and institutional arrangements such as cultural and legal conditions. These components of the framework combine to influence the way technological initiatives play out. The framework helps to explain why even very similar technological initiatives can have very different outcomes, because of different organizational and institutional influences on their implementation. Fountain also describes how such influences raise formidable challenges for successful utilization in government, given the strong, often entrenched organizational and institutional influences. She describes the complications encountered by officials in the numerous agencies involved in trying to develop the International Trade Data System, an IS on international trade that linked all the different agencies with responsibilities related to it. The differences among the agencies in their cultures, missions, stakeholders, standard practices, and other characteristics caused the project to founder. Fountain concluded that this and other examples suggest the impediments to major IT initiatives linking and coordinating diverse agencies and programs, and the likelihood that developments in IT applications will involve more modest projects and changes. Other authors point to evidence that the bureaucratic characteristics and political contexts of government agencies create significant challenges for major IT projects and initiatives in government (McKinsey and Company, 2010; Nye, 1999).

Illustrating and analyzing challenges in IT adoption in government, Bozeman (2002b) chronicled the agonies of the IRS in trying to modernize the tax system with IT. One glaring example of the problem took the form of a “meltdown” at one of the large centers where IRS employees process tax returns. A visiting official found tax returns, including checks for payment of taxes, stuffed in the trash cans in the restroom. The new equipment designed by contractors for automated reading and processing of the tax returns did not work. Employees, fearful of discipline for not finishing enough tax returns fast enough, resorted to discarding the returns. News of such breakdowns and failures in the new systems brought a tidal wave of criticism. In 1996, one congressman referred to the agency's efforts as “a four billion dollar fiasco” (Bozeman, 2002b). Bozeman pointed out that the “fiasco” was not as disastrous as critics sometimes claimed, because the IRS was still successfully using much of the equipment and hardware years later. The problems were severe, however, and Bozeman described how many of them arose from management lapses, such as failures in project management and in management of relations with contractors. The IRS struggled with the challenges of tax systems modernization, but succeeded in updating their systems.

Also providing evidence about IT developments and challenges in government, for over two decades researchers in public administration have conducted surveys covering large numbers of organizations. These studies also show a mixed picture of difficulties, but also progress and influence of IT initiatives in public organizations. Bretschneider (1990), e.g., added survey results to the evidence of particular challenges for public managers and IT professionals. He found that public organizations tend to be more information intensive than private firms; they have to engage in more information processing. Even so, he found that managers in government agencies report longer delays in procuring computer equipment than do private managers, due to more red tape, procurement rules, and accountability requirements in the public agencies. Conversely, Bretschneider and Wittmer (1993) reported evidence of innovativeness in IT adoption by government agencies. In comparing IT conditions in government agencies with those in business firms, they found that the government organizations reported having more microcomputers per employee than the business firms. This appears to result from the more information-intensive task environment in public organizations, and the evidence tends to contradict the view that public agencies tend to lag behind private firms in IT adoption and utilization (Moon and Bretschneider, 2002). Somewhat similarly, Rocheleau and Wu (2002) surveyed municipal government IS managers and compared their responses to those of IS managers in business firms and found that the government managers rated IT and IT training as more important than business managers did. Conversely, the business managers reported higher levels of spending on IT, IT training, and IT personnel in their organizations.

Moon and Bretschneider (2002) reported survey results that indicated that public sector managers engage in higher levels of IT innovativeness in response to higher levels of red tape (as measured by survey items about the level of burdensome rules and procedures). Public managers may regard red tape as a transaction cost and try to minimize it through proactive adoption of IT. In addition, Moon and Bretschneider found evidence that more entrepreneurial and risk-receptive leadership in the organization has a positive relationship to IT innovativeness.

Other studies have reflected on IT influences in addition to its utilization. On the basis of a mail survey of government program managers in the 450 largest US counties, Heintze and Bretschneider (2000) analyzed the impact of IT implementation on organizational structures and performance. They found that the managers reported that IT implementation has little impact on organizational structures, in the sense of increasing management levels and numbers of decision makers. In addition, the managers perceived that any structural changes caused by IT implementation in public agencies have little impact on organizational performance (measured as improved ease of communication and improved technical decision making). However, the managers tended to regard IT adoption as having a direct positive impact on improving technical decision making (as opposed to an impact on decision making by way of influences on structure). Although Heintze and Bretschneider noted that county government managers may have different responses to developments in IT than state and federal managers, the lack of perceived structural effects of IT is striking.

Moon (2002) found generally similar results when he analyzed the data on 2,899 municipal governments with populations of more than ten thousand from the 2000 E-Government Survey conducted by the International City/County Management Association and Public Technology, Inc. Moon found that most municipal governments surveyed have their own websites and intranets. However, few had well-developed e-government strategic plans. At that time, most of the municipal governments were in early stages of evolution in e-government utilization, using it mainly for simple information dissemination or two-way communication with citizens and stakeholders. Few governments reported being at the more advanced stages of development that involve using e-government for service provision and financial transactions. In findings similar to those of Heintze and Bretschneider, Moon stated that only a small portion of the governments reported that e-government programs enhance cost saving, downsizing, and entrepreneurial activities. A higher portion, however, reported improvements in work environment, general efficiency, and effective procurement. Although larger governments showed more active engagement with e-government, Moon concluded that in general municipal governments were not aggressively utilizing IT and that IT innovations were not contributing strongly to cost savings, revenue generation, and downsizing.

More recent evidence tends to be consistent with Moon's conclusions in some ways, but again provides a mixed picture of progress and valuable development, coupled with ongoing challenges. In a survey of about nine hundred cities, the International City Management Association (ICMA) found that 96% of the cities reported having a website (International City Management Association, 2011). Only 24%, however, had surveyed residents to determine the information, services, or forms of participation they wanted from the website, and 84% had no plans for such a survey. Small percentages (4 to 15%) reported using the website to conduct forums, operate chat rooms, permit citizen petitions, conduct town hall meetings, enable citizens to vote in elections or referendums, or enable citizens to participate in a public hearing. On the other hand, 50% or more of the respondents reported that “e-participation” had improved the quality and quantity on information available to local officials for decision making, and improved the quantity of citizen participation. The responses indicate that the websites tended to provide information to citizens more than to facilitate communication from citizens to local governments. While interactive communications with citizens via websites may be limited, however, websites are providing enhanced services in many ways. Very high percentages of the respondents reported that they provide online services for downloading forms such as building permit forms, for employment information, for council agendas and minutes, for codes and ordinances, and for e-newsletters (International City Management Association, 2011).

The ICMA survey also provides indications of management issues for local government IT services, and again makes the point that effective IT requires effective management. Among the local governments, 39% do not have a dedicated webmaster. Among the top five barriers to e-governments that the governments have encountered, lack of financial resources led the list (67%), followed by lack of technology and web staff (46%).

The findings in these studies about IT in government provide indications of progress and successes, as well as ongoing challenges. Both the good news and not-so-good news underscore the imperative of effectively organizing and managing IT. Organizing and managing any major new initiative, and especially highly technical ones such as IT projects, should be expected to involve challenges for leaders and professionals. As some of the sources indicate, the challenges may be even more formidable in the public sector. The studies and sources reviewed here suggest conditions for meeting those challenges and for effective management of IT resources and projects: strategic thinking and planning to guide the processes involved; clarification of mission, goals, and timetables; measures to identify progress and successes; clarification of leadership roles, authority, and responsibilities on the part of CIOs, webmasters, and others involved; adequate resources; and knowledge and skill in systems of control and project management. Prospects for improved service delivery, efficiency, communication, and general effectiveness should motivate anyone concerned with public service – which should include literally everyone – to confront the challenges and take advantage of the possibilities.

Social Media and Public Management

The challenges in managing information technology apply as well to governments' rapidly growing use of social media. Social media, such as Facebook, Twitter, wikis, and blogs, add new dimensions to the already widespread use of websites, e-mail, and other media. O'Reilly (2005; see also Mossberger, Wu, and Crawford, 2013) coined the term “Web 2.0” to refer to these new media that add to previous web applications the possibility for users to contribute content and to participate in developing collective intelligence, information, and communication. Mergel (2012a; 2012b) has contributed the term “Government 2.0” to refer to employment of these media in government and public management. The use of social media and interest in them has grown rapidly because of their potential to support much higher levels of interaction and information sharing between governments and their clients, stakeholders, and citizens. Government organizations now attempt to use social media to invite comments and reactions from citizens to post policy and program statements, to participate in policymaking in various ways, and to form social networks. Governments and their organizations seek public participation in problem solving in such areas as crime prevention and responses to crimes, and many others.

The examples of such uses of social media are now widely recognized and can be quite dramatic. They include law enforcement officials' responses when two men planted explosive devices among the spectators at the Boston Marathon, which injured numerous people and killed a young boy. Law enforcement authorities used social media to make public the footage from surveillance cameras that showed the men who had apparently planted the explosive devices. Citizen responses very soon helped to locate the suspects and contributed to their final confrontation with police.

Less nationally publicized examples further illustrate the role that social media can play, even if in a rather gruesome way. In Oconee County, Georgia, a man murdered a woman. He used his truck to take the deceased woman in her automobile to a shopping mall parking lot and left her there in the car. County sheriff's officials, one of whom was a graduate of a well-reputed MPA program in the area, circulated surveillance camera footage of the truck via social media, asking for public assistance in identifying the truck and its owner. Within twenty-four hours, a citizen had suggested the owner of the vehicle, and the sheriff's officers made an arrest and obtained a confession.

Much broader than these individual instances of social media use are program- and policy-related initiatives that government agencies at all levels of government now undertake. President Obama issued the Transparency and Open Government memorandum (2013), and federal agencies have engaged in a variety of initiatives. The National Aeronautics and Space Administration used social media to publicize the Mars rover landings and to encourage citizen engagement through such opportunities as meeting astronauts. The Environmental Protection Agency, the Centers for Disease Control, and the Federal Bureau of Investigation have launched efforts to employ social media in engaging citizens and interacting with them about policy issues and the agencies' programs (Mergel and Bretschneider, 2013).

Social media have played a widely publicized role in citizen unrest and protest in various nations, with communication among protesters building and encouraging the protests. Erkul and Fountain (2012; see also Fountain, 2013a) describe the role of social media and other media and IT resources in the nation of Turkey's efforts to expand e-government and use of IT and social media in their society. The initiative led to a vast increase in the number of citizens using social media. The developments had ironic effects, since when citizens protested against the government, the availability of social media supported their efforts. One social medium provides information as to where an individual is located. This medium widely distributed information indicating that a large number of people were at the location of the protest, which encouraged supporters of the protest and potential participants in it. Erkul and Fountain ultimately conclude that social media cannot alone enhance democratization in a nation moving in that direction, but can play a substantial role in the process.

Regardless of the accuracy of such observations, the challenge for leaders, managers, and professionals involves deciding how governments can employ social media to avoid the need for protest. Governmental use of social media has been increasing dramatically. Mossberger, Wu, and Crawford (2013) report an analysis of local governments' use of social media, concentrating on the thirty-five largest US cities. In 2009, about 13% of the cities were using Facebook. By 2011, 87% were using that medium. In 2009, 25% used Twitter, but by 2011, 87% used it. Use of a YouTube link increased from 16% in 2009 to 75% in 2011.

As rapidly as social media have become an issue in public management and government, experts have provided resources to support development of knowledge and skills for public managers' use of social media. Mergel (2012a) provides a comprehensive discussion of the experiments, best practices and policies, and available guidance for the employment of social media. Mergel (2102b) also provides the design of an online course to develop such skills. These resources include detailed listings and references to additional resources.

The spreading, growing government use of social media raises issues that have been common as in governance for years (Fountain, 2013a; 2013b; Mergel, 2012a). Encouraging citizen participation in government decisions has always raised questions about who gets to participate, and whether advantaged groups participate more than less advantaged groups. Experts on social media report that “trolls” representing particular issues and interests try constantly to impose themselves about all topics (Mergel, 2012a). The “digital divide,” which refers to certain groups' lack of access to computers and the internet, aggravates this problem. City councils and city-county commissions have to decide how much to allow single-issue groups to influence their decisions. In addition, there are issues regarding who owns information that citizens contribute to postings on various media, and about confidentiality and privacy versus public access.

Effective use of social media to create social networks and citizen participation and communication poses challenges. Mossberger and associates (2013) reported in-depth case studies of major cities' experiences with social media. They found no evidence of overwhelming successes and found the city officials to be very interested in practices in other cities that provide insights. Norris and Reddick (2013) analyzed two nationwide surveys of e-government among local governments and found no evidence of major advances. They found that implementation of e-government at local levels has been incremental, rather than “transformative,” as some authors had earlier predicted. E-government at the local level tends to involve governments delivering one-way transmission of information and services online with limited interactivity.

These apparent limitations of social media use suggest questions about how social media policies and processes will be managed. The framework presented in Chapter One illustrates many of the matters to be considered. What will be the goals of the process and how will they support the overall mission? Who will provide leadership? What level of resources will be provided?

Initiating and implementing social media use raises questions about how public managers and government officials can go about implementing social media processes. Mergel and Bretschneider (2012) provide a three-stage framework for understanding government use of social media. A first stage involves intrapreneurship and experimentation. New technologies become available in product and service markets external to the organization. Intrapreneurs, or entrepreneurs inside the organization, often act as “mavericks” and experiment with initiatives using a new technology. Multiple and separate instances of this process go on that differ among themselves in protocols, norms, and procedures. This leads to recognition of the need for better organization of social media use. It leads to a second stage of constructive chaos involving efforts to bring order from chaos. The growing recognition of the need for common standards leads to establishment of task forces and steering committees to achieve standards and coordination of activities. In a third stage of institutionalization, the organization develops uniformity and standards, rules, and processes. New elements of technologies will still be introduced, but the rate of change will slow down. This provides more predictability and sharing of innovations, common training, and other benefits.

The advent of social media provides opportunities and challenges for leaders, managers, and professionals in government. The three-stage adoption process that Mergel and Bretschneider describe provides a valuable perspective for understanding the challenges and addressing them.

Instructor's Guide Resources for Chapter Eight

  • Key terms
  • Discussion questions
  • Topics for writing assignments or reports
  • Exercises
  • Case Study: The Management of Brookhaven National Laboratory

Available at www.wiley.com/go/college/rainey.

..................Content has been hidden....................

You can't read the all page of ebook, please click here login for view all page.
Reset
18.220.137.164