Seeing Beyond the Blockchain Hype

The potential for blockchain to transform how organizations produce and capture value is very real, but so are the challenges to its broad implementation.

After eluding close inspection by most business leaders outside of the tech and financial sectors, blockchain technology has recently taken center stage in the conversation about management’s digital makeover. Indeed, many believe the impact of blockchain on the ways organizations function and produce value may be greater than the technologies that have grabbed most of our recent attention — data and analytics, the cloud, even artificial intelligence.

As with any emerging technology, it can be difficult to separate promise from probability. That is among the reasons why a new working paper from MIT Sloan School of Management professor Christian Catalini and University of Toronto Rotman School of Management professor Joshua S. Gans is so valuable: It offers a balanced analysis of blockchain through an economic lens.

Catalini discussed several of the study’s key findings and their relevance for managers in a written exchange with MIT Sloan Management Review editor in chief Paul Michelman, and what follows is an edited version of their conversation.

MIT Sloan Management Review: What prompted you to look at blockchain through an economics of innovation lens? What was it that you felt you knew — or suspected — before you began your investigation?

Catalini: There is substantial hype around blockchain and cryptocurrencies. As often happens when a breakthrough technology is on the horizon and uncertainty about its use cases is high, it becomes tempting to overstate its benefits and ignore the fact that technological change takes time to unfold and often requires entire ecosystems to adapt. Architectural changes in how value is created and appropriated within a given market do not happen overnight. They will generate resistance from regulators, who are trying to assess the risks the new technology involves, and from incumbents, who are worried about new entrants cannibalizing their revenue models.

In this phase, you often see strong polarization in opinions: On one side, you have detractors who highlight the current limitations of the technology (e.g., the fact that bitcoin can only process a small number of transactions per second or that bitcoin mining is highly concentrated in China) and use them to support their view that nothing will change. On the other side, you have the utopians who believe that the technology on its own can solve all of the problems of our financial system. The truth, of course, is somewhere in the middle. Economic theory can be extremely helpful in these cases: You take a step back, try to ignore the noise, and focus on the basic assumptions the technology is challenging. This is a difficult exercise, and our paper is just a first attempt in this direction.

We started by asking ourselves: What fundamental costs does blockchain reduce? If you can answer this question, it becomes much easier to identify where the opportunities are, whether you are an established firm, a startup, or a regulator. Applications that do not take advantage of the structural changes in costs the technology allows for are unlikely to succeed, as they will have a difficult time convincing consumers and businesses to adopt. Similarly, solutions that claim benefits the technology cannot currently deliver are likely to fail.

So, can blockchain reduce costs in a significant way? Where will we see an impact first?

Yes, we concluded that at least two key costs will be affected: the cost of verifying the attributes of a transaction (for example, when did it take place, who was involved, etc.) and the cost of exchanging value within a network without relying on a costly intermediary.

The ability to securely record and time-stamp information on a blockchain is extremely valuable when issues arise with a transaction. Whereas today we often have to invest resources to audit the transaction and assess the truth, in the future, these tasks could be automated thanks to a distributed ledger. This makes settlement and reconciliation across organizations simpler and more efficient, which explains why many early use cases are in the financial sector. Here the compelling reason to adopt is the ability to lower operational costs while keeping the rest of the ecosystem the same. It also explains why banks and financial institutions like distributed ledgers but are worried about cryptocurrencies. Distributed ledgers, on their own, do not challenge existing revenue models and regulatory frameworks. In fact, they may even allow incumbents to achieve greater economies of scale. Cryptocurrencies instead present an existential threat to how value is generated and appropriated in the economy.

This is where the second cost — the cost of networking — plays a key role: Before cryptocurrencies like bitcoin existed, we needed intermediaries to transfer value across the globe. Creating and maintaining a secure network was both capital and labor intensive. Bitcoin solves this problem by throwing cheap hardware at it: While often criticized for the energy-consuming computations needed to secure it, the bitcoin network has been extremely successful at automating value transfer. Where secure financial messaging platforms such as SWIFT and ACH have to invest in maintaining “trusted nodes” to validate transactions, Bitcoin uses a clever mix of cryptography and game theory to deliver the same results. Gone are the accounting, reconciliation, and security costs associated with ensuring that a transaction is not tampered with by a rogue employee or financial institution. The integrity of the underlying data is not guaranteed by an intermediary but by the design of the system itself. This is the architectural innovation associated with cryptocurrencies, and it constitutes both an opportunity and a threat to existing business models.

How does an organization begin to move in the direction of exploiting blockchain technology in the ways you describe here?

In terms of the cost of verification, an organization should ask where are resources currently being wasted in auditing transaction information, reconciling accounting books across different entities, and securing the integrity of digital trails both within as well as outside of the boundaries of the organization. By recording transaction attributes on a blockchain, organizations can ensure that auditing them in the future, if a dispute emerges, is cheap.

Of course, the immutability offered by a distributed ledger is only helpful if the information recorded on it is accurate in the first place. Hence, the cheaper it is to commit information early in the value chain and in an automated and tamper-proof fashion, the better. Similarly, the more one can envision replacing labor-intensive and time-consuming tasks with a combination of software and a “shared source of truth,” the more the technology is likely to be useful. Early applications on this front range from the trading and settlement of currencies and financial assets, to the tracking of ownership stakes in early stage companies. For example, in 2015, Nasdaq experimented with executing a private securities transaction for blockchain startup Chain Inc. on a distributed ledger, removing the manual steps typically involved in the process. Similarly, Digital Asset Holdings is developing distributed ledger technology for the Australian Securities Exchange post-trade market, and startups such as Circle Internet Financial and Abra are already using blockchain in their back end to lower the cost of transferring money across the globe.

Overall, most existing organizations are likely to benefit from a reduction in verification costs, as this change may not challenge their revenue models and may instead reduce frictions within their existing value chains. The exceptions are organizations that currently profit from securing the transfer of value: For them, blockchain represents a threat to their margins. For example, in the absence of added-value services, key components of payment networks can be commodified using distributed ledgers.

Changes in the cost of networking — although they will take longer to unfold — are more likely to be substantial. The ability to bootstrap a marketplace without the need for a central actor constitutes a radical departure from how most organizations appropriate value within their ecosystem today. Cryptocurrencies enable a hybrid type of organization that can take advantage of both the efficiency of a market and the more complex forms of contracting and governance that take place within firms or on online platforms. By sourcing capital, talent, and ideas through smart contracts, such organizations will be possibly able to move and allocate resources at a speed previously unimaginable. Many of the online platforms that rely today on their ability to process payments between buyers and sellers, and on controlling a reputation system (e.g., Uber, Airbnb) may face increased competition from open protocols that source resources and allocate returns in a more flexible way.

Early experiments in this space include startups like Numerai, a hedge fund that makes investment decisions based on the crowdsourced predictions generated by a distributed network of data scientists. The data scientists rely on a cryptocurrency to both disclose their confidence in their models and appropriate the returns from their contributions. Additionally, a smart contract ensures that participants do not have an incentive to overfit their data, as rewards are linked to the long-run ability of the hedge fund to make good investment decisions.

Who — which people, which functions — within the organization should be leading the investigation of blockchain?

Early on, the ideal team would probably include the CEO, chief technology officer, chief economist, and some of the key people directly reporting to them. The objective would be to map the idiosyncratic opportunities and challenges cryptocurrencies and blockchain pose for the company, and create the right platform for small, cross-functional, entrepreneurial teams to explore novel applications further. In many of these cases, projects will be early stage, high risk, and require collaboration outside the boundaries of the firm. Ideally, they would also receive enough autonomy to explore business models that are potentially inconsistent with how the organization currently operates and secures revenues, or at least receive enough funding to make strategic investment decisions in relevant startups.


Paul Michelman is editor in chief of MIT Sloan Management Review. He tweets @pmichelman on Twitter. Christian Catalini tweets at @ccatilini.


Reprint 58417.

For ordering information, visit our FAQ page. Copyright © Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 2017. All rights reserved.

..................Content has been hidden....................

You can't read the all page of ebook, please click here login for view all page.
Reset
18.221.239.148