CHAPTER 5
Risk‐Neutral Valuation

While forward contracts separate the agreement date and the forward transaction date, they require both counterparties to abide by the terms of the forward contract, regardless of any profit or loss consideration. For example, the buyer in a forward contract has to buy the asset for the previously agreed upon price, even if the market price of the asset is below the contract price. An option contract, on the other hand, provides the right, but not the obligation, to transact an asset at some future date for predetermined terms. While the cash‐and‐carry argument allowed us to price a variety of forward contracts, the pricing of options requires more advanced techniques, and their pricing falls under the modern pricing paradigm of risk‐neutral valuation.

5.1 CONTINGENT CLAIMS

Option contracts are examples of contingent claims that allow the owner to transact at the option owner's sole discretion. We will focus on the economic value of the contract at transaction time and assume that an option owner will transact if and only if the economic value of the underlying transaction is positive.

The prime example of an option is a European‐style exercise option, which has a specified payoff at a specific exercise/expiration date images in the future. For example, a European‐style call option, images, with strike images on an asset images gives the owner the right—but not the obligation as opposed to a forward contract—to buy the asset for images at expiry images. At expiration, if the asset price is below the strike images, the option owner can buy the asset in the market for a lower price than images, and, hence, will not exercise the option and let it expire worthless. If the asset price is above images, then the option owner can buy the asset for images and sell it immediately in the market for images for a profit of images. The economic value of the option payoff is then

equation
Schematic illustration of Economic value of European-style call and put options at expiration with strike K=100.

FIGURE 5.1 Economic value of European‐style call and put options at expiration with strike images.

Similarly, a put option with strike images allows the owner to sell the asset at images at expiry and its economic value at expiration is images (see Figure 5.1).

While the value of the contingent claim is known at expiration, the goal of contingent‐claim pricing is to determine its value prior to expiry. We will call the economic value of the option at expiry the option payoff, and focus on evaluating today's value of this future option payoff.

In 1973, the celebrated Black‐Scholes‐Merton (BSM) formula was derived to price European‐style call and put options [Black and Scholes, 1973]. While BSM methodology used advanced mathematical techniques to derive the formula, it was shown later by Cox‐Ross‐Rubinstein (CRR) [Cox et al., 1979] that the same formula can be obtained and understood using much simpler techniques. This new methodology goes under the name of risk‐neutral valuation and is the modern framework for contingent claim valuation. Its basic result is that any contingent claim's value is its expected discounted value of its cash flows in a risk‐neutral world [Harrison and Kreps, 1979; Harrison and Pliska, 1981].

5.2 BINOMIAL MODEL

Given today's images price of an underlying asset images, consider a European‐style contingent claim images with expiration images. Assume that the underlying asset has no cash flows over the period images, and let us consider the simplest case where the underlying asset at expiration can only take on two values images, images, as shown in Figure 5.2. Let images and images denote the corresponding then‐known values of the contingent claim in each state at expiration.

Schematic illustration of One-step binomial model.

FIGURE 5.2 One‐step binomial model.

Our goal is to construct a replicating portfolio today so that the portfolio value at expiration (images) replicates the value of the contingent claim. The fair price of the option today, images, would be today's value of this replicating portfolio.

Our portfolio consists of taking a position in the asset, images units of it, with positive images meaning buy and negative images meaning short, and entering into a loan or deposit at the prevalent continuously compounded risk‐free rate images until images. If images, we are borrowing money and if images we are lending. In either case, the value of the loan or deposit at expiration would be images regardless of the state of the world.

At images, if we are in images state of the world, we want this portfolio to be worth images

equation

Similarly, if we are in images state of the world, we want the portfolio to be worth images

equation

We have two equations and two unknowns, images. Solving for these, we get

(5.1)equation
(5.2)equation

Today's value of the contingent claim is

(5.3)equation

The seller of the option can charge images, borrow or lend images at interest rate of images, and use the proceeds to have images units of the asset priced at images. At expiration, in either state of the world, images or images, the value of her holdings (images units of the asset) exactly offsets her liabilities: loan or deposit amount plus interest, images, and payment of the economic value of the option (images or images) to the option owner.

In Example 1, we are assuming fractional (50%) shares for exposition. For a more realistic example, assume that the call option allows one to buy 100 shares of the stock at the price images per share. To replicate this option, one needs to buy 50 shares of the asset today at the price of $100 per share.

The replication argument allows the buyer and the seller of the option to agree on the arbitrage‐free price of the option. The option buyer knows that by spending $3.44 per option, she can replicate the economic value of the option at expiration, and paying any amount less than $3.44 will result in a sure profit. In a competitive market with participants in search of sure profits, they will bid up the price of the option to the theoretical value until there are no sure profits left. Similarly, the option seller knows that by receiving $3.44 per option, she can own and, hence, deliver the economic value of the option at expiration, so any amount higher than that is a sure profit. In a competitive market, other participants will offer the option lower and lower until there are no sure profits left.

5.2.1 Probability‐Free Pricing

Note that in the above setup, we did not have to consider the probability of either state happening: as long as images can happen and are the only two possibilities, we are golden!

However, there are restrictions on the assumed future states. A bit of algebra allows us to rewrite the formula for images as an expected value

(5.4)equation

where

(5.5)equation

and we recognize the images term as the forward price images (see Figure 5.3).

5.2.2 No Arbitrage

Lack of arbitrage is equivalent to images being a probability

equation

which is equivalent to the following restriction on assumed states

equation
Schematic illustration of lack of arbitrage.

FIGURE 5.3 Lack of arbitrage.

To see this, consider the case images, which means that the forward is higher than either state in the future: images. In this case, we can sell the asset forward for images, and deliver it at images by buying it at either images or images. Regardless, we have made money with no risk.

Similarly, if images, then images, and we can ensure a risk‐less profit by buying the asset forward for images, and selling it higher at expiration for images or images.

Therefore, if there is no arbitrage in the above simple economy, images can be considered as a probability, and today's value of the option is simply the expected discounted value of the option payoff under this probability per Formula 5.4.

5.2.3 Risk‐Neutrality

We obtained images by constructing a portfolio that replicates the option payoff regardless of the probability of each state. We then showed that we can get the same value by taking the expected value under a probability images. Other than a mathematical identity—images is the probability that gets you the correct option value, as long as you know the option value—is there another way of interpreting images? The answer is in the affirmative: images is the probability that a risk‐neutral investor would apply to the above setting. Consider two alternatives:

  1. Invest images at the risk‐free rate images, and receive images at images.
  2. Buy an asset at images and either get images or images at images.

For a risk‐neutral investor, these two investments would be equivalent if

(5.6)equation
(5.7)equation

which is identical to the expression in Formula 5.5. Therefore, rather than setting up a replicating portfolio and computing its value today, we can simply take the expected discounted value of the option payoff using risk‐neutral probabilities. Notice that Formula 5.6 can be rewritten as

(5.8)equation

relating the risk‐neutral probabilities directly to the assumed evolution of the asset. We can also rewrite Formula 5.4 as

(5.9)equation

with both of the above expectations using risk‐neutral probabilities.

5.3 FROM ONE TIME‐STEP TO TWO

The two‐state setup is obviously too simplistic. Assets can take a variety of values at expiration. However, using the above setup as a building block, we can arrive at more complex cases. The idea is to subdivide the time from now until expiration into multiple intervals, and for each state in each interval, generate two new arbitrage‐free (bracketing the forward) future states. With enough sub‐divisions, we can arrive at a richer and more real‐life terminal distribution for the asset.

Consider a two time‐step extension of the 1‐step binomial model shown in Figure 5.4. For each intermediate node images at images, we can use the 1‐step binomial model's Formulas, 5.8, and 5.9, to arrive at the risk‐neutral probabilities that would provide the same values for images as the replicating portfolios images. Having computed images, we can then use the 1‐step binomial model again to compute the risk‐neutral probabilities that would provide the same value as the replicating portfolio images to compute images.

Schematic illustration of two-step binomial model.

FIGURE 5.4 Two‐step binomial model.

5.3.1 Self‐Financing, Dynamic Hedging

As we subdivide the time to expiration into finer partitions, for the replication argument to hold, we have to ensure that the original portfolio is sufficient. We can change the composition of the portfolio, but cannot add new assets or unknown cash amounts. Therefore, at each interim state we can change the amount of the asset we hold by securing requisite funds at the prevailing financing rates. As we do this dynamic rebalancing (changing imagess), the value of the portfolio entering into each state must equal the value of the portfolio leaving the state, that is, the replicating portfolio should be self‐financing.

Consider the up state images. As we enter it, we hold a portfolio that consists of images units of the asset now worth images, and a loan of size images plus its interest worth images. Therefore, the value of the portfolio value is

equation

On the other hand, images, since images is the required portfolio to replicate the option payoffs images at the next time step images. Therefore, we need to change our holding of the asset from images to images only by changing the size of our loan from images to images, that is, the change in the underlying holding should only be financed by changing the loan size

equation

ensuring that the portfolio is self‐financing. Similarly, in the down state images, we have

equation

5.3.2 Iterated Expectation

For the two time‐step model, at node images, the risk‐neutral probability images must satisfy

equation

Having found images, we can compute images

equation

Similarly, at node images, the risk‐neutral probability images must satisfy

equation

to compute images

equation

The above formulas can be compactly written as conditional expectations conditioned on all information about an underlying asset up to images

(5.10)equation

where both images are random variables.

Having obtained images, we can compute the risk‐neutral probability images via

equation

to get

(5.11)equation

and to compute images

(5.12)equation

where we have used the law of iterated expectation: For any pair of random variables images

equation

where the outer expectation is taken relative to all possible outcomes of images, see Appendix A.2.3. Combining Formulas 5.11 and 5.12, we have

(5.13)equation

where the top equations in Formulas 5.10 and 5.13 characterize the risk‐neutral probabilities solely based on the assumed evolution of the underlying asset, while the bottom equations provide the valuation for any contingent claim.

5.4 RELATIVE PRICES

Formulas 5.10 and 5.13 can be generalized to images

(5.14)equation

which can be written as

(5.15)equation

Let images be the value of unit investment at a risk‐free rate, that is images equals the value of a money market account started with unit currency and continuously reinvested at the risk‐free rate. images and images. We have

(5.16)equation

The first formula in 5.16 pins down the asset evolution in a risk‐neutral setting, while the second is the valuation formula for contingent claims. Note that we can always form a contingent claim whose payoff equals the value of the underlying, images, therefore, the second formula already includes the first one and we can simply write

(5.17)equation

Probing Formula 5.17 further, it states that under risk‐neutral probabilities, relative prices for the asset and contingent claims on it relative to the money market account, images, form a martingale: at any time images, the conditional expected future (images) value is the images‐value

equation

or said differently, the conditional expected change between any two times is zero

equation

A prime example of a martingale is the symmetric random walk (see Figure 5.6). At each time‐step, the expected value of the change is zero

equation

Furthermore, no matter where we are in the future, say point images or images after four time‐steps, the expected value of the change from then on is still zero. This is a characterization of one's stake with payoff of images based on the outcome of a fair (images) coin. The expected amount of win or loss at each toss is 0 and the expected value of one's stake after any images tosses is the initial stake. The same holds for the future: if after images tosses we are at some level images, the expected value of the stake after another images tosses is still the same level images.

5.4.1 Risk‐Neutral Valuation

We now have all the components of risk‐neutral valuation:

  1. Posit a random process for the evolution of the underlying assets.
  2. Adjust the process to ensure risk‐neutrality, equivalent to relative prices being martingales.
  3. The price of any contingent claim is the risk‐neutral expected discounted price of its cash flows.
Schematic illustration of a symmetric random walk is a martingale.

FIGURE 5.6 A symmetric random walk is a martingale.

Note that ensuring risk‐neutrality is a condition on expectations that are composed of products of assumed states and their respective probabilities. This allows one to either fix the states and adjust the probabilities, or alternatively one can fix the probabilities and solve for the states. As long as expected relative prices satisfy Formula 5.17, we can use this probability‐adjusted or state‐adjusted evolution to price contingent claims.

The risk‐neutral framework applies to non‐constant and random interest rates. In this case, the money market account's value becomes

equation

where images denotes the randomness of future interest rates. This allows the risk‐neutral valuation framework to encompass interest rate derivatives (see Section 7.4.1).

5.4.2 Fundamental Theorems of Asset Pricing

The generalization of the above multi‐step model to an arbitrary number of assets and contingent claims based on them gives rise to the following Fundamental Theorems of Asset Pricing:

  1. For a given multi‐asset economy, lack of arbitrage is equivalent to the existence of probability distributions, which would make relative prices martingales. Each such probability distribution is called a risk‐neutral measure.
  2. A complete market is where every contingent claim can be replicated via a self‐financing trading strategy. A market is complete if and only if there exists a unique risk‐neutral measure.

The first condition is a generalization of the result that to preclude arbitrage, forward prices should be bracketed by assumed future states.

The second condition is the generalization of our ability to solve the replication equations, i.e., two equations and two unknowns. Had we assumed that starting from two assets—a bank loan and an asset—the number of future states in the next time‐step could be different than two, we would have had a different number of equations than unknowns, leading to generally either no solution or many solutions and, hence, a range of values for the contingent claim. In this case, the market would not be complete and contingent claims would not have a unique replicating portfolio or price.

REFERENCES

  1. Black, F. and Scholes, M. (1973). The pricing of options and corporate liabilities. Journal of Political Economy 81: 637–659.
  2. Cox, J.C., Ross, S.A., and Rubinstein, M. (1979). Option pricing: A simplified approach. Journal of Financial Economics 7: 229–263.
  3. German, H., El Karoui, N., and Rochet, J.C. (1995). Changes of numeraire, changes of probability measure, and option pricing. Journal of Applied Probability 32: 443–458.
  4. Harrison, J.M. and Kreps, D.M. (1979). Martingales and arbitrage in multi‐period securities markets. Journal of Economic Theory 20: 381–408.
  5. Harrison, J.M. and Pliska, S.R. (1981). Martingales and stochastic integrals in the theory of continuous trading. Stochastic Processes and Their Applications 11: 215–260.

EXERCISES

  1. Assume the risk‐free continuously compounded interest rate is 4% per annum. For an asset with today's price images, you are told that its expected return is 10% per annum and that the asset in one year's time can be images with probabilities images. What is the expected value of the asset in one year in a risk‐neutral setting?
  2. For each step of the risk‐neutral binomial model, what is the expected continuously compounded yield
    equation
  3. Let images be the risk‐free continuously compounded rate and images today's value of an asset. For a given horizon images, assume the asset can take on two values images with risk‐neutral probabilities of images. Provide an expression for images if images for a given volatility parameter images.
  4. In a 1‐step binomial model, compute the risk‐neutral probabilities for some images when
    1. images
    2. images
  5. In the 1‐step binomial model shown in Figure 5.2, consider the portfolio consisting of one long position in the contingent claim and short
    equation

    of the asset, images.

    1. Show that the portfolio has the same value at images regardless of the terminal state images, that is images for a constant images and the portfolio is risk‐less.
    2. Using an arbitrage argument, show that today's value of the portfolio should be its discounted future value
      equation
      and compute images.
    3. Show that the computed value of images above is the same as Formula 5.3.
  6. Using the same numerical values as in the 2‐period binomial model in Example 2
    1. Calculate today's price, images, of a 6‐month European put option with strike images.
    2. Calculate today's value of a 6‐month forward contract with purchase price images.
    3. Verify that images.
  7. Replication via Forward Contracts. In the 1‐step binomial model, replicate the option payoff at expiration via images amount of a forward contract with delivery price of images.
    1. Solve for images
      equation
    2. Compute today's value of the above replicating forward contract: images.
    3. Is images the same as Formula 5.3?
  8. Given two independent random variables images
    1. Provide an expression for images.
    2. Evaluate the above when images.
  9. Let images be independent and identically distributed random variables with images, and let
    equation

    Show that images form a martingale

    equation
  10. For the random walk shown in Figure 5.6
    1. What is the expected movement during each period?
    2. What is the standard deviation of the movement during each period?
    3. What is the expected movement over images time periods
      equation
    4. What is the standard deviation of the movement over images time periods
      equation
..................Content has been hidden....................

You can't read the all page of ebook, please click here login for view all page.
Reset
3.128.171.246