Chapter 16
Aid Allocation: A Complex Perspective

Robert J. Downes and Steven R. Bishop

16.1 Aid Allocation Networks

16.1.1 Introduction

While much has been written on foreign aid allocation, relatively little work has considered mathematical models beyond regression analysis. Modelling aid allocation is a complex issue. Empirical findings on the allocation of foreign aid indicate that donor countries pursue a wide range of objectives, achieving complex outcomes sometimes with unintended consequences. Poverty alleviation is frequently cited as a key factor in the disbursement of aid, see United Kingdom Government 2002, United States Government 1961, Collier and Dollar 2002; donor countries often engage in less than altruistic behaviour, see Harrigan and Wang 2011; highly heterogeneous behaviour is the norm, see Collier and Dollar 2002, Harrigan and Wang 2011, Alesina and Dollar 2000, Bermeo 2008, Berthélemy 2006, and Balla and Reinhardt (2008). Recent research indicates that decision-making in the donor community also impacts the allocation of aid (see Riddell 2007 and Frot and Santiso 2011). Such ‘bandwagon’ behaviour is widely recognised in financial markets, see Schiller 2000 and Hommes 2006, but has only recently been considered as a component of aid allocation.

The development of mathematical models can support thinking on aid allocation and effectiveness. Most mathematical models follow a statistical trajectory, postulating a range of variables upon which aid allocation depends, followed by a regression-based analysis of available data; McGillivray 2003, Berthélemy 2006, Alesina and Dollar 2000 and Tarp et al. 1999 give an excellent introduction to this approach. Other models take an econometric route, considering a utility maximisation process, often based on recipient need; Collier and Dollar 2002, Chong and Gradstein 2008 and Tarp et al. 1999 all cover such procedures and McGillivray 2004 gives a particularly delicate consideration in the context of so-called ‘prescriptive and descriptive’ analyses of aid allocation.

This chapter presents a novel formulation of aid allocation. Rather than adopting a statistical or data-driven approach, we develop a framework allowing the model user to explore the allocation of foreign aid through the mathematical theory of networks. We aim to allow users of this model to explore possible policy choices in aid allocation. Statistical analysis indicates how donor countries have allocated aid in the past. Looking forward, our model allows users to explore responses to this analysis. Highlighting the behaviour of donor countries, we focus on the complexity of aid allocation from a mathematical perspective. According to McBurney 2012, alternative perspectives can function as a ‘locus of discussion’ which

c16-math-0001provide[s] a means to tame the complexity of the domain. Modelling thus enables stakeholders to jointly explore relevant concepts, data, system dynamics, policy options, and the assessment of potential consequences of policy options, in a structured and shared way.

This is our intention throughout this chapter.

16.1.2 Why Networks?

The community of aid donors and recipients is complex in a mathematical sense. According to Wilson 2012:

Complex systems are characterised by requiring many variables to describe them and having strong interdependencies between the elements of the system. When represented mathematically, these interdependencies will typically be nonlinear relationships.

In the aid allocation context, complex systems exhibit emergent behaviour: decisions made by individual system actors aggregate into global system states in an often unpredictable manner. Whether global states are desirable or otherwise is beyond the purview of any individual actor.

A motivating example from population studies is given in Schelling 1971: the population comprises two groups randomly distributed on a lattice (finite in extent); individuals have a preference for remaining close to members of their own group and will move accordingly in a series of discrete steps. The model demonstrates that each actor's relatively small preference for being close to members of its own group can lead to a global pattern of segregation and that, famously, ‘inferences about individual motives can usually not be drawn from aggregate patterns’.

As currently available models of aid allocation are typically statistically oriented, only qualitative discussion of complex behaviour is possible, see for example Ramalingam (2011). Mathematical models allowing users to explore the complexity of aid allocation are therefore a valuable contribution to current discussion.

16.1.3 Donor Motivation in Aid Allocation

Overviews of donor behaviour in aid allocation are provided by the work of Alesina and Dollar 2000 and Fuchs et al. 2014: donor countries do not behave uniformly towards recipient countries [Berthélemy 2006 and Chong and Gradstein 2008], and aid allocation generally depends upon the specific situation in recipient and donor nations (both in demographic and political terms).

A selection of common donor motivations includes poverty alleviation Collier and Dollar (2002), McGillivray 2003, Baulch 2003; colonial ties Alesina and Dollar (2000); commercial interests Harrigan and Wang (2011), Alesina and Dollar (2000), Younas (2008); strategic interests Harrigan and Wang (2011); governance and policy environment quality Collier and Dollar (2002), Burnside and Dollar (2004), McGillivray (2006). Recent work suggests that donor community bandwagon effects Frot and Santiso (2011), conflict Balla and Reinhardt (2008) and [im]migration Bermeo (2008) also play a role. Contenting ourselves with these factors throughout this chapter, we emphasise that this is not an exhaustive list.

The factors motivating donors can be divided into two distinct classes:

  1. 1. Factors associated with individual countries. These include governance quality and demographic factors related to poverty;
  2. 2. Factors associated with relationships between countries. These include colonial ties and commercial interests in the form of trade flows.

This division is essential in this chapter as we relate donor behaviour to an underlying network of countries.

There are many ways to classify social phenomena in complex systems. For example, in the context of ethno-political conflict, Gallo 2013 classifies contributory factors as so-called ‘state’ or ‘activity’ variables: state variables define structural aspects of the system, while activity variables are used to affect change in this structure.

16.2 Quantifying Aid via a Mathematical Model

16.2.1 Overview of Approach

In this section, we write down the basic mathematical objects used in this chapter. We do not assume the reader to be familiar with network theory and so include illustrative diagrams wherever possible. The mathematical details are kept to a bare minimum. We direct the interested reader to Newman 2010 for an accessible introduction to the theory of networks.

We base our model on an underlying network comprising a set of nodes connected by a number of different quantifiable relationships: nodes are identified with countries, and links between nodes with international relationships, material or otherwise. By further identifying countries as either donors or recipients and associating demographic information to each country, we construct a model of the international network of nations.

To each donor–recipient pair, we assign a function determining the preference the donor has for awarding aid to the recipient. This function is dependent upon the following:

  1. 1. Demographic information of donor and recipient;
  2. 2. Relationships between donor and recipient;
  3. 3. Relationships between donor and all other recipients (explicitly).
  4. 4. Relationships between donor and all other donors via all recipients (implicitly).

Allocations are made on the basis of this preference along with a minimum donation value below which donations are zero.

Demographic and relational information encoded in the network is related to donor behaviours discussed in Section 16.1.3: the model then simulates donor behaviour and subsequent aid allocation. For example, we explore the complex interaction between donors allocating aid for poverty alleviation and commercial gain simultaneously.

The preference function is stimulated by the generalised Cobb–Douglas production function see Cobb and Douglas 1928. In its original guise, this provides a functional relationship between two inputs, capital and labour, with production as output; the parameters governing this interaction are estimated statistically in Cobb and Douglas 1928. While the specification of the function is arbitrary, see Simon and Levy 1963, its utility can be seen in its simple presentation, understandability and elucidation of the complex interaction between factors and output of production, see (Bhanumurthy, 2002).

The preference function also shares the form of the utility function found in weighted product method approaches to multi-objective optimisation (see Marler and Arora 2004). However, we do not adopt an optimisation approach here.

16.2.2 Basic Set-Up

A graph or, equivalently, network c16-math-0002 is a collection of nodes (or vertices), denoted c16-math-0003, linked by ties (or edges), denoted c16-math-0004. In a bipartite graph, the node set is decomposed into two disjoint subsets: there are edges between nodes in each disjoint set, but no edges connecting nodes within the same set. In a complete bipartite graph, each node is connected to every node of the opposing disjoint set; this is illustrated in Figure 16.1(a).

nfgz001

Figure 16.1 Complete bipartite graph (a) with vector weights and node-specific information detail (b)

A weighted graph has a numerical quantity associated with each edge. We work with a more general object, an c16-math-0005-vector-weighted graph, in which c16-math-0006 numbers are associated with each edge. Finally, we associate to each node an additional c16-math-0007 numerical quantities which we call the c16-math-0008-vector node-specific information.

16.2.3 The Network of Nations

Define the network of nations as a complete bipartite c16-math-0009-vector-weighted graph with c16-math-0010-vector node-specific information, with the following interpretation:

  • Nodes represent countries, c16-math-0011 donor nations and c16-math-0012 recipient nations. We index donors and recipients by c16-math-0013 and c16-math-0014, respectively.
  • The vertex set c16-math-0015 is partitioned into donor and recipient country sets c16-math-0016 and c16-math-0017. No donors are recipients, or vice versa, and the total number of countries is c16-math-0018.
  • The c16-math-0019-vector edge weights c16-math-0020 represent c16-math-0021 relationships between donor and recipient countries, material or otherwise. This will always be written so that the first superscript, c16-math-0022, is donor c16-math-0023 and the second superscript, c16-math-0024, is recipient c16-math-0025. Then, c16-math-0026 is the c16-math-0027 element of the vector c16-math-0028.
  • The c16-math-0029-vector node-specific information c16-math-0030 represents c16-math-0031 quantities associated with each country c16-math-0032 in our network. Then c16-math-0033 is the c16-math-0034 element of vector c16-math-0035. Donors and recipients will generally have different node-specific information, denoted by c16-math-0036 and c16-math-0037, respectively.

Figure 16.1(a) shows a network of nations with three recipients c16-math-0038 and three donors c16-math-0039; appropriate c16-math-0040-vector edge weights and c16-math-0041-vector node-specific information are given in Figure 16.1 (b).

16.2.4 Preference Functions

In this model, aid is allocated using a preference function representing the preference a donor has for awarding aid to a recipient. For a given donor c16-math-0042 and recipient c16-math-0043, this function depends explicitly on c16-math-0044, c16-math-0045, c16-math-0046 and c16-math-0047, c16-math-0048 where superscript • indicates ‘all countries in c16-math-0049’.

For each donor c16-math-0050 and recipient c16-math-0051, define the preference function as

The functions c16-math-0053, c16-math-0054 and c16-math-0055, c16-math-0056 are to be specified for each donor c16-math-0057.

Note that the functions c16-math-0058 and c16-math-0059 are country specific: in general, two different donors, c16-math-0060 and c16-math-0061, have two different sets of functions c16-math-0062 and c16-math-0063. Although we could suppress this additional generality, enforcing the same set of functions for all donors, we exploit this at a later stage when exploring donor heterogeneity.

For clarity, consider the relationship defined by Equation (16.1): given donor c16-math-0064 and recipient c16-math-0065, for each component of c16-math-0066, we have a function c16-math-0067 of c16-math-0068 and c16-math-0069. Then c16-math-0070 depends on both the relationship between donor c16-math-0071 and recipient c16-math-0072 and the relationship between donor c16-math-0073 and all other recipients in c16-math-0074. The same holds for functions c16-math-0075.

This construction therefore emphasises the role of the network of nations: the preference function assigned to each donor–recipient dyad depends upon both the dyad and all other recipients.

16.2.5 Specifying the Preference Functions

In applying the model, we must specify numerical quantities associated with the behaviour under investigation and, crucially, functions c16-math-0076 and c16-math-0077 for each donor c16-math-0078. While there is an arbitrariness in this specification, it can nonetheless provide insight into aid allocation.

Here, the functions take the following form:

The role of the superscript • is seen in the denominator of the bracketed quantities in (16.2) and (16.3).

Equations (16.2) and (16.3) warrant the following explanation:

  1. Input (positive correlation): in (16.2) and (16.3), indicators positively correlated with aid allocation have the functional input
    equation

    that is, as a proportion of the total c16-math-0082 between c16-math-0083 and all recipients, or the total quantity of c16-math-0084 among all recipients, respectively. A country with a greater proportion of a given quantity receives a greater allocation of preference and, hence, aid than a country with a lesser proportion.

  2. Input (negative correlation): in (16.2) and (16.3), indicators negatively correlated with aid allocation have the functional input
    equation

    A country with a lesser proportion of a given quantity receives a greater allocation of preference and, hence, aid than a country with a greater proportion. In this case, we alter (16.2) and (16.3) accordingly.

  3. Parameters: the parameters c16-math-0086 and c16-math-0087 can take values in c16-math-0088, the positive real numbers including zero. All other things being equal, if a parameter takes
    • the value 0: allocation is uniform;
    • the value 1: allocation is strictly proportional;
    • values in c16-math-0089: allocation is ‘sub-proportional’, tending towards ambivalence as the parameter approaches 0;
    • values in c16-math-0090: allocation is ‘super-proportional’, increasingly favouring the most preferred recipient as the parameter tends to c16-math-0091.

16.2.6 Recipient Selection by Donors

In recipient selection, we assume there exists a minimum aid volume (a lower bound), c16-math-0092, below which donor c16-math-0093 does not allocate. This threshold could be set uniformly for all donor nations and can also be set to zero.

Each donor ranks all recipients by preference, then allocates aid to the largest subset of this ranking such that

  • each recipient receives aid greater than or equal to the threshold c16-math-0094;
  • each recipient receiving aid has greater preference than all recipients not receiving aid.

If the threshold is set to zero, all donors receive some aid.

16.3 Application of the Model

16.3.1 Introduction

We illustrate the aid allocation model through three scenarios using the preference function (16.1), (16.2), (16.3) and the aforementioned model algorithm. All scenarios have the same set-up: three donors c16-math-0095 and three recipients c16-math-0096. This situation is described by Figure 16.1. By varying donor behaviour, these scenarios emphasise different aspects of the model, especially system feedbacks.

Figure 16.2 gives a schematic representation of our model (with only a single donor c16-math-0099 present for clarity). Recipient states, donor states, donor–recipient relationships and donor community activity feed into c16-math-0100's preference, determining aid allocation. In turn, this allocation affects the recipient states and the donor community in two feedback loops. This feedback is a simple source of complexity in the model and will be explored explicitly in the sequel.

nfgz002

Figure 16.2 A schematic model representation with recipients c16-math-0097 and donor c16-math-0098. Arrows show information flows; dashed lines, feedback; hyphens, inter-country relationships

16.3.2 Scenario 1. No Feedback

This scenario examines the impact of heterogeneous donor motivation in aid allocation, introducing the model and its mode of operation. Donor motivation consists of recipient poverty c16-math-0101, colonial relationships c16-math-0102 and trade flows c16-math-0103 (see Appendix A.1 for functional definitions). The scenario set-up is described in Figure 16.3; a detailed explanation of this figure is provided in Section 16.2.3. Note that all donors provide the same aid volume (normalised to 1); there is no minimum allocation threshold (see Section 16.2.6 for details).

nfgz003

Figure 16.3 Scenario 1 set-up emphasising the role of node-specific information and inter-country relationships. The table notes the data included in this scenario, while each network diagram encodes relevant allocation data

The ratio of poverty headcount between recipient countries is c16-math-0104; trade relationships are the same for each donor, with the ratio between recipients given by c16-math-0105, for c16-math-0106. Finally, for completeness, c16-math-0107 is a former colony of c16-math-0108 and c16-math-0109 while c16-math-0110 is a former colony of c16-math-0111.

Using (16.1), (16.2) and (16.3), we write the preference function:

equation

where

16.4 equation

For ease, we take the matrix of parameters as

equation

The choice of parameters governs the distribution of aid. We consider three different donor behaviours, showing the impact of (sub-/super-)proportional allocation (see Section 16.2.5).

Suppose alleviation of poverty is the only donor motive, and all donors value poverty identically (i.e. they have the same parameter choice). Let donors allocate proportionally, c16-math-0115, sub-proportionally, c16-math-0116 and super-proportionally, c16-math-0117:

equation

For each parameter choice, the allocation is given by Figure 16.4.

nfgz004

Figure 16.4 Model allocation for parameter choices 1, 2 and 3

The outcomes reflect recipient poverty headcount distribution, biased by donor motivation: when allocation is strictly proportional, c16-math-0119, recipient c16-math-0120 has 14% of total poverty and therefore receives 14% of total aid. Parameter choices c16-math-0121 and c16-math-0122 place, respectively, lesser and greater emphasis on poverty as a motivator of allocation, relative to the proportional allocation c16-math-0123.

Suppose that countries now allocate based on the poverty and colonial relationships. Again, let donors allocate proportionally, c16-math-0124, sub-proportionally, c16-math-0125 and super-proportionally, c16-math-0126:

equation

For each parameter choice, the allocation is given by Figure 16.5.

nfgz005

Figure 16.5 Model allocation for parameter choices 4, 5 and 6

In the proportional case (c16-math-0128), including the positive aid allocation–colonial relationship, correlation in the preference function reduces by around 15% the allocation to c16-math-0129, the recipient allocated most aid when poverty alone comprises donor behaviour, compared with the proportional allocation from Figure 16.4. In turn, the allocation to both c16-math-0130 and c16-math-0131 increases, especially to c16-math-0132 which is rewarded for its two colonial relationships with the donor community.

As earlier, parameter choices c16-math-0133 and c16-math-0134 place, respectively, lesser and greater emphasis on the overall combination of poverty and colonial history in aid allocation. Note also that c16-math-0135's parameter choice is the same as that from Figure 16.4 as it has no colonies.

These allocations are not obvious despite the simplicity of the situation (even assuming proportional allocation). In effect, identical signals from each recipient produce differing donor responses as a result of the unique set of donor–recipient relationships, even when donors share the same ‘values’ (parameter choices). This hints at the complexity of donor heterogeneity coupled with aggregation of aid flows.

Suppose now that commercial ties influence allocation, in addition to colonial relationships and poverty: donors reward recipients with whom they enjoy a large trade volume. Suppose that only c16-math-0136 and c16-math-0137 are influenced in this manner, with c16-math-0138 steadfastly continuing to allocate based on poverty alone. Again, let donors allocate proportionally, c16-math-0139, sub-proportionally, c16-math-0140 and super-proportionally, c16-math-0141:

equation

For each parameter choice, the allocation is given by Figure 16.6.

nfgz006

Figure 16.6 Model allocation for parameter choices 7, 8 and 9

While c16-math-0143 has the largest trade volume and poverty in absolute terms, overall donor behaviour has drawn aid away from the ‘most deserving’ recipient: aid is shared so that c16-math-0144, with middling poverty, strong colonial and modest trade relationships, is allocated approximately the same amount as c16-math-0145. This is in line with Alesina and Dollar 2000 who assert that former colonies are favoured over other nations; donors c16-math-0146 and c16-math-0147 act in this way, while c16-math-0148 is ‘Nordic’ in that it allocates based only upon need (see Alesina and Dollar 2000). This allocation with multiple criteria and heterogeneous donor motivation produces a radically different allocation to that given in Figure 16.4.

This scenario highlights both the operation of the model and the complex interactions at the heart of aid allocation, emphasising that aggregate flows are a poor indicator of donor behaviour when heterogeneous multi-objective behaviour is the norm in the donor community.

16.3.3 Scenario 2. Bandwagon Feedback

Bandwagon behaviour is the tendency of donors to act in a self-reinforcing collective manner. Certain recipient countries gain ‘star’ status relative to others despite seemingly little difference between such nations. While this may be attributed to increasing selectivity of aid, the tendency of donors to reward effective aid usage - see Dollar and Levin (2006), recent work suggests that herd behaviour can play a significant role, see Frot and Santiso (2011). Recipients previously awarded large aid volumes are then preferred by the donor community and are rewarded as such in subsequent allocation. (Although selectivity is not considered here, it could be incorporated as a positively correlated effectiveness input with a super-proportional parameter choice.)

Donors allocate based on recipient poverty c16-math-0149, commercial ties c16-math-0150 and previous success in receiving aid c16-math-0151 (see Appendix A.1 for functional definitions). The model is dynamic: with fixed demographic factors, aid volume changes as the model is iterated forward in time from c16-math-0152. Donors reward recipients which are successful in garnering aid; this ‘community action’ affects subsequent allocation and corresponds to the clockwise feedback loop in Figure 16.2.

The basic set-up of this scenario is as follows. Donors c16-math-0153 and c16-math-0154 allocate one unit of aid (c16-math-0155) while donor c16-math-0156 allocates two units (c16-math-0157). As earlier, the ratio of poverty headcount between recipient countries is c16-math-0158. Only donor c16-math-0159 has significant trade relationships: the ratio between recipients is given by c16-math-0160.

Using (16.1), (16.2), and (16.3) we write:

16.5 equation

where

16.6 equation
16.7 equation

We take the matrix of parameters as

equation

We consider two different parameter choices, showing the impact of bandwagon feedback on the allocation of aid, driven by poverty and commercial interest, respectively.

Let all donors allocate according to recipient poverty and experience a sub-proportional tendency towards bandwagon behaviour (as this is a relatively subtle effect, see Frot and Santiso (2011)). Allocation based on poverty and bandwagon behaviour manifests in the following parameter choice:

16.8 equation

For this parameter choice, the aid allocation from c16-math-0166 to c16-math-0167 is given by Figure 16.7.

nfgz007

Figure 16.7 Model allocation for parameter choice 10

As we move forwards in time, it is clear that c16-math-0168, the country allocated most aid based upon the poverty measure at c16-math-0169, has increased its share of aid by approximately 50% at c16-math-0170. Correspondingly, the country allocated least aid at c16-math-0171, c16-math-0172, has seen its share of aid fall by a significant factor by c16-math-0173.

This illustrates the bandwagon phenomenon driven by aid volume: c16-math-0174 experiences an increase in aid allocation as a result of prior success in garnering aid. While a contrived example, this scenario demonstrates one approach to modelling bandwagon behaviour in the donor community.

Suppose now that c16-math-0175 and c16-math-0176 allocate based on poverty, but c16-math-0177 allocates based on commercial interests; all donors are subject to a sub-proportional bandwagon influence.

Allocation based on this situation manifests in the following parameter choice:

16.9 equation

For this parameter choice, the aid allocation from c16-math-0179 to c16-math-0180 is given by Figure 16.8.

nfgz008

Figure 16.8 Model allocation for parameter choice 11

In this case, we see that the conflicting motivations of donor nations have produced a complex result. c16-math-0181 and c16-math-0182 prioritise c16-math-0183 as the ‘neediest’ nation, but have also been drawn towards c16-math-0184 via a bandwagon effect resulting from c16-math-0185's commercially driven aid allocation. As neither c16-math-0186, c16-math-0187 or c16-math-0188 prioritise c16-math-0189, the share of aid received by c16-math-0190 and c16-math-0191 increases. If the strength of the bandwagon behaviour were stronger, the self-reinforcing behaviour would draw increasing volumes of aid from c16-math-0192 toward c16-math-0193 over time.

These two examples show the bandwagon allocation mechanism, albeit in an exaggerated manner. The first shows that, in our model, poverty itself can act as a driver of bandwagon behaviour: even though all nations prioritise poverty alleviation, they can be affected by the relative success of certain nations over time. The good intentions of donor nations can be subverted by their tendency towards ‘groupthink’.

The second example shows how, in our model, varying motives and donated aid volumes can lead to a complex allocation outcome in the presence of bandwagon behaviour. A rich donor allocating a large quantity of aid for self-interested purposes can lead smaller but well-intentioned donors astray.

16.3.4 Scenario 3. Aid Effectiveness Feedback

This scenario presents a simple dynamic model of aid usage that allows us to explore how donors react to the changing fortunes of recipients, independent of the bandwagon effects discussed in Section 16.3.3. As earlier, we simplify the system under consideration for the purposes of elucidation.

Take recipient poverty c16-math-0194, trade relationships c16-math-0195 and governance quality c16-math-0196 as the discriminators used by donors in aid allocation. We allow each recipient nation to use allocated aid to decrease poverty (in line with humanitarian concerns) and increase trade flows (as a proxy for economic development). Governance quality is constant throughout.

Using basic financial mathematics, aid usage decisions concerning trade expansion and poverty alleviation are treated as an investment portfolio for recipients: we assume that recipients ‘invest’ their allocated aid in a risk averse manner (where ‘risk’ is quantified as the variance of the time series of the corresponding ‘asset’ returns, see below).

This model is dynamic: starting from c16-math-0197 the model is iterated forwards in time; underlying poverty and trade volumes change as a result of recipient investment decisions. This, in turn, impacts the way donor nations allocate their (fixed) aid volume at each time period.

The basic set-up of this scenario is as follows. All donors allocate one unit of aid (c16-math-0198). As earlier, the ratio of poverty headcount between recipient countries is initially (at c16-math-0199) c16-math-0200; trade relationships are the same for each donor, with the ratio between recipients initially (at c16-math-0201) given by c16-math-0202, for c16-math-0203; the ratio of governance quality between recipients is c16-math-0204 and is constant throughout.

Using (16.1), (16.2) and (16.3) we write:

16.10 equation

where

16.11 equation

Note that trade c16-math-0207 and poverty c16-math-0208 are dynamic quantities, while governance quantity c16-math-0209 is not. We take the matrix of parameters as

equation

Donors highly value a recipient country's level of poverty, allocate proportionally based on governance quality and have a sub-proportional interest in trade links.

16.3.5 Aid Usage Mechanism

We treat aid usage as an investment decision in the context of Modern Portfolio Theory (MPT) (see Adams et al. 2003 for an introduction to this topic). In essence, a portfolio in MPT consists of a number of possible assets each with normally distributed returns. An investment decision aims to minimise the risk of the total portfolio: risk is identified with the variance of each asset.

In the case of aid usage, each recipient country is allocated a certain aid volume. A fixed proportion of this, c16-math-0211, is then ‘invested’ in a portfolio consisting of a number of assets, here trade volume and poverty alleviation. The remaining proportion is lost to, for example, corruption; for ease, we allow 15% of allocated aid to be lost here; this quantity could be set for each country independently. An investment in poverty alleviation decreases poverty, and an investment in trade volume increases total exports.

When deciding how to invest, recipients aim to minimise risk across this portfolio, identified with the corresponding asset return variance: a large variance implies a riskier asset, a small variance a less risky asset. Assuming returns on each asset in the portfolio are normally distributed, with a specified mean and standard deviation, we can devise a risk-minimising investment decision.

MPT allows one to incorporate the correlation between each of the normally distributed variables in the portfolio as a whole. Note that this analysis can be extended to multiple correlated variables, assuming a multivariate normal distribution across the portfolio (see Adams et al. 2003). We simplify matters here by assuming the asset returns are uncorrelated.

Denote by c16-math-0212 recipient c16-math-0213's investment portfolio. This consists of two assets, poverty and trade volume:

equation

We must determine the proportion of allocated aid a recipient invests in each possible asset. To this end, we determine the asset returns: for recipient c16-math-0215, define the asset return at time c16-math-0216 as

equation

This then produces the time series of asset returns from c16-math-0218:

equation

Suppose these time series are normally distributed, as required by MPT. One can then calculate the means c16-math-0220 and c16-math-0221 and standard deviations c16-math-0222 and c16-math-0223, respectively.

According to MPT, the expected return on the investment is

equation

subject to the constraint

equation

where c16-math-0226 is a parameter to be found (see Adams et al. 2003): this parameter determines the proportion of c16-math-0227 devoted to poverty alleviation (c16-math-0228) and the proportion devoted to trade volume expansion (c16-math-0229).

Under the assumption of normally distributed asset returns

equation

as the means c16-math-0231 and standard deviations c16-math-0232 are constant in time.

This situation has an optimal ‘risk-minimising’ solution when

equation

This determines the ‘risk-minimising’ investment opportunity or, alternatively, the proportional investment in each possible asset which minimises the standard deviation of the total investment.

Then, aid usage is determined by investing c16-math-0234 in c16-math-0235 and c16-math-0236 in c16-math-0237, thus maximising the expected rate of return while minimising the overall portfolio risk. The model is re-evaluated at each time step c16-math-0238.

16.3.6 Application

Continuing with Scenario 3, we apply the mechanism presented in Section 16.3.5. The initial aid allocation is shown in Figure 16.9 (c16-math-0239). We supplement this data with the mean and variance of each asset for each recipient. Guided by recipient governance quality, given in Section 16.3.4, we assign these according to Table 16.1.

nfgz009

Figure 16.9 Aid allocation incorporating aid usage

Table 16.1 Parameters determining recipient investment

Country c16-math-0241 c16-math-0242 c16-math-0243 c16-math-0244
P 2 0.2 2 0.2
Q 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.7
R 0.5 0.7 0.5 0.7

Countries with lower governance quality c16-math-0240 are likely to lack the necessary bureaucratic infrastructure to successfully utilise development aid or lose aid to corruption throughout the investment process. Therefore, we associate a greater risk to countries with lower governance quality.1

Iterating the model forward from c16-math-0245, aid allocation is as shown in Figure 16.9.

We see that c16-math-0246 is initially allocated the largest aid volume, reflecting its poverty headcount; c16-math-0247 experiences its largest allocation at c16-math-0248, with diminishing subsequent allocations. c16-math-0249 has the smallest initial allocation, which grows as the model is iterated forwards in time. c16-math-0250 has a middling initial allocation, which diminishes initially, reaching a nadir at c16-math-0251, but growing again thereafter.

We can explain this situation by considering the changes resulting from recipient investment of aid (see Figure 16.10).

nfgz010

Figure 16.10 Poverty and trade levels of recipients following aid investment

Following the initial allocation, c16-math-0252 draws most aid. The investment parameters indicate (see Table 16.1) that c16-math-0253 invests equally in poverty reduction and trade expansion. However, having a significantly greater headcount than either c16-math-0254 or c16-math-0255, c16-math-0256 continues to draw heavily from a donor community highly motivated by poverty.

c16-math-0257 also splits its investment evenly between poverty reduction and trade expansion, but receives a relatively small aid volume compared to its comparator recipient nations. However, its fortunes begin to change after c16-math-0258 has decreased its poverty headcount sufficiently for the governance advantage held by c16-math-0259 to become a determining factor in aid allocation; aid volumes increase significantly after c16-math-0260.

c16-math-0261 receives relatively little aid throughout, losing out initially to c16-math-0262 and c16-math-0263. However, as c16-math-0264's aid allocation drops after c16-math-0265, c16-math-0266 begins to benefit. It is bias towards poverty reduction, as seen in investment parameters given in Table 16.1, mean its poverty headcount is reduced at a greater pace than trade expansion, which diminishes its likelihood of receiving aid in the subsequent time period.

16.3.7 Conclusions

Scenario 3 has shown how aid usage may be factored into a model of aid allocation, closing the counter-clockwise feedback loop of Figure 16.2 and feeding into donor preferences in allocation. Again, this process can produce complex outcomes.

While the approach sketched out earlier is clearly a heuristic, a stand-in for a full economic model encompassing the impact aid allocation on recipient economies, it does begin to encode behaviour identified in the literature.

16.4 Remarks

This Chapter presents a novel model of foreign aid allocation based on the mathematical theory of networks. Our intention is to capture the interconnected nature of this system, shedding light on the complex interactions between donors and recipients.

As we have shown, complex donor motivators in aid allocation can be described by our model. In particular, we have shown that heterogeneous donor motivation can lead to a wide variety of behaviours, even when donor nations share the same laudable intentions. Commercial and colonial relationships are shown to interact in an unpredictable manner with more altruistic, poverty-minded motivations.

Crucially, all allocations by our model are made in reference to the wider community of donors and recipients. This emphasises the increasingly networked nature of the global aid system which cannot be captured by more traditional dyadic analyses.

Our model allows for a simple characterisation of bandwagon behaviour (see Section 16.3.3). This characterisation is carried out in explicitly network theoretic terms and, hence, is an exploratory tool allowing connections not seen when using more traditional aid allocation models.

As we have shown, albeit in an exaggerated manner, bandwagon behaviour not only can skew the allocation of aid but can do so in an unexpected way in the context of our model. Over time, even a small tendency towards self-reinforcing behaviour can have a substantial impact upon the allocation of aid. This interaction becomes increasingly complex as the number of donor motivators increases.

This chapter joins an increasing chorus arguing that foreign aid should be viewed through the lens of complex systems analysis. Such a perspective suggests that aggregated data and assumptions in favour of homogeneity of motivation and behaviour are insufficient to describe global aid patterns. This chapter offers a new perspective on aid allocation and also suggests a new approach towards aid effectiveness using a conceptual-numerical modeling lens.

Acknowledgements

The authors thank R.G. Levy for a valuable tour of the development economics literature and the code used to generate the network images. A.G. Wilson and F.T. Smith provided helpful suggestions in developing this chapter. The authors acknowledge the financial support of the Engineering and Physical Sciences Research Council under the grant ENFOLDing—Explaining, Modelling, and Forecasting Global Dynamics, reference EP/H02185X/1.

References

  1. Adams, A.T., Booth, P.M., Bowie, D.C., and Freeth, D.S. (2003) Investment Mathematics, John Wiley & Sons, Ltd, Chichester.
  2. Alesina, A. and Dollar, D. (2000) Who gives foreign aid to whom and why? Journal of Economic Growth, 5 (1), 33–63.
  3. Balla, E. and Reinhardt, G.Y. (2008) Giving and receiving foreign aid: does conflict count? World Development, 36 (12), 2566–2585.
  4. Baulch, B. (2003) Aid for the poorest? The distribution and maldistribution of international development assistance. Chronic Poverty Research Centre (CPRC).
  5. Bermeo, S.B. (2008) Aid strategies of bilateral donors. Department of Political Science, Yale University. Unpublished manuscript.
  6. Berthélemy, J.C. (2006) Bilateral donors' interest vs. recipients' development motives in aid allocation: do all donors behave the same? Review of Development Economics, 10 (2), 179–194.
  7. Bhanumurthy, K. (2002) Arguing a case for the Cobb-Douglas production function. Review of Commerce Studies, 20, 21.
  8. Burnside, A.C. and Dollar, D. (2004) Aid, policies, and growth: revisiting the evidence. World Bank, Washington DC.
  9. Chong, A. and Gradstein, M. (2008) What determines foreign aid? The donors' perspective. Journal of Development Economics, 87 (1), 1–13.
  10. Cobb, C.W. and Douglas, P.H. (1928) A theory of production. The American Economic Review, 18 (1), 139–165.
  11. Collier, P. and Dollar, D. (2002) Aid allocation and poverty reduction. European Economic Review, 46 (8), 1475–1500.
  12. Dollar, D. and Levin, V. (2006) The increasing selectivity of foreign aid, 1984–2003. World Development, 34 (12), 2034–2046.
  13. Frot, E. and Santiso, J. (2011) Herding in aid allocation. Kyklos, 64 (1), 54–74.
  14. Fuchs, A., Dreher, A., and Nunnenkamp, P. (2014) Determinants of donor generosity: a survey of the aid budget literature. World Development, 56, 172–199.
  15. Gallo, G. (2013) Conflict theory, complexity and systems approach. Systems Research and Behavioral Science, 30 (2), 156–175.
  16. Harrigan, J. and Wang, C. (2011) A new approach to the allocation of aid among developing countries: is the USA different from the rest? World Development, 39 (8), 1281–1293.
  17. Hommes, C.H. (2006) Heterogeneous agent models in economics and finance. Handbook of Computational Economics, 2, 1109–1186.
  18. Marler, R.T. and Arora, J.S. (2004) Survey of multi-objective optimization methods for engineering. Structural and Multidisciplinary Optimization, 26 (6), 369–395.
  19. McBurney, P. (2012) What are models for? in Post-Proceedings of the 19th European Workshop on Multi-Agent Systems (EUMAS 2011), Lecture Notes in Computer Science, vol. 7541 (eds M. Cossentino, K. Tuyls, and G. Weiss) Springer-Verlag, Berlin, pp. 175–188.
  20. McGillivray, M. (2003) Modelling aid allocation: issues, approaches and results, 2003/49, WIDER Discussion Papers//World Institute for Development Economics (UNU-WIDER).
  21. McGillivray, M. (2004) Descriptive and prescriptive analyses of aid allocation: approaches, issues, and consequences. International Review of Economics & Finance, 13 (3), 275–292.
  22. McGillivray, M. (2006) Aid allocation and fragile states, in Fragile States: Causes, Costs and Responses (eds W. Naudé, A.U. Santos-Paulino, and M. McGillivray), Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp. 166–184.
  23. Newman, M. (2010) Networks: An Introduction, Oxford University Press, Oxford.
  24. Ramalingam, B. (2011) Aid on the Edge of Chaos, Oxford University Press, Oxford.
  25. Riddell, R.C. (2007) Does Foreign Aid Really Work? Oxford University Press, Oxford.
  26. Schelling, T.C. (1971) Dynamic models of segregation. Journal of Mathematical Sociology, 1 (2), 143–186.
  27. Schiller, R.J. (2000) The irrational exuberance. Princeton University Press, Princeton.
  28. Simon, H.A. and Levy, F.K. (1963) A note on the Cobb-Douglas function. The Review of Economic Studies, 30 (2), 93–94.
  29. Tarp, F., Bach, C.F., Hansen, H., and Baunsgaard, S. (1999) Danish Aid Policy: Theory and Empirical Evidence, Springer-Verlag, Heidelberg.
  30. United Kingdom Government (2002) International Development Act 2002 1(1)a.
  31. United States Government (1961) Foreign Assistance Act of 1961 Sec. 101(a).
  32. Wilson, A. (2012) The Science of Cities and Regions, Springer-Verlag, Berlin.
  33. Younas, J. (2008) Motivation for bilateral aid allocation: altruism or trade benefits. European Journal of Political Economy, 24 (3), 661–674.

Appendix

A.1 Common Functional Definitions

Common functional definitions are collected in this appendix. Variables not discussed here may be assumed to be easily defined from Section 16.2.5.

Variable Definition
c16-math-0267 Colonial relationship between donor c16-math-0268 and recipient c16-math-0269:
equation


The ‘null’ condition 1 is arbitrary: the key point is that donors have greater preference for colonial over non-colonial recipients (see Alesina and Dollar 2000). A more complex measure would be the fraction of the last century for which a colonial relationship existed (see Alesina and Dollar 2000).

c16-math-0271

Prior success in receiving aid, the total volume of aid received in the previous year, c16-math-0272 where c16-math-0273 indicates time. Assume that when c16-math-0274, c16-math-0275 is allocated identically for all recipients:

equation
..................Content has been hidden....................

You can't read the all page of ebook, please click here login for view all page.
Reset
13.59.180.145