CHAPTER 3

Factors Influencing Entrepreneurial Activities

Introduction

Shane et al. were particularly interested in improving the quality and conciseness of research on how human motivations influence entrepreneurship; however, they suggested a model that may well have a broader application in the design of an analytical framework for studying the various factors that influence entrepreneurship.1 Shane et al. believed that entrepreneurship was best viewed as a “process” that occurred over an extended period of time, rather than an isolated event or moment in time when a person decides whether he or she should become an “entrepreneur.” This process included a number of stages, including recognition of opportunities, development of ideas about how to pursue the opportunity by turning it into new products or services, and, finally, execution of the activities required to harvest the desired profits from the opportunities. The execution phase involved an array of tasks and activities such as evaluating the feasibility of the opportunity, product or service development, assembly of human and financial resources, organizational design, and “market making” (i.e., identification and pursuit of customers). In their model, the success or failure of the entire entrepreneurial process, and the decisions made along the way are influenced by several important factors. The motivational traits of the prospective entrepreneur is one of them; however, in order to get a complete picture it is necessary to also take into account other factors that Shane et al. felt had been ignored by previous researchers such as cognitive factors, the nature of the opportunity, and environmental conditions.2

In order to address the concerns described above regarding the inadequacies of previous research on the relationship between human motivation and entrepreneurship, Shane et al. devised their own “model of entrepreneurial motivation and the entrepreneurial process” that focused on the factors that came into play at various points where individuals (i.e., “entrepreneurs”) transitioned from one stage of the entrepreneurial process to the next. It was assumed that at each “transition point,” such as moving from “opportunity recognition” to “idea development,” influences might come from one or more categories of factors: entrepreneurial motivations, entrepreneurial opportunities, and conditions and cognitive factors.3 However, the mix of influences in play at a particular stage was not fixed, nor was the relative importance of specific factors. Interestingly, the model did not attempt to identify relationships between any of the factors and traditional measures of “success” or “performance,” such as profitability or growth rates, but simply focused on sensitizing researchers to the influences on the actions that entrepreneurs must take as they pursue development and commercialization of their ideas. In other words, in contrast to earlier models and assumptions, Shane et al. recognized that the most relevant effects of factors such as “entrepreneurial motivations” on venture performance and growth may actually be more “indirect” than “direct.”4

The elements of the analytical framework suggested by Shane et al. were similar in many ways to those used by Baum et al. in studying the growth of small companies in the architectural woodworking industry.5 Baum et al. analyzed 29 variables divided among five different domains, including “traits and motivations,” which included motivational factors similar to those described by Shane et al., such as hard work, tenacity, and drive; situation-specific motivation, such as goals and self-efficacy; cognitive skills; business strategies; and environmental factors. Interestingly, consistent with the arguments made by Shane et al., Baum et al. found that motivational factors did have an effect on the growth of the ventures included in their study but that the effects were “indirect,” meaning that motives came into play as influencers of other domains such as cognitive skills, situation-specific motivation, and business strategies.6 The sections that follow combine the various factors and domains identified by Shane et al. and Baum et al. to describe an analytical model of the entrepreneurial process that would incorporate several key factors: entrepreneurial motivations, cognitive factors, entrepreneurial opportunities, environmental conditions, competitive strategies, and, finally, certain nonmotivational individual differences that have been shown to play an important role on the willingness of people to engage in entrepreneurial activities.

While not explicitly incorporated into the sections below, notice should also be taken of the “entrepreneurial process model,” which is a conceptual framework proposed by Kantis to analyze and understand the “entrepreneurial process” and facilitate comparison of the conditions confronting prospective entrepreneurs in different countries.7 While conceding, as others have done, that the entrepreneurial process does not necessarily follow a linear sequence, Kantis suggested that it was useful to analyze that process as three stages of events, which, hopefully, lead to the creation of entrepreneurs and entrepreneurial firms.8 The first stage was “inception of the entrepreneurial venture” and involved three key activities and related questions. First, the prospective entrepreneur needs to acquire the motivation and skills needed to become an entrepreneur and this raises the following questions: what are the motivating factors that first lead a person to think about becoming an entrepreneur? how does the entrepreneur’s immediate social context influence the motivational process? and where does an individual find the motivation and skills needed to become an entrepreneur? Second, the business opportunity for the new enterprise must be identified and researchers would like to know the principal sources of business opportunities and how entrepreneurs find and identify these opportunities? Finally, business planning is required during the preparatory phase and the inquiries focus on what information and planning tools do entrepreneurs use? The second stage is “company startup” and begins with the final decision to begin entrepreneurial activity. Kantis suggested that it is important to understand how entrepreneurs make the final decision to start a new business. Once the decision has been made, the inquiry turns to understanding how entrepreneurs access and mobilize the financial and nonfinancial resources needed to launch a business. The last of the three stages is early development of the firm including introduction to the market of the firm’s goods and services and management of the firm during the early years. The key questions for this stage include what factors influence market entry; what are the main problems confronting entrepreneurs during this phase and how to they deal with those problems; and how do entrepreneurs finance firm operations and growth?

Having defined and explained the “entrepreneurial process,” Kantis suggests that a model of an “entrepreneurial development system” can be created by adding in a combination of elements and factors that have an impact, both positive and negative, on the process and, ultimately, on the efficient development of entrepreneurs and entrepreneurial firms. Kantis grouped these factors into a short list of categories, which he introduced and described as follows9:

  • Social and economic conditions reflect the profile of the ­households from which potential entrepreneurs emerge and take into factors such as the degree of social fragmentation, access to education, flow of information relevant to entrepreneurial activity, income levels, and overall macroeconomic conditions such as the behavior of demand or the degree of economic stability;
  • Societal culture, which is discussed extensively in this book, influences the formation of the “entrepreneurial spirit” and cultural values impact important factors such as the social value ascribed to the entrepreneur and attitudes toward the risk of failure;
  • Productive structure and dynamism refers to the sector and regional profile and the size of the existing enterprises and institutions and is considered important because it determines the type of work and professional experience, including opportunities for the development of entrepreneurial skills and networks of relationships (see below), which individuals can obtain prior to becoming entrepreneurs;
  • Personal aspects, which refers to sociodemographic profile of the entrepreneur—which are influenced by his or her family, educational and work environments—and his or her entrepreneurial skills (e.g., propensity to assume risk, tolerance for hard work, managerial capacities, and creativity);
  • Networks, which include the assistance provided through his or her social networks (i.e., friends and family), institutional networks (i.e., business associations, institutions of higher learning and/or development agencies), and commercial networks (i.e., suppliers and customers);
  • Factor markets, which provide entrepreneurs with access to financial resources (e.g., bank loans, venture capital, and/or government financing), skilled labor, and professional services (accountants, consultants, etc.) and suppliers of inputs and equipment; and
  • Regulations and policies that have an impact on enterprise creation, such as taxes, procedural requirements for formally establishing a new firm, and initiatives and programs to develop entrepreneurship.

In many ways, the list of factors developed by Kantis was similar to those discussed in the following sections. For example, the issues consumed in personal aspects and networks can also be found in the discussion of entrepreneurial motivations, cognitive factors, and nonmotivational individual differences. In addition, social and economic conditions and societal culture are part of the relevant environmental conditions and productive structure and dynamism determine entrepreneurial opportunities and competitive strategies. As noted above, Kantis himself deployed his model as a tool for cross-border comparison of entrepreneurial activities and policies.

Entrepreneurial Motivations

The “entrepreneurial motivations” that Shane et al. included in their model were similar to those that they had identified and analyzed in their survey of previous research discussed above and were separated into “general” and “task-specific.” Motivations classified as “general” included nAch, locus of control, “vision,” desire for independence, passion, and drive. The motivations classified as “task-specific” included “goal-­setting” and “self-efficacy” and were similar to those analyzed in the “situation-­specific motivation” domain of the Baum et al. study.10 Once again, it is important to emphasize the Shane et al. believed that the influence of any of these motivations varied depending upon the stage of the entrepreneurial process:

In some cases, all of the motivations might matter. In other cases, only some of the motivations might matter. The relative magnitudes of how much each motivation matters will likely vary, depending on the part of the process under investigation. In fact, it is quite plausible that motivations that influence one part of the process have all of their effects at that stage in the process and have no effects on later stages in the process.11

Baum et al. tested for the influence of traits and motives of entrepreneurs on venture success.12 They noted that several important personality theorists, such as McClelland, had argued that personality predispositions were important predictors of the success of entrepreneurial ventures13 and observed that venture capitalists, whose job it is to “pick winners” among all the proposals and opportunities presented to them by would-be entrepreneurs, had consistently emphasized how much weight they gave to “entrepreneur characteristics” as key indicators of profitable investments.14 The problem, from a research perspective, was that studies had shown a relatively weak relationship between the traits and motives of entrepreneurs and venture performance and that traits and motives were not nearly as important to venture success as organizational and industry variables.15 Baum et al. believed that the influence of individual-level traits and motives of entrepreneurs had not been properly recognized because they did not work in isolation from other factors and the previous studies had not included the proper traits.16 In their study they supplemented the pool of entrepreneurial traits by adding tenacity, pro-activity, and passion and tested not only for a direct relationship of traits and motives on venture growth but also for the relationship that traits and motives had on other influencers of venture growth (i.e., “indirect effects”). While they did not find support for the hypothesis that, with all other antecedents of venture growth controlled, the greater the tenacity, pro-activity, and passion for work of a venture’s CEO, the greater the venture’s growth, they did find evidence that these individual-level traits and motives did have a strong influence on several other factors relevant to venture growth, including general competencies, situation-specific motivation, and competitive strategies.17

As mentioned above, Baum et al. created and tested a separate dimension for several situational-specific motivations, including “vision,” growth goals, and self-efficacy.18 These motivations were distinguished from the other entrepreneurial traits and motives because they had previously demonstrated “significant empirical relationships with business performance” and had been celebrated by researchers as important for planning and venture performance.19 Baum et al. did indeed find ­confirmation for the hypothesis that “[t]he greater the situationally specific motivation of a venture’s CEO with respect to vision, growth goals, and self-efficacy, the greater the venture’s growth.”20 Apparently, these traits and motivations had a much greater direct effect on venture growth than the more ­“general” traits and motives tested by Baum et al.; however, those ­general traits and motives did have a significant influence on the strength of the situational-specific motivations.21 The general competencies of entrepreneurs also had a large influence on their situational-specific motivations. Situational-specific motivations also had a significant influence on ­elements of the competitive strategies selected by entrepreneurs, which, in turn, ultimately influenced venture growth. Specifically, Baum et al. argued that organizations led by highly motivated entrepreneurs often reflected the character of these entrepreneurs as evidenced by the choices made regarding organizational structures and processes and the bias toward recruiting goal-oriented employees.22

Cognitive Factors

According to Locke, all action is a result of the integration or combination of motivational and cognitive factors and thus it was necessary and appropriate for Shane et al. to include certain cognitive factors—knowledge, skills, and abilities (“KSAs”)—in their analytical framework.23 They explained that entrepreneurs must have “some knowledge,” particularly knowledge about the industry and markets in which they are involved and the technology that is relevant to the projected success of the entrepreneurial activities. In addition, entrepreneurs must have certain skills, the range of which depends on the circumstances, which can be called upon during the various stages of entrepreneurial process. Shane et al. listed skills such as “selling and bargaining, leadership, planning, decision making, problem solving, team building, communication and conflict management.” Shane et al. mentioned that entrepreneurs can hire persons to fill in gaps in their own “skill set”; however, they believed that entrepreneurs cannot rely on others for the knowledge about the industry and technology that is crucial for setting the right course during the entrepreneurial process. Finally, entrepreneurs needed certain abilities, such as intelligence, in order to acquire and process the knowledge and develop and use the skills referred to above.

As with the “entrepreneurial motivations,” the KSAs are needed in order for entrepreneurs to navigate the entrepreneurship process and Shane et al. noted that not only did the KSAs come into play in making the best decisions at each stage of the process but also in the development of an overriding “vision” for entrepreneurial activities, including formulation of a viable strategy for the firm.24 Inclusion of these cognitive factors in the model was consistent with the findings of other researchers that have highlighted the importance of certain types of knowledge and skills on various phases of the entrepreneurial process, particularly the startup and resource assembly and organization stages.25 Motivations are linked to cognitive factors in that motivations provide entrepreneurs with the incentive and drive to acquire the necessary KSAs and take the actions necessary to implement the vision and associated strategies.

KSAs were also part of the foundational principles for the “individual competencies” domain in the Baum et al. model.26 Baum et al. actually broke out this domain into two categories: “general” competencies, which included an array of so-called organizational competencies such as oral presentation skills, decision-making ability, conceptualization ­ability, diagnostic use of concepts, use of power, and “opportunity recognition”; and “specific competencies,” which included technical skills and industry skills.27 They found that the general competencies of a venture’s CEO, particularly with respect to organizational skills and opportunity recognition, did not have a material positive relationship on ­venture growth; however, they did influence situation-specific motivations and the ­selection process for competitive strategies. On the other hand, specific competencies were found to have a direct positive relationship with, and effect on, venture growth.28 In their own words, Baum et al. explained:

We speculate that an entrepreneur’s technical and industry competencies are an important form of expert power that facilitates the implementation of the entrepreneur’s vision and strategy. We can further hypothesize that these entrepreneurial skills may serve as sources of competitive advantage that rivals find difficult to identify and imitate.29

Notice should be taken of the work of Nassif et al., who studied entrepreneurship from a dynamic perspective in order to gain a better understanding of the values, characteristics, and actions over time as they launch and develop their businesses.30 Based on their analysis of work by various researchers on the types and characteristics of Brazilian small business entrepreneurs, Nassif et al. developed an entrepreneurial process dynamics framework that included and distinguished “affective aspects,” which were most important during the earliest stages of the entrepreneurial process, and “cognitive aspects,” which became more important relative to the affective aspects as time went on and the business matured. The affective aspects included perseverance, courage, willpower, initiative, willingness to take risks, personal motivation, facing challenges, passion for the business, autonomy, self-confidence, and independence. Cognitive aspects included assumption of calculated risks, ability to establish partnerships, defining goals and planning skills, knowing one’s limits, and eloquent communication skills.

Entrepreneurial Opportunities

Shane et al. argue that the nature of entrepreneurship, including the decisions made with regard to entrepreneurial actions and even deciding whether or not entrepreneurship is an appropriate and desired path, depends upon the specific “opportunity” confronting the would-be entrepreneur.31 They defined “entrepreneurial opportunities” as “situations in which new goods, services, raw materials, and organizing methods can be introduced and sold at greater than the cost of their production.”32 The problem, of course, is coming up with a reasonable estimate of the “expected value” of an opportunity since, by definition, an opportunity is all about potential rather than guarantees. One issue, of course, is that there is wide range of activities that would fit within this definition of opportunity: grand and bold initiatives that seek to establish whole new industries (e.g., the early biotechnology firms) as well as more modest undertakings such as starting a new business in an established industry to exploit a small, yet potential profitable, market niche.33 In addition, the value of opportunities not only varies across industries but one also finds variations in opportunity values within industries. Still another factor that must be considered is how the entrepreneur “interprets” the opportunity. The Internet, for example, has generated a wide array of new business models from e-tailing targeting millions of potential customers to sole proprietors looking to make their mark through website design or consulting on online advertising. Finally, “solutions” clearly matter—if an entrepreneur develops a product, service, or method that creates more sales and/or lower production costs than he or she can rightly assign a high value to that opportunity.

It is assumed that an individual will generally not pursue opportunities unless they have value to the individual and a “valuable opportunity for an individual is one that generates a level of profit that exceeds the entrepreneur’s opportunity cost, a premium for the illiquidity of money, time and effort expended, and a premium for bearing risk and uncertainty.”34 Obviously, this formulation allows that some opportunities will have more value than others for a particular entrepreneur and that the same opportunity may be valued differently by different entrepreneurs.35 It does not necessarily mean that entrepreneurs will always choose the opportunity that has the highest “value” since that decision will be influenced by the motivations that are most important in the entrepreneur’s decision-making process at the particular time; however, studies have shown that entrepreneurs are more likely to pursue an opportunity based on a condition or asset that is likely to generate extraordinary returns (e.g., patented technology, large market opportunity, and/or high margins).36

Ultimately, the value of entrepreneurial opportunities only becomes clear in hindsight once the entrepreneurial process has played out and each of the stages in that process have been navigated and completed. At each point along the way information is gathered, and decisions are made, which influence the assessment of the value of the opportunity and there could arise a possibility where an opportunity ceases to be “valuable” for the entrepreneur because, for example, the anticipated level of profits no longer exceeds the entrepreneur’s estimate of the opportunity costs that will need to be borne over the remaining stages of the entrepreneurial process. All of this does necessarily dissuade the boldest of innovators from moving forward in situations where it is impossible to quantify the value of an opportunity simply because what is being attempted has never been done before. Shane et al. reminded that Steve Jobs in the PC industry and Sam Walton in retailing were able to take advantage of opportunities through entrepreneurial actions that turned nothing more than a potential market for a product or service that had not been created into tangible industries in which values could eventually be assigned to the anticipated outputs of their actions. For Jobs, he not only had to develop the technical solution (i.e., a computer with a reasonable design cost) he also had to create a new “mass market” through a combination of design features, easy-to-use software, pricing, and marketing. Walton had to test and prove the viability of his “discounting” strategy and fend off the responses of his existing competitors as well as new competitors who entered the market after Walton took the first steps.37

Environmental Conditions

A large amount of research had been done on the impact of environmental conditions on entrepreneurship and many of these studies have found indications that the success of an entrepreneurial activity, as measured by the firm growth, is influenced by things such as

(1) political factors (e.g., legal restrictions, quality of law enforcement, political stability and currency stability); (2) market forces (e.g., structure of the industry, technology regime, potential barriers to entry, market size, and population demographics); and (3) resources (e.g., availability of investment capital, labor ­market including skill availability, transportation infrastructure, and ­complimentary technology).38

Shane et al. argued that it would be interesting and useful to study whether the motivations of entrepreneurs led to different types of entrepreneurial actions and decisions under different environmental conditions.39 They also noted that in order to gain a clearer understanding of the influence of motivations on the entrepreneurial process and the impact of environmental conditions would need to be controlled, perhaps by limiting sampling to firms in the same industry pursuing comparable market and technological opportunities.

Baum et al. also analyzed environmental conditions and focused on three dimensions relating to the environment: dynamism, which is the level of environmental predictability, including the rate of market and industry change and the level of uncertainty that firms must endure due to forces that are out of their control; munificence, which refers to the support provided by the environment for organizational growth; and complexity, which is measured by the concentration or dispersion of organizations in the environment.40 Somewhat surprisingly, Baum et al. did not find sufficient evidence to support their hypothesis that a firm’s environment is related to venture growth. Specifically, operating in a stable, munificent, and simple environment did not guarantee that a firm would achieve the highest growth.41 Environmental factors did have a significant, positive influence on competitive strategies but not as much as the traits, general competencies, and situation-specific motivations of the entrepreneurs leading the firms.42 Baum et al., noting the somewhat surprising “relatively low impact of the environmental domain on venture growth,” suggested that perhaps CEOs of smaller firms have more control over the growth and performance of their firms than had previously been suggested by several “macro theories” such as those posited by Hannan and Freeman and Pfeffer and Salancik.43

Competitive Strategies

Shane et al. argued that it was important for researchers to study and analyze the role that individual motivations played in the specific decisions that entrepreneurs made at certain points during the entrepreneurial ­process—in other words, how do the motivations of the entrepreneurs influence the choices that they make regarding “business strategies.”44 Shane et al. offered several scenarios. First, they suggested that an ­inventor with a high level of self-efficacy might be more likely to take an aggressive approach regarding exploitation of his or invention, such as going through the trouble of forming their own firm, while an inventor with an invention of equal “value” but lower self-efficacy might prefer to pursue profits indirectly through the efforts of others by selecting a strategy of licensing the invention to others who take on the additional tasks found along the path of the entrepreneurial process. Another example would be the influence of the entrepreneur’s “need for independence” on financing strategies: entrepreneurs scoring high on the measure might be more motivated to self-finance their firms to avoid having to put up with the “interruptions” from outside investors while entrepreneurs scoring lower on that measure would not be uncomfortable with giving up some control over their businesses in exchange for capital (e.g., venture capital investment).

Baum et al. studied the relationship of a firm’s competitive strategy to its performance. They conceived of “competitive strategy” in terms of three broad business-level choices suggested by Porter as alternative viable approaches for dealing with environmental forces: “focus” strategies, which target a particular set of customers, segment of a product line or geographic market; “low-cost” strategies, which involve construction of efficient-scale facilities and aggressive pursuit of cost reductions; and “differentiation” strategies, which are based on attempting to ­create and market innovative, high-quality products and/or services industry-wide.45 According to Porter, in order for firms to have a chance at being ­successful they need to pick and follow one of these strategies and failure to do leaves them “stuck in the middle” and doomed to failure.46 Baum et al. found evidence supporting Porter’s proposition (i.e., that a firm’s competitive strategy will be related to performance and that the firms with the highest growth were those that emphasized either a focus, low-cost, or differentiation strategy).47 Interestingly, they also found that choices regarding competitive strategy were heavily influenced by the traits, general competencies, and situation-specific motivations of the entrepreneurs responsible for making the decisions about firm strategy.48 This finding was consistent with theories holding that personal characteristics of entrepreneurs are determinants of their personal strategies and that these personal strategies are, in turn, determinants of the strategies of the organizations that they found and lead.49

Nonmotivational Individual Differences

While Shane et al. focused on motivational differences among prospective entrepreneurs, they acknowledged that nonmotivational individual differences have been shown to play an important role in the willingness of people to pursue entrepreneurial activities. For example, researchers have found evidence that a person’s decision to become an “entrepreneur” may depend on such factors as the person’s opportunity cost,50 which is actually built into the definition of “entrepreneurial opportunity” used by Shane et al.; his or her stocks of financial capital51; the social ties that he or she may have with investors52; and the person’s career experience.53 There does not, however, appear to be much research on how these ­nonmotivational factors specifically influence particular stages of the ­entrepreneurial process. Presumably a large stock of personal ­financial capital and/or close social ties with investors would be helpful in ­procuring capital for the firm but these “advantages” may be of value during other stages of the process.

Societal Culture and Entrepreneurship

While a good deal of the research regarding entrepreneurship has focused on questions such as identifying individual traits and values that are ­positively associated with entrepreneurial activities, it is generally ­conceded that societal culture also plays an important role in entrepreneurship.54 In fact, as Mueller and Thomas put it,

culture, as the underlying system of values peculiar to a specific group or society, shapes the development of certain personality traits and motivates individuals in a society to engage in behaviors that may not be as prevalent in other societies . . . [e]ntrepreneurial activity (i.e., new venture creation) may be one of these ­behaviors which varies across countries due to differences in ­cultural values and beliefs.55

Mueller and Thomas also noted that while there are many factors underlying entrepreneurial behavior that are common across all ­cultures, such as economic incentives that serve as motivators for entrepreneurship, differences in societal cultures influence other relevant factors by reinforcing certain characteristics related to entrepreneurship, and penalizing other characteristics, thus leading to variations among societies with respect to how closely they are aligned with an entrepreneurial orientation.56

Representative Studies of Influence of Societal Culture on Entrepreneurship

While there has been a relative dearth of research on the relationship between culture and entrepreneurship, particularly cross-border comparisons, studies have provided strong evidence that some cultures produce more innovation and entrepreneurship than others.57 R. Bouncken et al. provided a short summary of some of the research that has been done on cultural aspects of entrepreneurial intentions.58 They noted, for example, that dissimilarities of entrepreneurship across cultures had been identified by researchers such as Erez and Early59 and that other researchers had analyzed issues such as the impact of values and culture on entrepreneurial motivations and the generation and success of new ventures. In addition, they cited a number of studies that appeared to confirm that entrepreneurship and the associated new venture generation are influenced by culture. For example, McGrath et al. found that high scores of power distance, individualism, and masculinity, and low scores of uncertainty avoidance, appeared to increase entrepreneurship.60 However, they also noted that other researchers had found contrary indications with regard to some of the cultural dimensions and concluded that the direction of the influence of culture uncovered in the research community has often been somewhat unclear and conflicting.61

As noted above, McGrath et al. found that a high score on power distance appeared to increase entrepreneurship62; however, several other researchers have found that a high score on that cultural dimension actually decreased entrepreneurship.63 The hypothesis that low power distance is more conducive to entrepreneurship appears to be supported by other studies relating to some of the organizational characteristics associated with increased levels of innovativeness, often mentioned as a core element of entrepreneurship. For example, it is well accepted that innovation is more likely to occur in organic organizational structures, which feature lower power distance, than in higher power distance mechanistic structures.64 In addition, greater equality of prestige, rewards, and social power has been found to increase innovation.65 Finally, it has been observed that decentralization, which is associated with low power distance, promotes innovation because upper and lower level staff members are able to communicate more easily.66 On balance, it appears that cross-cultural research should identify differences between low and high power distance countries with respect to entrepreneurial motivations, with high power distance having a negative impact on such motivations.67

There are a number of indicators that individualism should be positively associated with entrepreneurial activities and, in fact, researchers have uncovered evidence that higher levels of individualism in an entrepreneur increase the chances of his or her success.68 McGrath et al. found that a high societal culture score on individualism appeared to increase entrepreneurship in that society.69 Individualistic societies tend to be nurturing environments for several of the individual personality traits thought to be positively associated with a bent toward entrepreneurship. For example, Shane found that autonomy and independence are more common in individualistic societies70 and studies have confirmed that these traits are found more frequently among entrepreneurs than nonentrepreneurs.71 In addition, Mueller and Thomas speculated, based on several research studies, that:

. . . [s]ince individualistic cultures are more supportive of individual action and more tolerant of independent action than are ­collectivist cultures, we would expect that an internal locus of control orientation would be less prevalent in collectivist cultures than in individualistic cultures.72

However, researchers have suggested that the traditional approach of a single dimension with individualism and collectivism at opposite ends of the pole should be modified to take into account that both individualism and collectivism are necessary for successful entrepreneurship73 and, in fact, studies have shown that collectivism increases motivation to form new ventures and also facilitates the team-based entrepreneurship that often eases the path to innovation.74

McGrath et al. found that low scores of uncertainty avoidance appeared to increase entrepreneurship.75 In turn, Dwyer et al. found that a person’s intent to engage in new venture creation will be negatively influenced by things such as uncertainty avoidance and the fear of overcoming new and unfamiliar barriers (e.g., technological bureaucracy).76 Mueller and Thomas speculated that

[s]ince low uncertainty avoidance cultures are more accepting of non-traditional behaviors, it follows that entrepreneurs in those contexts enjoy greater freedom and legitimacy than their counterparts in high uncertainty avoidance cultures where the “deviance” of entrepreneurs would be viewed with suspicion.77

Tuunanen et al. found that preferences for innovation among entrepreneurs were higher among entrepreneurs in the United States, a relatively low uncertainty avoidance country, than among entrepreneurs in Finland, a relatively high uncertainty avoidance country.78 Shane tested the “per capita rate of innovation” among 33 countries and concluded that the rate declined as uncertainty avoidance increased.79

Mueller and Thomas conducted a multicultural survey of third-and fourth-year university students in nine countries to analyze the relationship between two common cultural dimensions: individualism-­collectivism and uncertainty avoidance, and internal locus of control and innovativeness, two traits that are often associated with entrepreneurial potential.80 As they had expected, the results confirmed that “some cultures are more conductive for entrepreneurship than others.”81 Specifically, they found that an increased likelihood on internal locus of control orientation in individualistic cultures and also found that what they referred to as “entrepreneurial orientation,” defined as a combination of internal locus of control and innovativeness, was more likely to be found in individualistic, low uncertainty avoidance cultures than in collectivistic, high uncertainty avoidance cultures. Mueller and Thomas argued that their results provided support for the notion that creating a “supportive” societal culture may have positive benefits for increasing entrepreneurial potential and suggested that business training efforts include not only technical areas but also lessons that assist prospective entrepreneurs in realizing and cultivating psychological characteristics such as self-reliance, independent action, creativity, and flexible thinking. Mueller and Thomas conceded that other traits associated with entrepreneurial behavior and not included in their study could also have an important impact and that other contextual factors (e.g., other dimensions of societal culture, educational systems, political economy, and stage of economic development) should also be integrated into expanded investigations.

Bouncken et al. set out to “investigate the cultural antecedents of new venture generation” by focusing on several cultural dimensions, power distance, individualism, and collectivism, and searching for differences in cultural influences on entrepreneurship between Germany and Poland.82 They concluded that their hypothesis that influences on entrepreneurship across cultures was supported by Germany and Poland. For ­example, Bouncken et al. surveyed a sample of 450 MBA students in the two countries and found that among the German students, power distance, which is lower in Germany than in Poland, had a negative impact on entrepreneurial motivation while the same cultural dimension had a positive impact among the Poles. Bouncken et al. speculated that the results for the Germans, which were consistent with prior research on the relationship of power distance to entrepreneurship, was due to individuals in that country being more comfortable with being subordinates in organizations with less power distance across organizational levels. On the other hand, people in Poland, weary of hierarchical constraints created by long-standing political conditions, might have a strong desire to break these old ties and increase their social status and freedom through entrepreneurship. Bouncken et al. also found differences between Germany and Poland with respect to the influence of individualism and collectivism, which they believed were best treated as two separate dimensions rather than points on a continuum of a single dimension for purposes of entrepreneurship, on both motivation to form a new venture and actual intention to form a new venture.83 Finally, Bouncken et al. noted that although motivation to engage in entrepreneurship influenced intent to form a new venture in each country, the likelihood of new venture ­formation was influenced by noncultural factors such as the economic environment and that this led to a finding that the likelihood of new venture formation was higher in Germany than in Poland.

Hyrsky et al. compared entrepreneurial behavior between entrepreneurs and small business owners in the United States and Finland, with a specific focus on two personality traits generally associated with potential for entrepreneurship: “innovativeness” and “risk taking.”84 Their results showed that the respondents from the United States scored higher on both “risk taking” propensity and on innovation than their counterparts in Finland. Another interesting finding was that while U.S. founders of their own businesses scored higher on risk taking than those U.S. respondents who had purchased or inherited their businesses (referred to as “nonfounders” by Hyrsky et al.) the situation in Finland was reversed with nonfounders scoring higher on risk taking than Finns who founded their own businesses. The countries scored the same with respect to several other issues. For example, in the combined sample of United States and Finnish respondents the females had higher levels of innovation preference than the males but males scored significantly higher than females with respect to risk taking. In addition, in both the United States and Finland, the respondents who scored highest on innovativeness and risk taking were more likely to take the time to create formal, written plans for developing and growing their businesses. Finally, in both countries there was a correlation between innovativeness and risk taking on the one hand and an orientation toward pursuing profits and growth as opposed to simply earning family income.

Another study by Abbey focused on identifying differences between entrepreneurs in the United States, generally recognized as a highly individualistic societal culture, and the relatively collectivist society of ­Ghana.85 The survey results uncovered statistically significant differences were found between the entrepreneurs in the two countries on entrepreneurial motivations such as the desire for independence, need for economic security, social standing, and opportunity to contribute; however, no difference between entrepreneurs in the United States and Ghana were found on other entrepreneurial motivational factors such as the desire for recognition, innovativeness, and challenge. Abbey cited his results as confirmation that certain motivational factors may be common to entrepreneurs from different cultural backgrounds (i.e., “universal”) and that there are also differences between countries caused by differences in the cultural frame of reference of the entrepreneurs in those countries. Abbey observed that recognition of cultural differences is important for policymaking creating economic development policies for collectivist societies such as Ghana since those policies are not likely to be effective if they are based on a Western model that solely or heavily encourages individualist values such as individual initiative and need for individual achievement. Abbey urged policymakers to “focus on how to use the cultural orientation of the people to foster entrepreneurship.”86

Universality and Cultural Specificity of Entrepreneurial Cognitions

As noted above, there appears to be little opposition to the notion that societal culture plays an important role in entrepreneurial activity.87 However, as in other areas of leadership and management studies, “universality” has long been debated among scholars and researchers involved in international studies of entrepreneurship and there is inconclusive evidence on whether universal reasons exist for entrepreneurship. Mitchell et al., for example, suggested that some part of entrepreneurial thinking may be “universal” due, in part to the increasing similarity of the global environment for business and the need for entrepreneurs everywhere to confront and overcome many of the same challenges along the road to new venture creation.88 Other researchers, however, have cautioned that any “universal” values and norms attributed to entrepreneurs must be tempered by culture-specific values and norms that heavily influence behaviors in particular countries.89 Accordingly, while there seems to be a growing consensus that entrepreneurship is an important driving force for new infrastructure, technology, and job creation around the world,90 the development of a new global system based on entrepreneurship will be impacted by both cultural homogenization and cultural clashes.91

Researchers have conducted studies in multiple countries in an effort to identify reasons for new business formation and have found indications that entrepreneurs in many countries act out of needs for approval, personal wealth, personal development, independence, social status, and escape.92 A study conducted by McGrath et al. provided support for the idea that entrepreneurs share a common set of values despite differences in cultural background.93 Shane et al. identified the “desire for job freedom” as a universal reason for new business formation.94 A study of entrepreneurs in the United States and Ghana led Abbey to conclude that it was likely that “desire for independence” was a universal reason for new business formation.95 However, other results from the same study caused Abbey to conclude that there are also differences between countries caused by differences in the cultural frame of reference of the entrepreneurs in those countries. Shapero and Sokol also observed that entrepreneurial activity varies from society to society because of cultural beliefs about entrepreneurship.96

One interesting exploration of universality versus culture-specificity was grounded in entrepreneurial cognition research, which focuses on identifying and analyzing entrepreneur’s distinctive ways of thinking as a way of addressing issues related to the entrepreneurship phenomena.97 Entrepreneurial cognitions have been shown to be useful in explaining a number of aspects of entrepreneurial activity including, for example, differentiation between entrepreneurs and nonentrepreneurs,98 opportunity identification,99 success in the startup process,100 and making the venture-creation decision.101 Specifically, Mitchell et al. conducted a comprehensive study of 990 entrepreneurs and business managers in 11 countries, including the members of what was then known as the G7 (i.e., the United States, Canada, the United Kingdom, Germany, France, Italy, and Japan) and four Pacific Rim countries—Australia, Chile, Mexico, and China.102 The researchers explained that they had identified two cognitive scripts of entrepreneurs, which were generally referred to as “entry” and “doing.”103 The “entry” phase required attention to making “arrangements” for embarking on the entrepreneurial activities. Once those arrangements have been completed, the entrepreneur then moves to the “doing” phase, which requires that the entrepreneur have the “willingness” and the “ability” to take the actions necessary to achieve the goal of successfully engaging in the entrepreneurial activities. Mitchell et al. briefly described the three conditions, mindsets, and skills that must be present in order for entrepreneurship to be successful as follows:

  • Arrangements: Arrangements include seeking and finding a supportive environment in relation to an opportunity and organizing the resources available from that environment (e.g., capital, social networks (i.e., contacts and relationships), plant and equipment, labor, etc.) that would allow the entrepreneur to capitalize on the opportunity.104
  • Willingness: Willingness includes a commitment to venturing and receptivity to the idea of starting a new venture,105 readiness to commit,106 motivation to seek an opportunity,107 and eagerness to act versus missing an opportunity.108
  • Ability: Ability refers to the knowledge structures or scripts109 that individuals have to support the capabilities, skills, knowledge, norms, and attitudes required to create a venture110 and recognize, capture, and protect an opportunity.111

Mitchell et al. assumed that a high amount of cognitions were a threshold condition for entrepreneurship and then went on to suggest the following four entrepreneurial archetypes based on the levels of the other two cognitive categories—willingness and ability:

  • Dangerous: This archetype included individuals who had high levels of arrangement and willingness but low levels of ability, which ultimately created a high risk that the new venture would fail.
  • Professionals: This archetype included individuals with high levels of arrangements, willingness, and ability cognitions, which made them to be more likely than any of the other archetypes to be successful in their new venture activities due to their higher relative levels of expertise and experience.
  • Arrangers: This archetype included individuals with low levels of both of the “doing” cognitions—willingness and ability—which meant that while they are likely to possess a protectable niche they would not be actively seeking other opportunities.
  • Conservatives: This archetype included individuals have relatively higher levels of arrangements and ability cognitions, but lower willingness cognitions. Individuals in this category tended to be extremely careful about pursuing opportunities even though they had access to the necessary resources and the skills that are necessary to form a new venture to exploit an opportunity.

Using the framework discussed above, Mitchell et al. used their survey group to test several hypotheses. They found, for example, that it was universally true (i.e., true across all the countries in the survey) that “entry” and “doing” differed between “professional” entrepreneurs and nonentrepreneurs. There was only mixed support for differences between the other entrepreneurial archetypes and nonentrepreneurs. In addition, they found that entrepreneurs could be differentiated into archetypes described in all of the countries in the survey, which they argued was evidence that entrepreneurs share a number of common cognitive constructs—an “entrepreneurial way of thinking”—regardless of the country in which they are operating.112 However, evidence of cultural influence on entrepreneurial cognitions was also found in the form of country-based differences in the script content of the arrangements, willingness, and ability cognitions of entrepreneurs and differences among countries with respect to the proportion of individuals populating a given entrepreneurial archetype. For example, entrepreneurs in the United States were observed to have higher seeking focus and commitment tolerance cognitions than entrepreneurs in Mexico, the United Kingdom, Germany, or France, and greater resource access cognitions than entrepreneurs in Mexico, Italy, Germany, and France. However, there were also some similarities such as situational knowledge, venture diagnostic ability, and opportunity recognition, which indicates an important similarity in entrepreneurial cognitions.

The general conclusion seems to be that the search for universality is of limited utility and attempts to develop universal theories of business formation should be abandoned in favor of focusing on more robust models that acknowledge and accept culture-based differences among entrepreneurs, their organizations, and the processes they follow to create new businesses.113 If this is true, researchers have a wide array of questions that need to be addressed including identifying and measuring just how cultural values influence entrepreneurial activity and the institutions that support entrepreneurship, a topic discussed in more detail below. Another challenge is isolating and understanding the influence of cultural factors in the face of evidence that the level of entrepreneurship is also significantly related to other factors such as economic development and growth, the quality of the legal and regulatory environment, access to financing and other resources, and the prevalence of informality.114

Institutional Environment and Entrepreneurship

Several scholars have argued that the rate of new venture formation and growth is directly influenced by the institutional environment, both formal and informal, in which the venture is operating.115 New ventures, being both new and small, must struggle to gain legitimacy and survive in their external environment and one way to do that is to conform to the norms and practices that have been prescribed and sanctioned by the institutional environment. In many ways, the institutional environment limits the range of strategic options that are available to new ventures in a society116 and thus plays an important role in both the creation and destruction of entrepreneurial activities in that society.117 It is, therefore, not surprising that one area of comparative research with respect to international entrepreneurship is comparing the institutional environment of different societies for to their favorability for entrepreneurship. The need for this type of research is particularly compelling for emerging economies as they struggle to identify and implement policies that can promote economic development including policies to encourage entrepreneurs to form new ventures that hopefully create new jobs and contribute to an increase in overall economic welfare.118 In fact, several researchers have asserted that the rate and trajectory of entrepreneurial activities in emerging countries is significantly influenced by the institutional environment in those countries.119

While North defined the “institutional framework” of a society as “the fundamental political, social, and legal ground rules, which establish the basis for production and distribution,”120 Scott laid the foundation for meaningful comparison by suggesting that the formal and informal institutions that influence business can be categorized as follows: regulatory institutions, which include the formal system of laws and regulations that have been adopted and enforced in a given community, society, or country; normative institutions, which include the commercial standards and conventions that have been established and recognized through professional and trade associations in a given community, society, or country; and cognitive institutions, which encompass the culture-specific beliefs regarding socially appropriate behavior, which are acquired by persons as they undergo the socialization process in the community, society, or country.121 These categories served as the basis for the creation of a survey instrument by Busenitz et al., which has often been used as a means for measuring a country’s institutional profile.122 The survey items for the various categories, sometimes referred to as “dimensions,” included the following:

  • Regulatory: The level of government assistance and special support to individuals looking to start their own business; the degree to which the government sets aside contracts for new and small businesses; the level of government sponsorship of organizations that assist in the development of new businesses; and the degree to which the government assists entrepreneurs who have failed in earlier business to start new businesses.
  • Cognitive: The knowledge and skills possess by people in the country pertaining to establishing and operating a new business as indicated by the degree to which individuals know how to legally protect a new business; the degree to which entrepreneurs know how to cope with high levels of risk and manage those risks; and the availability of information ­regarding markets for products and services to be offered by new businesses.
  • Normative: The degree to which entrepreneurship is an admired career path within the society; the degree to which innovative and creative thinking is valued and viewed as a route to success within the society; and the degree to which entrepreneurs are admired in the society.123

Eunni used the survey instrument to study and compare the institutional environment for entrepreneurship in two emerging economies: Mexico and Brazil.124 Eunni first concluded that the Busenitz et al. survey methodology, which was originally designed for industrialized economies, would also be valid for emerging economies in Latin America. Eunni went on to observe that the results of the surveys in the two countries included evidence of significant differences between them with respect to both the regulatory and cognitive dimensions, with Mexico performing much better on both of those dimensions than Brazil. When discussing the regulatory dimension, Eunni noted the importance of measuring the time and difficulty associated with starting a business, employing workers, and registering property. With regard to the cognitive dimension, relevant factors might include religious beliefs and the influence of parents and other family members. Mexico also scored higher than Brazil with respect to its overall institutional profile; however, it was quite telling to see that while there were differences between the two countries neither of them were especially favorable to new venture creation.125 Eunni recommended that the number of countries included in the test to be sampled be increased in future and validate the survey instrument and cautioned that, of course, institutional environments can be expected to evolve as time goes by and that it is therefore necessary to conduct follow-up surveys as policy initiatives are implemented.

The Global Entrepreneurship Monitor (GEM) is a partnership between the London Business School and Babson College that administers a comprehensive research program to produce annual assessments of national levels of entrepreneurial activity. The project was first launched in 1999, when it covered just 10 countries, and has since grown to cover as many as 85 countries in subsequent years and is recognized as the largest ongoing study of entrepreneurial dynamics in the world. The main objectives of the GEM program are measurement of differences in the level of entrepreneurial activity between countries, uncovering the ­factors that lead to appropriate levels of entrepreneurship and making ­suggestions for policies that may lead to enhancement of national levels of entrepreneurial activity.126

The GEM is based on a conceptual model of the institutional environment and its effect on entrepreneurship. The model recognizes the importance of the social, cultural, and political context in which entrepreneurial activities occur and assumes that these contextual factors influence three sets of conditions: basic requirements, which include institutions, infrastructure, macroeconomic stability, health, and primary education; “efficiency enhancers,” which include higher education, goods and labor market efficiency, financial market sophistication, technological readiness, and market size; and the following entrepreneurial framework conditions (EFCs), which represent elements of the institutional environment for entrepreneurship in a particular country:

  • Finance: The availability of financial resources—equity and debt—for small and medium enterprises (SMEs) (including grants and subsidies);
  • Government policies: The extent to which taxes or regulations are either size-neutral or encourage SMEs;
  • Government programs: The presence and quality of direct ­programs to assist new and growing firms at all levels of ­government (national, regional, municipal);
  • Entrepreneurial education and training: The extent to which training in creating or managing SMEs is incorporated within the education and training system at all levels (primary, ­secondary, and postschool);
  • R&D transfer: The extent to which national research and development will lead to new commercial opportunities and is available to SMEs;
  • Commercial and professional infrastructure: The presence of property rights and commercial, accounting, and other legal services and institutions that support or promote SMEs;
  • Entry regulation: Contains two components including “market dynamics,” which is the level of change in markets from year to year, and “market openness,” which is the extent to which new firms are free to enter existing markets;
  • Physical infrastructure and services: Ease of access to ­physical resources—communication, utilities, transportation, land, or space—at a price that does not discriminate against SMEs; and
  • Cultural and social norms: The extent to which social and cultural norms encourage or allow actions leading to new business methods or activities that can potentially increase personal wealth and income.

The study of the relationship of the institutional environment, regardless of how it is defined and measured, and entrepreneurship is part of the larger field of new institutional economics (NIE), which was pioneered by scholars, such as Coase, North, and Williamson,127 who were interested in making sure that there was a recognition that “institutions matter” and that the structure and performance of institutions has a substantial influence on economic behavior. Work in NIE has included property rights analysis, transaction cost economics, public choice theory, and comparative economic systems.128 While there appears to be growing acceptance that institutions must be considered when developing and testing economic theories, particularly with respect to growth and development, the processes remain fairly new129 and it has been observed that “the causality of the various links and channels of influence between the institutional set-up and development outcome is still not well or fully understood.”130 It has also been acknowledged that the effectiveness of formal institutions and institutional change depends on other factors. For example, Milo noted that “[f]ormal rules must be securely nested in hospitable informal norms for them to function well, since it is the latter that legitimizes the former.”131 In addition, several scholars have cautioned that economic institutions must have the support of the appropriate political institutions in order to be effective.132 In fact, enlightened political leadership can make even ineffective economic institutions workable and Milo advised that “[t]here are times when it is preferable to work within the context of imperfect existing institutions, rather than use up political ­capital on long-term institutional reforms.”133

While much time, effort, and capital has been invested in institutional reform in both developed and developing countries, the results have not always been what had been expected.134 It seems clear that creating institutions is not sufficient and that growth and economic development only follows when the institutions are “efficient” and “encourage individuals to engage in productive activities by providing appropriate incentives and establish a stable structure of human interactions, which reduce uncertainty.” Scholars have identified and defined two types of “efficiency” with respect to institutions. The first is “substantive efficiency,” which includes rules that promote allocative efficiency, and the second is “procedural efficiency,” which include rules designed to either reduce the cost or increase the accuracy of participating in and using the system of rules that form the institutions.135 Milo has suggested that to achieve the institutional efficiency necessary for achieving development countries must have institutions “that promote exchange by lowering transaction costs and promoting trust . . . and [institutions] that induce the state to protect rather than expropriate private property.”136 Institutions that are likely to have the desired effect of improving the efficiency and integrity of economic transactions include “contracts and contract enforcement mechanisms, commercial norms and rules, and habits and beliefs favoring shared values and the accumulation of human capital” and institutions that can be expected to contribute to the creation and protection of private property rights include “[c]onstitutions, electoral rules, laws governing speech and education, and legal and civic norms.”137

Innovation Clusters and Entrepreneurial Ecosystems

Many believe that the first serious reference to geographic concentrations of interconnected companies—clusters—appeared in the work of the Cambridge economist Alfred Marshall, who described “industrial districts” that arose from an observed tendency of specialized companies to cluster together to form geographic concentrations of expertise and economic activity.138 Marshall viewed these tendencies positively and, in fact, wrote in 1890 about how “…great are the advantages which people following the same skilled trade get from near neighboring to one another…”139 Other economists built on Marshall’s initial theory by suggesting and adding other “necessary elements” for the creation and maintenance of “innovation clusters” including the importance of a “self-interested economic agents” or “entrepreneurs” willing to take on and attempt to overcome the risks associated with unproven technologies to seek substantial profits. According to Schumpeter, these entrepreneurs drove the process of transferring and transforming emergent technologies into new products, services, and product models and creating new methods for organizing economic activities to establish new industries and markets.140 Romer suggested that technological progress is driven by researchers searching for new ideas for innovations, which can eventually provide them with monopoly profits.141

A century after Marshall’s work Porter undertook an extension examination and analysis of business clusters and uncovered evidence of a strong positive relationship between the proximity of specialized companies and extraordinary competitive success.142 Dearlove provided the following description of how Porter painted the boundaries of clusters:

Professor Porter suggests that clusters encompass an array of linked industries and other entities important to competition, including suppliers of specialized inputs and providers of specialized infrastructure. Clusters also extend downstream to channels and customers and laterally to manufacturers of complementary products, and to companies in industries with common skills, technologies, or inputs. Clusters often include governmental and other institutions, such as universities, standard-setting agencies, and think tanks, as well as providers of specialized training, education, information, research, and technical support.143

Porter famously observed that the importance of clustering contrasts dramatically with the idea that the emerging global economy is breaking down barriers and making location less important as a condition for becoming a “global player” and referred to what he called the “paradox of location”: “Paradoxically, the enduring competitive advantages in a global economy lie increasingly in local things—knowledge, relationships, and motivation that distant rivals cannot match.”144

In recent years it has become increasingly popular to refer to innovation clusters as “entrepreneurial ecosystems,” a concept that Mason and Brown discussed in 2013 as part of the broader question of what types of policy initiatives should be taken to promote the creation and maturation of high-growth firms (HGFs).145 Mason and Brown cited the works of several researchers that supported the premise that HGFs have a significant impact on economic development. For example, the OECD and Brown et al. have reported that HGFs drive productivity growth, create new employment, increase innovation, and promote business internationalization.146 Henrekson and Johansson, after conducting a meta-analysis of prior empirical studies, concluded that “a few rapidly growing firms generate a disproportionately large share of all net new jobs compared with non-high growth firms. This is a clear-cut result… [T]his is particularly pronounced in recessions when Gazelles continue to grow.”147 Others have suggested that HGFs have important spill-over effects that are beneficial to the growth of other firms in the same locality and industrial cluster.148

Mason and Brown noted that the recognition of the disproportionate value of HGFs to economic development has led policymakers to consider adopting support programs for high-growth entrepreneurship that are more “systems-based” and which rely mainly on “relational” forms of support including building connections and networks among entrepreneurs, prioritizing development of “blockbuster entrepreneurs” with significant economic potential and institutional alignment of priorities. A number of researchers have referred to the overall framework for providing this type of support as an “entrepreneurial ecosystem,”149 which Mason and Brown defined, based on their own synthesis of definitions throughout the relevant literature, as

a set of interconnected entrepreneurial actors (both potential and existing), entrepreneurial organisations (e.g., firms, ­venture capitalists, business angels, banks), institutions (universities, public sector agencies, financial bodies) and entrepreneurial processes (e.g., the business birth rate, numbers of high growth firms, ­levels of “blockbuster entrepreneurship,” number of serial ­entrepreneurs, degree of sell-out mentality within firms and ­levels of entrepreneurial ambition) which formally and informally coalesce to connect, mediate and govern the performance within the local entrepreneurial environment.150

While Mason and Brown added that entrepreneurial ecosystems were geographically bounded, they noted that cities did not have to be a particular size to qualify and pointed to Austin, Texas, and Boulder, Colorado in the United States and Cambridge in England as examples of smaller cities that had been successful at developing what they referred to as “thriving entrepreneurial ecosystems.” Mason and Brown also explained that a system could emerge around one industry or evolve and expand to cover several industries.151

For researchers like Isenberg, an entrepreneurial ecosystem is a ­“strategy for economic development” that depends on several key factors or domains: a conducive culture, enabling policies and leadership, availability of appropriate finance, quality human capital, venture friendly ­markets for products, and a range of institutional supports.152 For their part, Mason and Brown argued that the distinguishing features of entrepreneurial ecosystems include

a core of large established businesses, including some that have been entrepreneur-led (entrepreneurial blockbusters); entrepreneurial recycling—whereby successful cashed out entrepreneurs reinvest their time, money, and expertise in supporting new entrepreneurial activity; and an information-rich environment in which this information is both accessible and shared.153

Mason and Brown also believed that in order for entrepreneurial ecosystems to thrive there must be a group of “dealmakers” who are involved in a fiduciary capacity in several entrepreneurial ventures, ready availability of startup and growth capital, and a supportive community of large firms, universities, and service providers.154 Others have suggested that an effective entrepreneurial ecosystem needs accessible domestic ­markets, including access to small and large companies and governments as ­customers; human capital, including managerial and technical talent and experience in launching and building knowledge-intensive firms; funding and finance; support systems, including mentors/advisors, professional services, incubators/accelerators and a network of entrepreneurial peers; regulatory framework and infrastructure; education and training; major universities as catalysts; and cultural support.155

On a practical level, entrepreneurial ecosystems should be able to provide entrepreneurs with the resources and tools they need to launch their emerging companies, including networks that can be used to tap into the human resources necessary to build a founding team and recruit knowledge workers who can create and develop new products and services; professional investors (e.g., venture capitalists) and/or corporate partners with the capital necessary to support the product development activities of the founders and the expansion of the company to the point required for effective promotion and distribution of the product or service; professional and business advisors, including attorneys, accountants, bankers, insurance brokers, and consultants; regulatory framework that facilitates creation of business entities and establishment of governance systems and allows entrepreneurs to create and protect an intellectual property rights portfolio; and strategic partners that can collaborate with the new firm as suppliers, customers, manufacturers, distributors, and research and development partners.156

As for the specific steps that should be taken to launch and stimulate entrepreneurial ecosystems, Mason and Brown argued that policymakers would need to focus on several dimensions including direct support of entrepreneurial actors through accelerators and incubators; development of entrepreneurial organizations and resource providers such as business angels, venture capital, banks, service providers, universities; creation of connectors within the ecosystem through public–private partnerships and alliances and peer-to-peer learning; and development and nurturing of an entrepreneurial environment or culture within the ecosystem through entrepreneurship education, role models, peer-to-peer networking, and entrepreneurial recycling.157 Mason and Brown noted while there was a role for governments to play in developing entrepreneurial ecosystems, they should limit their involvement to facilitation and leave the details to the private sector, experienced local entrepreneurs, and/or leading local companies. Key to success would be the ability to create a local culture that was favorable to startup activity and which promoted and accepted entrepreneurial risk-taking. Experienced entrepreneurs could do their part by training, coaching, and mentoring their prospective peers and local companies could contribute by allowing and encouraging spinoff of promising ideas into new firms. In many cases it will be necessary to provide training to both local entrepreneurs and investors on the financing process until such time as the ecosystem has a community of experienced angel and venture capital investors.

Institutional Environment and Entrepreneurship in Developing Countries

There has been growing interest among researchers focusing on economic and social development in developing countries to understand the relationship between the institutional framework that exists in a ­country and the level and type of entrepreneurship practiced in that country. For example, when discussing the important and fundamental role that institutions play with respect to economic development, Acemoglu began by referring to the evidence from economic analysis that has confirmed that differences between countries with respect to prosperity and per capita income are strongly related to differences in the traditional factors of production: human capital, physical capital, and technology.158 He went on to argue that these findings raised a fundamental question for researchers: why is it that some countries have less human capital, physical capital, and technology than other countries and/or make worse use of these factors than other countries (i.e., failure to identify and/or exploit entrepreneurial opportunities effectively)? Certainly some of the differences can be attributed to geographical differences or cultural factors; however, Acemoglu observed that “[i]nstitutions have emerged as a potential fundamental cause.”159 In the same vein, Chu argued that countries that have achieved relative affluence in relation to others have done so in large part because they were able to establish and maintain “efficient” institutions while countries that have remained undeveloped have suffered from the lack of efficient institutions.160 Milo described and analyzed several ­different institutional indicators and concluded that there was a positive relationship between economic performance and institutional quality among member countries of the ASEAN and noted, in particular, that the strong relative economic performance of countries such as Malaysia, Singapore, and Thailand was consistent with their high scores on ­measures of institutional quality.161

Other scholars, while often using different definitions of “institutions,” have reached similar conclusions: “institutions explain economically and statistically significant differences in per capita incomes across countries.”162 Olson tackled the question of why there continued to be widely differing standards of living around the world if, in fact, markets everywhere were working efficiently.163 He first investigated whether the variations among countries might be attributable to different resource endowments (i.e., poorer countries have problems with economic growth and social development because “they lack land and natural resources, physical and human capital, or access to the latest technology”164). He systematically dismissed this proposition noting, for example, that there was evidence showing that knowledge was and is equally available to all countries at a reasonable cost, population density does not explain economic performance, capital flows are driven by the quality of institutions, and there was no basis for assuming that citizens of richer countries were innately “smarter” than citizens of poorer countries. Olson thus ­concluded that

the large differences in per capita income across countries ­cannot be explained by differences in access to the world’s stock of ­productive knowledge or to its capital markets, by differences in the quality of marketable human capital or personal culture.165

Assuming this to be true, “[t]he only plausible explanation left is that differing performances are caused by differences in the quality of countries’ institutions and policies.”166 Olson predicted that poorer countries that elect to adopt better economic policies and institutions would enjoy higher rates of growth in per capita incomes in relation to richer countries because they were so far short of their potential prior to the adoption of the new policies and there was such a huge gap to close between actual and potential income in those countries.167

Holcombe took a different approach by arguing that differences in the economic performance of countries could be explained by the “entrepreneurial opportunities” that are available in those countries and that decentralized free economies are the ones that do the best job of generating more opportunities that can be seized for their profitability and which also continuously generate new opportunities that ultimately will create an “endogenous engine of economic growth.”168 He placed so much importance on the availability of entrepreneurial opportunities that he argued that often-used techniques for launching economic development such as encouraging investment in industrial activities and research and development, calling for increased savings, and funding education would not, in and of themselves, be successful unless and until fundamental market reforms, including the creation and support of appropriate institutions, were made to facilitate creation of entrepreneurial opportunities. As an example, Holcombe pointed out that when developing countries have educated their citizens they often migrate to other countries due to lack of entrepreneurial opportunities in their homelands and pointed out that this sort of “brain drain” will continue until governments in those countries create and support institutions that are conductive to entrepreneurship.169

It should be noted that there are some who have questioned the relationship between institutional development and entrepreneurship in developing countries. Lingelbach et al., whose studies of “what makes entrepreneurs in developing countries different” are described elsewhere in this chapter, argued that the data collected from studies of new- and growth-oriented firms in developing countries suggested

several important, but counterintuitive findings: freer, more competitive, poor countries are not correlated in a statistically significant way with higher levels of opportunity entrepreneurs; recent economic growth in a poor country is not correlated in a statistically significant way with higher levels of opportunity entrepreneurship; and protection of property rights and levels of corruption don’t seem to matter either.170

In spite of these assessments of the data, the general consensus appears to be that institutions do matter; however, as they await institutional improvements small but growing numbers of entrepreneurs in developing countries are developing and implementing strategies to create ­successful businesses in spite of higher risks and uncertainties, difficulties in ­accessing financial and human capital, and the absence of mentors and role models.

Setting the appropriate policies for promoting entrepreneurship in developing countries is not an easy task and policymakers have often failed mightily in their efforts and seen huge amounts of resources ­effectively wasted. Accepting the importance of institutions, notice should be taken of the advice of Milo, who suggested that to achieve the institutional efficiency necessary for achieving development countries must have institutions “that promote exchange by lowering transaction costs and ­promoting trust . . . and [institutions] that induce the state to protect rather than expropriate private property.”171 Institutions that are likely to have the desired effect of improving the efficiency and ­integrity of ­economic transactions include “contracts and contract enforcement mechanisms, commercial norms and rules, and habits and beliefs ­favoring shared values and the accumulation of human capital” and institutions that can be expected to contribute to the creation and protection of ­private property rights include “[c]onstitutions, electoral rules, laws ­governing speech and education, and legal and civic norms.”172


1 Shane, S., E. Locke, and C. Collins. 2003. “Entrepreneurial Motivation.” Human Resource Management Review 13, no.2, pp. 257–79, 274–76.

2 Id. at p. 258 (“In our arguments, we explicitly assume that all human action is the result of both motivational and cognitive factors, the latter including ability, intelligence and skills. We also assume that entrepreneurship is not solely the result of human action; external factors also play a role . . .”)

3 This view was consistent with the observations of others such as Aldrich and Zimmer, who wrote that entrepreneurial activity “can be conceptualized as a function of opportunity structures and motivated entrepreneurs with access to resources.” See Aldrich, H., and C. Zimmer. 1986. “Entrepreneurship through Social Networks.” In The Art and Science of Entrepreneurship, eds. D. Sexton and R. Smilor, 3–23, 3. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger.

4 Shane, S., E. Locke, and C. Collins. 2003. “Entrepreneurial Motivation.” Human Resource Management Review 13, pp. 257–79, 276. (“Motivations might be more or less stronger than these other factors in the degree that they influence particular transitions points. In addition, there might be important and interesting interaction effects between motivations and opportunities, [knowledge, skills and abilities] and environmental factors.”)

5 Baum, J., E. Locke, and K. Smith. 2001. “A Multi-Dimensional Model of ­Venture Growth.” Academy of Management Journal 44, no. 2, pp. 292–303.

6 Shane, S., E. Locke, and C. Collins. 2003. “Entrepreneurial Motivation.” Human Resource Management Review 13, pp. 257–79, 273.

7 Kantis, H. 2005. “A Systematic Approach to Enterprise Creation.” In Developing Entrepreneurship: Experience in Latin America and Worldwide, ed. H. Kantis, 17–27. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank.

8 Id. at pp. 19–21.

9 The summary description of each of the categories is based on Kantis, H. 2005. “A Systematic Approach to Enterprise Creation.” In Developing Entrepreneurship: Experience in Latin America and Worldwide, ed. H. Kantis, 17–27, 20–22. ­Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank.

10 Shane, S., E. Locke, and C. Collins. 2003. “Entrepreneurial Motivation.” Human Resource Management Review 13, pp. 257–79, 274.

11 Id. at p. 275.

12 Baum, J., E. Locke, and K. Smith. 2001. “A Multi-dimensional Model of ­Venture Growth.” Academy of Management Journal 44, no. 2, pp. 292–303.

13 Hollenbeck, J., and E. Whitener. 1988. “Reclaiming Personality Traits for Personnel Selection.” Journal of Management 14, no. 1, pp. 81–91; and ­McClelland, D. 1965. “N-Achievement and Entrepreneurship: A Longitudinal Study.” ­Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 1, no. 4, pp. 389–92.

14 MacMillan, I., R. Siegel, and P. SubbaNarisimha. 1985. “Criteria Used by Venture Capitalists to Evaluate New Venture Proposals.” Journal of Business ­Venturing 1, no. 1, pp. 119–28.

15 Begley, T., and D. Boyd. 1987. “Psychological Characteristics Associated with Performance in Entrepreneurial Firms and Smaller Businesses.” Journal of ­Business Venturing 2, no. 1, pp. 79–93; Low, M., and I. MacMillan. 1988. “Entrepreneurship: Past Research and Future Challenges.” Journal of Management 14, no. 2, pp. 139–61; Sandberg, W., and C. Hofer. 1987. “Improving New Venture ­Performance: The Role of Strategy, Industry Structure and the Entrepreneur.” Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 16, no. 1, pp. 73–90.

16 Baum, J., E. Locke, and K. Smith. 2001. “A Multi-Dimensional Model of Venture Growth.” Academy of Management Journal 44, no. 2, pp. 292–303, 292.

17 Id. at pp. 299–300.

18 Id. at p. 293.

19 Low, M., and I. MacMillan. 1988. “Entrepreneurship: Past Research and Future Challenges.” Journal of Management 14, no. 2, pp. 139–61; and Bird, B. 1989. Entrepreneurial Behavior. Glenview, IL: Scott, Foresman. Also, one of the core elements of motivation in charismatic leadership theory is “vision.” See Bass, B. 1990. Handbook of Leadership. New York, NY: Free Press.

20 Baum, J., E. Locke, and K. Smith. 2001. “A Multi-Dimensional Model of Venture Growth.” Academy of Management Journal 44, no. 2, pp. 292–303, 293, 297, 301 (citing Bandura, A. 1997. Self-efficacy: The Exercise of Control. New York, NY: W.H. Freeman.); and Locke, E., and G. Latham. 1990. A Theory of Goal Setting and Task Performance. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.

21 Id. at pp. 294–299 (confirming hypothesis that “[t]he greater the tenacity, proactivity, and passion for work of a venture’s CEO, the greater his or her situationally specific motivation with respect to vision, goals, and self-efficacy”).

22 Id. at p. 301 (citing Hambrick, D., and P. Mason. 1984. “Upper Echelons: The Organization as a Reflection of Its Top Managers.” Academy of Management Review 9, no. 2, pp. 193–206).

23 Id. at p. 275.

24 Locke referred to “vision” as the “capacity of the human mind to discover, through creative thought, solutions that had not existed before” and noted that vision often stepped in when traditional financial methods of assessing and mapping an opportunity would not be helpful (e.g., when Jobs first developed the mass market for personal computers or Walton planted the seeds for discount retailing). Id. at p. 263 (citing Locke, E. 2000. The Prime Movers: Traits of the Great Wealth Creators. New York, NY: AMACOM).

25 Id. at p. 275 (citing Bates, T. 1990. “Entrepreneur Human Capital Inputs and Small Business Longevity.” Review of Economics and Statistics 72, no. 4, pp. 551–59; and Schoonhoven, C., K. Eisenhardt, and K. Lyman. 1990. “Speeding Products to Market: Waiting Time to First Product Introduction in New Firms.” Administrative Science Quarterly 35, pp. 177–207).

26 Id. at p. 293.

27 Id. (citing Bird, B. 1989. Entrepreneurial Behavior. Glenview, IL: Scott, Foresman); Boyatzis, R. 1982. The Competent Manager. New York, NY: Wiley; ­Chandler, G., and E. Jansen. 1992. “The Founder’s Self-Assessed Competence and Venture Performance.” Journal of Business Venturing 7, pp. 223–36; and ­Herron, L., and R. Robinson. 1990. “Entrepreneurship Skills: An Empirical Study of the Missing Link Connecting the Entrepreneur with Venture Performance.” Paper Presented at the annual meeting of the Academy of Management, San Francisco.

28 Id. at pp. 299–301.

29 Id. at pp. 300–301.

30 Nassif, V., A. Ghobril, and N.S.D. Silva. April/June 2010. “Understanding the Entrepreneurial Process: A Dynamic Approach.” Brazilian Administrative Review 7, no. 2, pp. 213–26.

31 Shane, S., E. Locke, and C. Collins. 2003. “Entrepreneurial Motivation.” Human Resource Management Review 13, no. 2, pp. 257–79, 269.

32 Id. at pp. 260–61 (citing Shane, S., and S. Venkataraman. 2000. “The Promise of Entrepreneurship as a Field of Research.” Academy of Management Review 25, no. 1, pp. 217–26, 220).

33 Established industries may also be reenergized and transformed by entrepreneurs testing new business models, such as Sam Walton’s disruptive activities in the retail sector and the new organizing models in that same sector deployed by a wide array of “e-tailors.” Id. pp. 261–62.

34 Id. (citing Venkataraman, S. 1997. “The Distinctive Domain of Entrepreneurship Research: An Editor’s Perspective.” In Advances in Entrepreneurship, Firm Emergence and Growth, eds. J. Katz and R. Brockhaus, 119–38. vols. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press).

35 Shane et al. observed that variations in the opportunities that various entrepreneurs might pursue were not being taken into account by researchers studying the effects of motivation on entrepreneurial decisions. They suggested, among other things, that “researchers could explore settings in which potential ­entrepreneurs pursue reasonably identical opportunities,” such as comparing the motivations of persons interested in purchasing a McDonald’s franchise against those of ­persons preferring to tapped to manage a company-owned McDonald’s outlet. Id. at p. 270.

36 Shane, S., 2001. “Technology Opportunities and New Firm Creation.” ­Management Science 47, no. 2, pp. 205–20. For further discussion of the ­“characteristics of entrepreneurial opportunities,” see Christiansen, C. 1997. The Innovator’s Dilemma. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business School Press.

37 Shane, S., E. Locke, and C. Collins. 2003. “Entrepreneurial Motivation.” Human Resource Management Review 13, pp. 257–79, 261–62.

38 Id. at pp. 260, 275–76. Other environmental factors mentioned by Shane et al. included the age of the industry, the condition of capital markets, and the overall health of the economy. See also, for example, Aldrich, H., and G. Wiedenmayer. 1993. “From Traits to Rates: An Ecological Perspective on Organizational Foundings.” In Advances in Entrepreneurship, Firm Emergence, and Growth, eds. J. Katz and R. Brockhaus, Sr. 1 vols. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press, 145–95; and Aldrich, H. 2000. Organizations Evolving. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage.

39 Id.

40 Id. at pp. 293–94 (citing Dess, G., and P. Davis. 1984. “Porter’s (1980) Generic Strategies as Determinants of Strategic Group Membership and Organizational Performance.” Academy of Management Journal 27, no. 3, pp. 467–88; and Aldrich, H., and G. Wiedenmayer. 1993. “From Traits to Rates: An Ecological Perspective on Organizational Foundings.” In Advances in Entrepreneurship, Firm Emergence, and Growth, eds. J. Katz and R. Brockhaus, Sr. 1 vols. 145–95. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.

41 Id. at p. 301.

42 Id. at p. 299.

43 Id. at p. 301 (citing Hannan, M., and J. Freeman. 1977. “The Population Ecology of Organizations.” American Journal of Sociology 82, no. 5, pp. 929–64; and Pfeffer, J., and G. Salancik. 1978. The External Control of Organizations. New York, NY: Harper & Row).

44 Id. at p. 272.

45 Id. at p. 293 (citing Porter, M. 1980. Competitive Strategy. New York, NY: Free Press); and Dess, G., and P. Davis. 1984. “Porter’s (1980) Generic Strategies as Determinants of Strategic Group Membership and Organizational Performance.” Academy of Management Journal 27, no. 3, pp. 467–88.

46 Id. at p. 293 (citing Porter, M. 1980. Competitive Strategy, 42. New York, NY: Free Press.)

47 Id. at pp. 297, 301.

48 Id. at p. 301.

49 Id. (citing Bandura, A. 1997. Self-efficacy: The Exercise of Control. New York, NY: W.H. Freeman.); and Locke, E., and G. Latham. 1990. A Theory of Goal ­Setting and Task Performance. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.

50 Amit, R., E. Meuller, and I. Cockburn. 1995. “Opportunity Costs and Entrepreneurial Activity.” Journal of Business Venturing 10, no. 2, pp. 95–106.

51 Evans, D., and L. Leighton. 1989. “Some Empirical Aspects of Entrepreneurship.” American Economic Review 79, pp. 519–35.

52 Aldrich, H., and C. Zimmer. 1986. “Entrepreneurship through Social ­Networks.” In The Art and Science of Entrepreneurship, eds. D. Sexton and R. ­Smilor, 3–23. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger.

53 Cooper, A., C. Woo, and W. Dunkleberg. 1989. “Entrepreneurship and the Initial Size of Firms.” Journal of Business Venturing 4, no. 5, pp. 97–108.

54 See, for example, Holt, D. 1997. “A Comparative Study of Values among Chinese and USA Entrepreneurs: Pragmatic Convergence between Contrasting Cultures.” Journal of Business Venturing 12, no. 6, pp. 483–505; McGrath, R., I. MacMillan, and S. Scheinberg. 1992. “Elitists, Risk-takers, and ­Rugged ­Individualists—An Exploratory Analysis of Cultural-Differences between Entrepreneurs and Non-Entrepreneurs.” Journal of Business Venturing 7, no. 2, pp. 115–35; Peterson, R. 1988. “Understanding and Encouraging Entrepreneurship Internationally.” Journal of Small Business Management 26, no. 2, pp. 1–7; and Huisman, D. 1985. “Entrepreneurship: Economic and Cultural Influences on the Entrepreneurial Climate.” European Research 13, no. 4, pp. 10–17.

55 Mueller, S., and A. Thomas. 2000. “Culture and Entrepreneurial Potential: A Nine Country Study of Locus of Control and Innovativeness.” Journal of ­Business Venturing 16, no. 1, pp. 51–75, 58.

56 Id. at p. 59.

57 Baumol, W. 1990. “Entrepreneurship: Productive, Unproductive, and Destructive.” Journal of Political Economy 98, no. 5, pp. 893–921; Shane, S. 1995. “Uncertainty Avoidance and the Preference for Innovation Championing Roles.” Journal of International Business Studies 26, no. 1, pp. 47–68; Shapero, A., and L. Sokol. 1982. “The Social Dimensions of Entrepreneurship.” In Encyclopedia of Entrepreneurship, ed. K. Vesper, 72–90. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.

58 Bouncken, R., J. Zagvozdina, and A. Golze. 2009. “A Comparative Study of Cultural Influences on Intentions to Found a New Venture in Germany and Poland.” International Journal of Business and Globalisation 3, no. 1, pp. 47–65, 51–52.

59 Erez, M., and P. Earley. 1993. Culture, Self-Identity, and Work. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.

60 McGrath, R., I. MacMillan, and S. Scheinberg. 1992. “Elitists, Risk-takers, and Rugged Individualists—An Exploratory Analysis of Cultural-Differences between Entrepreneurs and Non-entrepreneurs.” Journal of Business Venturing 7, no. 2, pp. 115–35.

61 See, for example, McGrath, R., I. MacMillan, and S. Scheinberg. 1992. “Elitists, Risk-takers, and Rugged Individualists—An Exploratory Analysis of Cultural-Differences between Entrepreneurs and Non-entrepreneurs.” Journal of Business Venturing 7, no. 2, pp. 115–35; Busenitz, L., and C. Lau. 1996. “A Cross-Cultural Cognitive Model of Venture Creation.” Entrepreneurship: Theory and Practice 20, no. 4, pp. 25–39; Mitchell, R., B. Smith, K. Seawright, and E. Morse. 2000. “Cross-Cultural Cognitions and the Venture Creation Decision.” Academy of Management Journal 43, no. 5, pp. 974–93; Morris, M., D. Davis, and J. Allen. 1994. “Fostering Corporate Entrepreneurship—Cross-cultural Comparisons of the Importance of Individualism Versus Collectivism.” Journal of International Business Studies 25, no. 1, pp. 65–89; and Takyi-Asiedu, S. 1993. “Some Socio-Cultural Factors Retarding Entrepreneurial Activity in Sub-Saharan Africa.” Journal of Business Venturing 8, no. 2, pp. 91–98. The discussion of the various cultural dimensions herein assumes familiarity with the topic, which is introduced and discussed in “Globalization: A Library of Resources for Sustainable Entrepreneurs” prepared and distributed by the Sustainable Entrepreneurship Project (www.seproject.org).

62 McGrath, R., I. MacMillan, and S. Scheinberg. 1992. “Elitists, Risk-takers, and Rugged Individualists—An Exploratory Analysis of Cultural-Differences between Entrepreneurs and Non-entrepreneurs.” Journal of Business Venturing 7, no. 2, pp. 115–35.

63 See, for example, Aiken, M., and J. Hage. 1971. “The Organic Organization and Innovation.” Sociology 5, no. 1, pp. 63–82; Burns, T., and G. Stalker. 1961. The Management of Innovation. London: Tavistock; Thompson, J. 1967. Organizations in Action. New York, NY: McGraw-Hill; and Zaltman, G., R. Duncan, and J. Holbek. 1973. Innovations and Organizations. New York, NY: A Wiley-Interscience Publication.

64 Burns, T., and G. Stalker. 1961. The Management of Innovation. London: Tavistock.

65 Id. The relative “equality” associated with a low power distant environment also increase opportunities for the formation of coalitions that are useful in combining the resources required for innovation. See, for example, Thompson, J. 1967. Organizations in Action. New York, NY: McGraw-Hill.

66 Aldrich, H. 1979. Organizations and Environments. Englewood Cliffs, NJ.: Prentice Hall; and Aiken, M., and J. Hage. 1971. “The Organic Organization and Innovation.” Sociology 5, no. 1, pp. 63—82. Other researchers have also found that the more innovative organizations in surveys conducted in the United States and Japan were those that created mechanisms for freer communications throughout the organization. See, for example, Shane, S. 1993. ­“Cultural ­Influences on National Rates of Innovation.” Journal of Business Venturing, pp. 59–73; and Thompson, J. 1967. Organizations in Action. New York, NY: McGraw-Hill.

67 Bouncken, R., J. Zagvozdina, and A. Golze. 2009. “A Comparative Study of Cultural Influences on Intentions to Found a New Venture in Germany and Poland.” International Journal of Business and Globalisation 3, no. 1, pp. 47–65, 51.

68 Peterson, R. 1980. “Entrepreneurship and Organization.” In Handbook of Organizational Design, eds. P. Nystrom and W. Starbuck. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.

69 McGrath, R., I. MacMillan, and S. Scheinberg. 1992. “Elitists, Risk-takers, and Rugged Individualists—An Exploratory Analysis of Cultural-Differences between Entrepreneurs and Non-entrepreneurs.” Journal of Business Venturing 7, no. 2, pp. 115–35.

70 Shane, S. 1992. “Why Do Some Societies Invent More than Others?” Journal of Business Venturing 7, no. 1, pp. 29–46.

71 For an extensive discussion of the various “trait” theories of entrepreneurship, see “Motivational Traits of Prospective Entrepreneurs” in “Entrepreneurship: A Library of Resources for Sustainable Entrepreneurs” prepared and distributed by the Sustainable Entrepreneurship Project (www.seproject.org).

72 Mueller, S., and A. Thomas. 2000. “Culture and Entrepreneurial Potential: A Nine Country Study of Locus of Control and Innovativeness.” Journal of ­Business Venturing 16, pp. 51–75, 60 (including citations). Research has generally confirmed that firm founders are more “internal” than the general public with regard to locus of control.

73 Bouncken, R., J. Zagvozdina, and A. Golze. 2009. “A Comparative Study of Cultural Influences on Intentions to Found a New Venture in Germany and Poland.” International Journal of Business and Globalisation 3, no. 1, pp. 47–65, 52 (citing Tiessen, J. 1997. “Individualism, Collectivism and Entrepreneurship: A Framework for International Comparative Research.” Journal of Business ­Venturing 12, no. 5, pp. 367–84).

74 Id. (citing Shane, S. 1992. “Why Do Some Societies Invent More than ­Others?” Journal of Business Venturing 7, no. 1, pp. 29–46; and Shane, S. 1993. “Cultural Influences on National Rates of Innovation.” Journal of Business Venturing 8, no. 1, pp. 59–73).

75 McGrath, R., I. MacMillan, and S. Scheinberg. 1992. “Elitists, Risk-takers, and Rugged Individualists—An Exploratory Analysis of Cultural-Differences between Entrepreneurs and Non-entrepreneurs.” Journal of Business Venturing 7, no. 2, pp. 115–35.

76 Dwyer, S., H. Mesak, and H. Maxwell. 2005. “An Exploratory Examination of the Influence of National Culture on Cross-national Product Diffusion.” Journal of International Marketing 13, no. 2, pp. 1–28.

77 Mueller, S., and A. Thomas. 2000. “Culture and Entrepreneurial Potential: A Nine Country Study of Locus of Control and Innovativeness.” Journal of ­Business Venturing 16, pp. 51–75, 61.

78 Tuunanen, M., and K. Hyrsky. 1997. “Innovation Preferences among Finnish and U.S. Entrepreneurs.” Academy of Entrepreneurship Journal 3, no. 1, pp. 1–11.

79 Shane, S. 1993. “Cultural Influences on National Rates of Innovation.” ­Journal of Business Venturing 8, pp. 59–73 (innovation rates determined by ­reference to number of trademarks granted to nationals of the 33 countries included in the survey). See also Shane, S. 1995. “Uncertainty Avoidance and the Preference for Innovation Championing Roles.” Journal of International Business Studies 26, no. 1, pp. 47–68.

80 Mueller, S., and A. Thomas. 2000. “Culture and Entrepreneurial Potential: A Nine Country Study of Locus of Control and Innovativeness.” Journal of ­Business Venturing 16, no. 1, pp. 51–75. While students in 15 countries were surveyed the cultural analysis was limited to those nine countries within that group that were in 1980 survey conducted by Hofstede: the United States, Croatia and Slovenia (former Yugoslavia), Canada, Ireland, Belgium, Germany, Singapore, and China (PRC).

81 Id. at p. 52.

82 Bouncken, R., J. Zagvozdina, and A. Golze. 2009. “A Comparative Study of Cultural Influences on Intentions to Found a New Venture in ­Germany and Poland.” International Journal of Business and Globalisation 3, no. 1, pp. 47–65. The authors noted that the cultural profiles of the two countries based on ­Hofstede’s four cultural dimensions were as follows: power distance—Germany “low” and Poland “high”; uncertainty avoidance—both “high”; ­individualism-collectivism—Germany “individualist” and Poland “collectivist”; and masculine-feminine: both “masculine”. Id. at p. 50.

83 Bouncken et al. commented that collectivism is important to certain aspects of successful entrepreneurship such as leveraging resources internally, establishing external ties and effective teamwork among members of a group involved in launching a new venture. They noted that their results for Poland, a “collectivist” society as opposed to the “individualism” associated with Germany, explicitly identified the positive impact of collectivism as a motivator for entrepreneurship and thus suggested that it was best for “research to move from the single dimensional measures of individualism to two dimensional measures of individualism and collectivism.” Id. at pp. 60–61.

84 Hyrsky, K., M. Tuunanen, and M. Koiranen. March 22, 2012. “Innovativeness and Risk-Taking Propensity: A Cross-Cultural Study of Finnish and U.S. Entrepreneurs and Small Business Owners.” lta.hse.fi/1999/3/lta_1999_03_s2.pdf (accessed March 22, 2012).

85 Abbey, A. 2002. “Cross-Cultural Comparison of the Motivation for Entrepreneurship.” Journal of Business and Entrepreneurship 14, no. 1, pp. 69–82. The researcher noted that Ghana’s place as a more collectivist society on the ­Hofstede individualism-collectivism scale was consistent with other countries in West Africa where there is a strong emphasis on extended familial relationships and traditional values that persist even in the face of the influences of modernization. See, for example, Sadowsky, R. 1989. The Things We Lose. Columbia, MO: ­University of Missouri Press; and McFadden, J., and K. Gbekobou. 1984. “Counseling African Children in the United States.” Elementary School Guidance and Counseling 18, pp. 223–30. The researcher conducted his own assessment among the respondents in his survey to confirm the differences between the two groups of entrepreneurs on various indicators used to measure placement on the individualist-collectivist pole.

86 Abbey, A. 2002. “Cross-Cultural Comparison of the Motivation for Entrepreneurship.” Journal of Business and Entrepreneurship 14, no. 1, pp. 69–82.

87 See, for example, Huisman, D. 1985. “Entrepreneurship: Economic and ­Cultural Influences on the Entrepreneurial Climate.” European Research 13, no. 4, pp. 10–17; and Wittman, D. 1989. “Why Democracies Produce Efficient Results.” Journal of Political Economy 97, no. 6, pp. 1395–424.

88 Mitchell, R., B. Smith, K. Seawright, and E. Morse. 2000. “Cross-Cultural Cognitions and the Venture Creation Decision.” Academy of Management Journal 43, no. 5, pp. 974–93. Other researchers have found similarities across ­countries with respect to certain predictors of success of small firms including staffing, level of education, and use of professional advice and planning. Lussier, R., and S. Pfeifer. July 1, 2001. “A Cross-National Prediction Model for Business ­Success.” Journal of Small Business Management (comparing small firms in the United States and in Central Eastern Europe).

89 Busenitz, L., C. Gomez, and J. Spencer. 2000. “Country Institutional Profiles: Unlocking Entrepreneurial Phenomena.” Academy of Management Journal 43, no. 5, pp. 994–1003.

90 Arzeni, S. Dec 1997/Jan 1998. “Entrepreneurship and Job Creation.” The OECD Observer 209, pp. 18–20; Bates, T., and C. Dunham. 1993. “Asian-American Success in Self-Employment.” Economic Development Quarterly 7, no. 2, pp. 199–214; and McDougall, P., and B. Oviatt. 1997. “International Entrepreneurship Literature in the 1990s and Directions for Future Research.” In Entrepreneurship 2000, 291–320. eds. D. Sexton and R. Smilor, Chicago, IL: Upstart Publishing.

91 King, R., and T. Craig. 2002. “Asia and Global Popular Culture: The View from He Yong’s Garbage Dump.” In Global Goes Local: Popular Culture in Asia, eds. R. King and T. Craig, 1–11. Vancouver: UBC Press.

92 Ray, D., and D. Turpin. 1987. “Factors Influencing Entrepreneurial Events in Japanese High Tech Venture Business.” In Frontiers of Entrepreneurship Research, eds. N. Churchill et al. Wellesley, MA: Babson College; and Scheinberg, S., and I. MacMillan. 1988. “An Eleven-country Study of the Motivation to Start a Business.” In Frontiers of Entrepreneurship Research, eds. B. Kirchoff, W. Long, W. McMullan, K. Vesper and W. Wetzel. Wellesley, MA: Babson College.

93 McGrath, R., I. MacMillan, and S. Scheinberg. 1992. “Elitists, Risk-takers, and Rugged Individualists? An Exploratory Analysis of Cultural Differences between Entrepreneurs and Non-entrepreneurs.” Journal of Business Venturing 7, no. 2, pp. 115–35.

94 Shane, S., L. Kolvereid, and P. Westhead. 1991. “An Exploratory Examination of the Reasons Leading to New Firm Formation across Country and Gender (Part 1).” Journal of Business Venturing 6, no. 6, pp. 431–46.

95 Abbey, A. 2002. “Cross-Cultural Comparison of the Motivation for Entrepreneurship.” Journal of Business and Entrepreneurship 14, no. 1, pp. 69–82.

96 Shapero, A., and L. Sokol. 1982. “The Social Dimensions of Entrepreneurship.” In Encyclopedia of Entrepreneurship, eds. C. Kent, D. Sexton and K. Vesper, 72–88. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.

97 Ho, M., and M. Wilson. March 31, 2012. “Cognitive Mapping Methodologies for Entrepreneurial Cognition Research.” http://swinburne.edu.au/lib/ir/onlineconferences/agse2008/000022.pdf (accessed March 31, 2012). For further discussion of the “cognitive view” of entrepreneurship, see Meyer, D., W. Gartner, and S. Venkataraman. 2000. “The Research Domain of Entrepreneurship.” Entrepreneurship Division Newsletter 15, no. 6; Stevenson, H., and J. Jarillo. 1990. “A Paradigm of Entrepreneurship: Entrepreneurial Management.” Strategic Management Journal 11, no. 1, pp. 17–27; and Venkataraman, S. 1997. “The Distinctive Domain of Entrepreneurship Research.” In Advances in Entrepreneurship, Firm Emergence and Growth, ed. J. Katz, 119–38. 3 vols. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.

98 Baron, R. 1998. “Cognitive Mechanisms in Entrepreneurship: Why and When Entrepreneurs Think Differently than Other People.” Journal of Business Venturing 13, no. 4, pp. 275–94.

99 Krueger, N. 2000. “The Cognitive Infrastructure of Opportunity Emergence.” Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 24, no. 3, pp. 5–23.

100 Gatewood, E., K. Shaver, and W. Gartner. 1995. “A Longitudinal Study of Cognitive Factors Influencing Start-up Behaviors and Success at Venture Creation.” Journal of Business Venturing 10, no. 5, pp. 371–91.

101 Mitchell, R., B. Smith, K. Seawright, and E. Morse. 2000. “Cross-Cultural Cognitions and the Venture Creation Decision.” Academy of Management Journal 43, no. 5, pp. 974–93.

102 Mitchell, R., J. Smith, E. Morse, A. Peredo, and B. McKenzie. 2002. “Are Entrepreneurial Cognitions Universal? Assessing Entrepreneurial Cognitions across Cultures.” Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 26, no. 4, pp. 9–32.

103 Leddo, J., and R. Abelson. 1986. “The Nature of Explanations.” In Knowledge Structures, eds. J. Galambos, R. Abelson and J. Black, 103–22. New Jersey, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates.

104 Vesper, K. 1996. New Venture Experience. Seattle, WA: Vector Books; and Mitchell, R., B. Smith, K. Seawright, and E. Morse. 2000. “Cross-Cultural ­Cognitions and the Venture Creation Decision.” Academy of Management Journal 43, no. 5, pp. 974–93.

105 Id.

106 Ghemawat, P. 1991. Commitment: The Dynamics of Strategy. New York, NY: The Free Press; and Hisrich, R., and A. Jankowicz. 1990. “Intuition in Venture Capital Decisions: An Exploratory Study Using a New Technique.” Journal of Business Venturing 5, no. 1, pp. 49–62.

107 Kirzner, I. 1982. “The Theory of Entrepreneurship in Economic Growth.” In Encyclopedia of Entrepreneurship, eds. C. Kent, D. Sexton and K. Vesper, 272–76. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall; and Krueger, N., and D. Brazeal. Spring 1994. “Entrepreneurial Potential and Potential Entrepreneurs.” Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 19, pp. 91–104.

108 Sexton, D., and N. Bowman-Upton. 1985. “The Entrepreneur: A Capable Executive and More.” Journal of Business Venturing 1, no. 1, pp. 129–40.

109 Glaser, R. 1984. “Education and Thinking.” American Psychologist 39, pp. 93–104.

110 Mitchell, R., B. Smith, K. Seawright, and E. Morse. 2000. “Cross-Cultural Cognitions and the Venture Creation Decision.” Academy of Management Journal 43, no. 5, 974–93.

111 Stevenson, H., M. Roberts, and H. Grousbeck. 1994. New Business Ventures and the Entrepreneur. Homewood, IL: Irwin.

112 Meyer, D., W. Gartner, and S. Venkataraman. 2000. “The Research Domain of Entrepreneurship.” Entrepreneurship Division Newsletter 15, no. 6; ­Stevenson, H., and J. Jarillo. 1990. “A Paradigm of Entrepreneurship: Entrepreneurial Management.” Strategic Management Journal 11, pp. 17–27; and Venkataraman, S. 1997. “The Distinctive Domain of Entrepreneurship Research.” In Advances in Entrepreneurship, Firm Emergence and Growth, ed. J. Katz, 119–38. 3 vols. ­Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.

113 Gartner, W. 1985. “A Conceptual Framework for Describing the Phenomenon of New Venture Creation.” Academy of Management Review 10, no. 4, pp, 696–706; and Gibb, A., and J. Richie. 1982. “Understanding the Process of Starting Small Business.” European Small Business Journal 1, no. 1, pp. 26–45.

114 Klapper, L., R. Amit, and M. Guillén. February 2008. Entrepreneurship and Firm Formation across Countries. Washington, DC: The World Bank Group.

115 Eunni, R. March 2010. “Institutional Environments for Entrepreneurship in Emerging Economies: Brazil vs. Mexico.” World Journal of Management 2, no. 1, pp. 1–18 (citing Hwang, H., and W. Powell. 2005. “Institutions and Entrepreneurship.” In Handbook of Entrepreneurship Research, eds. Z. Acs and D. Audretsch, 179–210. Norwell, MA: Kluwer; Gnyawali, D., and D. Fogel. 1994. “Environments for Entrepreneurship Development: Key Dimensions and Research Implications.” Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 18, no. 4, pp. 43–62; and Aldrich, H. 1990. “Using an Ecological Perspective to Study Organizational Founding Rates.” Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 14, no. 3, pp. 7–24).

116 Ahlstrom, D., and G. Bruton. 2002. “An Institutional Perspective on the Role of Culture in Shaping Strategic Actions by Technology-focused Entrepreneurial Firms in China.” Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 26, no. 4, pp. 53–70; and Roy, W. 1997. Socializing Capital: The Rise of the Large Industrial Corporation in America. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

117 Aldrich, H., and G. Wiedenmayer. 1993. “From Traits to Rates: An Ecological Perspective on Organizational Foundings.” In Advances in Entrepreneurship, Firm Emergence, and Growth, eds. J. Katz and A. Brockhaus, 145–95. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.

118 Wennekers, A., and A. Thurik. 1999. “Linking Entrepreneurship and Economic Growth.” Small Business Economics 13, no. 1, pp. 27–55; and Baumol, W. 2002. The Free Market Innovation Machine: Analyzing the Growth Miracle of Capitalism. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press (both observing that new venture creation leads to the creation of new jobs and economic welfare).

119 Peng, M., and P. Heath. 1996. “The Growth of the Firm in Planned Economies in Transformation: Institutions, Organizations and Strategic Choice.” Academy of Management Review 21, no. 2, pp. 492–528; Ahlstrom, D., and G. Bruton. 2002. “An Institutional Perspective on the Role of Culture in Shaping Strategic Actions by Technology-Focused Entrepreneurial Firms in China.” Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 26, no. 4, pp. 53–70; Smallbone, D., and F. Welter. 2001. “The Distinctiveness of Entrepreneurship in Transition Economies.” Small Business Economics 16, no. 4, pp. 249–62; and Smallbone, D., and F. Welter. 2006. “Conceptualizing Entrepreneurship in a Transition Context.” International Journal of Entrepreneurship and Small Business 3, no. 2, pp. 190–206.

120 North, D. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance. New York, NY: Norton. In a later work, North commented that institutions “form the incentive structure of a society, and the political and economic institutions, in consequence, are the underlying determinants of economic performance” and then defined institutions as “the humanly devised constraints that structure human interaction . . . [t]hey are made up of formal constraints (such as rules, laws, constitutions), informal constraints (such as norms of behavior, conventions, self-imposed codes of conduct), and their enforcement characteristics.” North, D. 1994. “Economic Performance through Time.” American Economic Review 84, no. 3, pp. 359–68, 360.

121 Scott, W. 1995. Institutions and Organizations. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. Scott’s classification model has been adopted by a number of other researchers. See, for example, Ahlstrom, D., and G. Bruton. 2002. “An Institutional Perspective on the Role of Culture in Shaping Strategic Actions by Technology-Focused Entrepreneurial Firms in China.” Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 26, no. 4, pp. 53–70; Kostova, T. 1997. “Country Institutional Profiles: Concept and Measurement.” Academy of Management Best Paper Proceedings, no. 1, pp. 180–89; Parkhe, A. 2003. “Institutional Environments, Institutional Change and International Alliances.” Journal of International Management 9, no. 3, pp. 305–16; and Bruton, G., V. Fried, and S. Manigart. 2005. “Institutional Influences on the Worldwide Expansion of Venture Capital.” Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 29, no. 6, pp. 737–60.

122 Busenitz, L., C. Gomez, and J. Spencer. 2000. “Country Institutional ­Profiles: Unlocking Entrepreneurial Phenomena.” Academy of Management Journal 43, no. 5, pp. 994–1003.

123 It should be noted, however, that when discussing the normative dimension a comparison of the institutional environment for entrepreneurship in Mexico and Brazil, Eunni included the role of industry and trade associations, formalization of recordkeeping and accounting requirements, the sophistication of local banking and insurance industries, support for new business incubation, and the availability of funding for the promotion of innovation. Eunni, R. March 2010. “Institutional Environments for Entrepreneurship in Emerging Economies: ­Brazil vs. Mexico.” World Journal of Management 2, no. 1, pp. 1–18.

124 Id. (citing Hwang, H., and W. Powell. 2005. “Institutions and Entrepreneurship.” In Handbook of Entrepreneurship Research, eds. Z. Acs and D. Audretsch, 179–210. Norwell, MA: Kluwer; Gnyawali, D., and D. Fogel. 1994. “Environments for Entrepreneurship Development: Key Dimensions and Research Implications.” Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 18, no. 4, pp. 43–62; and Aldrich, H. 1990. “Using an Ecological Perspective to Study Organizational Founding Rates.” Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 14, no. 3, pp. 7–24).

125 Eunni reported that for both countries the means of their scores were below “4” on the 7-point Likert scale and observed that the findings were consistent with how the countries fared in other studies such as the World Economic Forum’s Global Competitiveness Report (in 2008 Mexico ranked 60th and Brazil 64th among 134 surveyed countries on indicators of economic competitiveness) and the World Bank’s “Ease of Doing Business” rankings (in 2008 Mexico ranked 56th and Brazil ranked 125th among 181 surveyed countries). Id.

126 For further discussion of the GEM, see “Research in ­Entrepreneurship” in “Entrepreneurship: A Library of Resources for Sustainable Entrepreneurs.” ­Prepared and distributed by the Sustainable Entrepreneurship Project (www.seproject.org).

127 See, for example, Coase, R. 1937. “The Nature of the Firm.” Economica, 4, no. 4, pp. 386–405; Williamson, O. 1998. “The Institutions of Governance.” American Economic Review 88, no. 2, pp. 75–79; North, D. 1994. “Economic Performance through Time.” American Economic Review 84, no. 3, pp. 359–68.

128 Milo, M. 2007. Integrated Financial Supervision: An Institutional ­Perspective for the Philippines, 18. Tokyo: Asian Development Bank Institute, ADBI ­Discussion Paper 81.

129 Aron, J. 2000. “Growth and Institutions: A Review of the Evidence.” The World Rank Research Observer 15, no. 1, pp. 99–135.

130 Milo, M. 2007. Integrated Financial Supervision: An Institutional Perspective for the Philippines, 19. Tokyo: Asian Development Bank Institute, ADBI ­Discussion Paper 81, (citing Jütting, J. 2003. Institutions and Development: A Critical Review. Paris: OECD Development Centre, Work Paper No. 210).

131 Id.

132 See, for example, Chu, K. 2003. “Collective Values, Behavioural Norms and Rules: Building Institutions for Economic Growth and Poverty Reduction.” In Perspectives on Growth and Poverty, eds. R. van der Hoeven and A. Shorrocks. Tokyo: United Nations University Press; Fukuyama, F. January 19–21, 2006. “Development and the Limits of Institutional Design.” Paper Presented at the Seventh Annual Global Development Network Conference, St. Petersburg; and North, D. 1994. “Economic Performance through Time.” American Economic Review 84, no. 3, pp. 359–68.

133 Milo, M. 2007. Integrated Financial Supervision: An Institutional ­Perspective for the Philippines, 19. Tokyo: Asian Development Bank Institute, ADBI ­Discussion Paper 81.

134 For discussion of the role of institutions in establishing a platform for entrepreneurship that can lead to economic growth and development, see “Entrepreneurship in Developing Countries.” Prepared and distributed by the Sustainable Entrepreneurship Project (www.seproject.org).

135 Milo, M. 2007. Integrated Financial Supervision: An Institutional ­Perspective for the Philippines, 19. Tokyo: Asian Development Bank Institute, ADBI ­Discussion Paper 81 (citing Posner, R. 1998. “Creating a Legal Framework for ­Economic Development.” The World Bank Research Observer. Washington DC: The World Bank).

136 Id.

137 Id. at p. 20 (citing Shirley, M. 2005. “Institutions and Development.” In Handbook of New Institutional Economics, eds. C. Menard and M. Shirley, Dordrecht, Netherlands: Kluwer Academic Publishers).

138 Lazzeretti, L., S. Sedita, and A. Caloffi, 2014. “Founders and Disseminators of Cluster Research.” Journal of Economic Geography 14, no. 1, p. 21.

139 Dearlove, D. July 1, 2001. “The Cluster Effect: Can Europe Clone Silicon Valley?” Strategy+Business (citing Marshall, A. 1890. Principles of Economics).

140 For extensive discussion of Schumpeter’s theories relating to “entrepreneurship,” see Schumpeter, J. 1949. Theory of Economic Development.

141 See Romer, D. 2011. “Endogenous Growth.” In Advanced Macroeconomics, 4th ed. 101.

142 Porter explained his research and theories in a number of articles including Porter, M. 1998. “Clusters and the New Economics of Competition.” Harvard Business Review 76, no. 6, pp. 77–90; and Porter, M. 2000. “Location, Competition, and Economic Development: Local Clusters in a Global Economy.” Economic Development Quarterly 14, no. 1, pp. 15–34, 16.

143 Dearlove, D. July 1, 2001. “The Cluster Effect: Can Europe Clone Silicon Valley?” Strategy+Business.

144 Id. (citing Porter, M. 2000. “Location, Competition, and Economic Development: Local Clusters in a Global Economy.” Economic Development Quarterly 14, no. 1, p. 16).

145 Mason, C., and R. Brown. November 7, 2013. “Entrepreneurial Ecosystems and Growth Oriented Entrepreneurship.” International Workshop on Entrepreneurial Ecosystems and Growth Oriented Entrepreneurship Organized by OECD LEED Programme and Dutch Ministry of Economic Affairs Workshop; Background Paper (Final Version: January 2014).

146 Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. 2013. An International Benchmarking Analysis of Public Programmes for High-growth Firms. OECD LEED programme, Paris; and Brown, R., C. Mason, and S. Mawson. 2014. Increasing the Vital 6%: Designing Effective Public Policy to Support High Growth Firms. London: National Endowment for Science Technology & Arts (NESTA).

147 Henrekson, M., and D. Johansson. 2010. “Gazelles as Job Creators: A ­Survey and Interpretation of the Evidence.” Small Business Economics 35, no. 2, pp. 227–44.

148 Mason, G., K. Bishop, and C. Robinson. 2009. Business Growth and Innovation: The Wider Impact of Rapidly Growing Firms in UK City-Regions. London: NESTA [http:// niesr.ac.uk/pdf/ 190509_94959.pdf]; Du, J., Y. Gong, and Y. Temouri. 2013. High Growth Firms and Productivity: Evidence from the UK. ­London, NESTA. [http://nesta.org.uk/publications/working_papers/assets/features/high_growth_ firms_and_productivity]; Feldman, M., J. Francis, and J. Bercovitz, 2005. “Creating a Cluster While Building a Firm: Entrepreneurs and the Formation of Industrial Clusters.” Regional Studies 39, pp. 129–41; and Brown, R. 2011. “The Determinants of High Growth Entrepreneurship in the Scottish Food and Drink Cluster.” In The Handbook of Research on Entrepreneurship in Agriculture and Rural Development, eds. G. Alsos, S. Carter, E. Ljunggren, and F. Welter. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

149 Zacharakis, A., D. Shepard, and J. Coombs. 2003. “The Development of Venture-Capital-backed Internet Companies: An Ecosystem Perspective.” Journal of Business Venturing 18, p. 217; Napier, G., and C. Hansen. 2011. Ecosystems for Young Scaleable Firms (FORA Group,); and Feld, B. 2012. Startup Communities: Building an Entrepreneurial Ecosystem in Your City. Hoboken, NJ: Wiley.

150 Mason, C., and R. Brown. November 7, 2013. “Entrepreneurial Ecosystems and Growth Oriented Entrepreneurship.” International Workshop on Entrepreneurial Ecosystems and Growth Oriented Entrepreneurship Organized by OECD LEED Programme and Dutch Ministry of Economic Affairs Workshop; Background Paper, 5 (Final Version: January 2014).

151 Id. at pp. 5–6.

152 Isenberg, D. 2011. The Entrepreneurship Ecosystem Strategy as a New Paradigm for Economy Policy: Principles for Cultivating Entrepreneurship, 4. Babson Park, MA: Babson Entrepreneurship Ecosystem Project, Babson College.

153 Mason, C., and R. Brown. November 7, 2013. “Entrepreneurial Ecosystems and Growth Oriented Entrepreneurship.” International Workshop on Entrepreneurial Ecosystems and Growth Oriented Entrepreneurship Organized by OECD LEED Programme and Dutch Ministry of Economic Affairs Workshop; Background Paper, 1 (Final Version: January 2014).

154 Id.

155 World Economic Forum. September 2013, Entrepreneurial Ecosystems around the Globe and Company Growth Dynamics: Report Summary for the Annual Meeting of the New Champions 2013.

156 For a further discussion of the specific issues and challenges associated with launching an emerging company, as well as a description of the characteristics of such a firm, see the Part on “Launching a New Business” in “Entrepreneurship: A Library of Resources for Sustainable Entrepreneurs.” prepared and distributed by the Sustainable Entrepreneurship Project (www.seproject.org).

157 Mason, C., and R. Brown. November 7, 2013. “Entrepreneurial Ecosystems and Growth Oriented Entrepreneurship.” International Workshop on Entrepreneurial Ecosystems and Growth Oriented Entrepreneurship Organized by OECD LEED Programme and Dutch Ministry of Economic Affairs Workshop; Summary Report.

158 Acemoglu, D. “Challenges for Social Sciences: Institutions and Economic Development.” http://aeaweb.org/econwhitepapers/white_papers/Daron_Acemoglu.pdf

159 Id.

160 Chu, K. 2003. “Collective Values, Behavioural Norms and Rules: Building Institutions for Economic Growth and Poverty Reduction.” In Perspectives on Growth and Poverty, eds. R. van der Hoeven and A. Shorrocks. Tokyo: United Nations University Press.

161 Milo, M. 2007. Integrated Financial Supervision: An Institutional Perspective for the Philippines, 23–29. Tokyo: Asian Development Bank Institute, ADBI ­Discussion Paper 81.

162 Id. at p. 20 (citing Eicher, T., and A. Leukert. August 24–28, 2006. “Institutions and Economic Performance: Endogeneity and Parameter Heterogeneity.” Paper Presented at the European Economic Association and Econometric Society Parallel Meetings, 2. Vienna).

163 Olson, M. 2008. “Big Bills Left on the Sidewalk: Why Some Nations Are Rich, and Others Poor.” In Making Poor Nations Rich: Entrepreneurship and the Process of Economic Development, ed. B. Powell, 25–53. Stanford, CA: Stanford Economics and Finance.

164 Powell, B. 2008. “Introduction.” In Making Poor Nations Rich: Entrepreneurship and the Process of Economic Development, 1–22, 3. ed. B. Powell, Stanford, CA: Stanford Economics and Finance.

165 Olson, M. 2008. “Big Bills Left on the Sidewalk: Why Some Nations Are Rich, and Others Poor.” In Making Poor Nations Rich: Entrepreneurship and the Process of Economic Development, 25–53, 44. ed. B. Powell. Stanford, CA: ­Stanford Economics and Finance.

166 Id. Olson’s article also includes citations to other studies that he and other conducted that provide “direct evidence of the linkage between better economic policies and institutions and better economic performance.” Id. at p. 47.

167 Id. at pp. 45–46. Olson noted during the 1970s the fastest growing countries in the world (apart from the oil-exporting countries) were poorer countries that grew at rates that far exceeded the growth achieved by the U.S. economy during that period. Id. A similar spree of spectacular growth rates, relative to industrialized countries, has been achieved in countries such as China and India in recent years.

168 Holcombe, R. 2008. “Entrepreneurship and Economic Growth.” In ­Making Poor Nations Rich: Entrepreneurship and the Process of Economic Development, 54–78. Stanford, CA: Stanford Economics and Finance.

169 Id. at p. 71.

170 Lingelbach, D., L. De La Vina, and P. Asel. March 2005. What’s Distinctive about Growth-Oriented Entrepreneurship in Developing Countries? 3. San Antonio, TX: UTSA College of Business Center for Global Entrepreneurship Working Paper No. 1.

171 Milo, M. 2007. Integrated Financial Supervision: An Institutional Perspective for the Philippines, 19. Tokyo: Asian Development Bank Institute, ADBI ­Discussion Paper 81.

172 Id. at p. 20 (citing Shirley, M. 2005. “Institutions and Development.” In Handbook of New Institutional Economics, eds. C. Menard and M. Shirley. Dordrecht, Netherlands: Kluwer Academic Publishers).

..................Content has been hidden....................

You can't read the all page of ebook, please click here login for view all page.
Reset
3.144.189.177