Chapter 9
Power, Conflict, and Coalition

The captain had the flu and was coughing repeatedly before he boarded the plane. The copilot had been called at 4 a.m. to work a flight that was departing in less than two hours (Suhartono and Ramzy, 2019). Both pilots were highly experienced, but the copilot's training record was spotty, with a tendency to rigidify under stress and instances of marginal aircraft control (KNKT, 2018). Neither pilot knew that the crew on the aircraft the previous day had struggled with control problems, nor that those problems were symptoms of a potentially fatal design flaw (Suhartono and Ramzy, 2019).

 

The crew of Lion Air Flight 610 left Jakarta on October 29, 2018, flying an almost‐new Boeing 737 MAX. Takeoff was uneventful, and flying conditions were excellent. But things soon went downhill. The captain's and copilot's indicators for airspeed and altitude were giving discrepant readings, making it hard for the crew to know how high they were and how fast they were going (KNKT, 2018). The conflicting information created stress and confusion, factors that increase pilot errors (Ruffell Smith, 1979). Then things got worse. An automatic system known as MCAS (Maneuvering Characteristics Augmentation System) began to override the crew's control of the aircraft by pushing the nose of the plane down. MCAS was supposed to be a safety feature to protect against stall if the aircraft pitched up too steeply.1 Fatally, it relied on only one sensor. That sensor was misreading the plane's “angle of attack,” and began to battle the crew for control of the plane. MCAS kept pushing the nose down, and the crew fought to pull it back up. After only 13 minutes in the air, the plane crashed into the sea, killing all 189 persons on board.

In the aftermath, critics suggested that the 737 MAX had serious design flaws, but a Boeing spokesman offered standard corporate pablum, insisting that “We are confident in the safety of the 737 MAX. Safety remains our top priority and is a core value for everyone at Boeing” (Fox, 2018). The Federal Aviation Administration (FAA) sided with Boeing and allowed the plane to keep flying, even though an internal FAA memorandum predicted more accidents unless MCAS was fixed (Marsh and Wallace, 2019). The FAA settled instead on an emergency bulletin instructing pilots on how to disable MCAS. Boeing and the FAA both hoped the problem was solved. Those hopes were dashed five months later in March, 2019, when another 737 MAX, Ethiopian Airlines Flight 310, crashed only 6 minutes after takeoff. The pilots on that flight fought the same battle with MCAS. They tried to follow the updated advice from Boeing, but still lost control of the plane. All 149 passengers and eight crew members perished.

After the second accident, every 737 MAX in the world was grounded for more than a year, and the search was on to determine how two brand‐new, state‐of‐the‐art planes could crash in five months. When answers eventually came, they told a familiar tale. A combination of mismanagement, myopia, and political maneuvering had produced almost 350 deaths and a multibillion‐dollar loss for Boeing. It all began with management's fixation on getting the plane out as swiftly as possible to compete with the new A320neo from Airbus, which was already on the market and beginning to grab market share. The pressure intensified when one of Boeing's biggest customers, American Airlines, threatened to start buying from Airbus (Gelles, Kitroeff, Nicas, and Ruiz, 2019). In the rush to shave time and costs, the design for MCAS was changed to rely on only one sensor instead of two. Whistleblowing engineers at Boeing tried to warn management that relentless pressure, long hours, and corner‐cutting were creating risks to the plane's safety (Marsh and Wallace, 2019). But, as often is the case in such high visibility accidents, their concerns were discounted.

In its rush to market, Boeing had insisted to both customers and the FAA that the MAX was so similar to previous iterations of the 737 that pilots could transition immediately to the new plane with no additional training. That claim was disingenuous at best. MCAS was added to the MAX because the plane's new engines forced changes in wing structure that created a greater risk of pitching up. But “Boeing deliberately played down the details of the flight control system that later helped bring down two 737 MAX jets so that the Federal Aviation Administration (FAA), responsible for certifying the new system, entirely missed its significance and danger” (Gates, 2020). Boeing also chose to omit mention of MCAS from the training manuals for 737 MAX pilots. The assumption was that the system would take care of itself, deploying rarely and only when needed.

A congressional report in 2020 was scathing, concluding that a culture of concealment at Boeing, augmented by fundamental flaws in the regulatory system, had led to disaster.

Boeing's management prioritized the company's profitability and stock price over everything else, including passenger safety. Perhaps even more alarmingly, the F.A.A., which once had a sterling reputation for independence and integrity, acted as a virtual agent for the company it was supposed to be overseeing. (Cassidy, 2020)

In short, management self‐interest and political infighting brought down the MAX. The story has eerie similarities to an earlier American tragedy. Flash back to 1986. After a series of delays, the Space Shuttle Challenger was set to launch on January 28. At sunrise, it was clear but extremely cold at Cape Canaveral, Florida. The weather felt more like New Hampshire, where Christa McAuliffe, one of the crew, was a high school teacher. Curtains of ice greeted ground crews as they inspected the shuttle. The temperature had plunged overnight to a record low of 24 degrees Fahrenheit (–4 degrees Celsius). Temperatures gradually warmed, but it was still brisk at 8:30 a.m. Challenger's crew of seven astronauts noted the ice as they climbed into the capsule. As McAuliffe, the first teacher to venture into space, entered the ship, a technician offered her an apple. She beamed and asked him to save it until she returned. At 11:38 a.m., Challenger lifted off. A minute later, there was a massive explosion in the booster rockets. Millions watched their television screens in horror as the shuttle and its crew plummeted to the sea.

On the eve of the launch, an emergency teleconference had been called between NASA and the Morton Thiokol Corporation, the contractor for the shuttle's solid‐fuel rocket motor. During the teleconference, Thiokol engineers pleaded with superiors and NASA to delay the launch. They feared cold temperatures would cause a failure in synthetic rubber O‐rings sealing the rocket motor's joints. If the rings failed, the motor could blow up. The problem was simple and familiar: rubber loses elasticity at cold temperatures. Freeze a rubber ball and it won't bounce; freeze an O‐ring and it might not seal. Engineers recommended strongly that NASA wait for warmer weather. They tried to produce a persuasive engineering rationale, but their report was hastily thrown together, and the data seemed equivocal (Vaughan, 1995). The battle was uphill because Thiokol and NASA both faced strong pressure to get the shuttle in the air. Thiokol had gained its lucrative sole source contract thirteen years earlier with substantial help from insiders in Utah's tightly knit political hierarchy. “By summer 1985, however, Thiokol's monopoly was under attack, and the corporation's executives were reluctant to risk their billion‐dollar contract by halting shuttle flight operations long enough to correct flaws in the booster joint design” (McConnell, 1987, p. 7).

Meanwhile, NASA managers were experiencing their own political pressures. As part of the effort to build congressional support for the space program, NASA had promised that the shuttle would pay for itself in cargo fees, like a boxcar in space. Projections of profitability were based on an ambitious plan calling for more than a dozen flights a year, but NASA had fallen well behind schedule—only five launches in 1984 and eight in 1985. The promise of “routine access to space” and self‐supporting flights looked more and more dubious. With every flight costing taxpayers about $100 million, NASA needed a lot of cash from Congress, but prospects were dimming. NASA's credibility was eroding as the U.S. budget deficit soared.

Such was the highly charged context in which Thiokol's engineers recommended canceling the next morning's launch. The response from NASA officials was swift and pointed. One NASA manager said he was “appalled” at the proposal, and another said, “My God, Thiokol, when do you want me to launch? Next April?” (McConnell, 1987, p. 196). Senior managers at Thiokol huddled and decided, against the advice of engineers, to recommend the launch. NASA accepted the recommendation and launched Flight 51‐L. It, along with its human crew, was destroyed in a tremendous fire ball (Bell and Esch, 1987; Jensen, 1995; McConnell, 1987; Marx, Stubbart, Traub, and Cavanaugh, 1987; Vaughan, 1990, 1995).

It is deeply disturbing to see political agenda corrupting technical decisions, particularly when precious lives are at stake. It is tempting to explain the 737 MAX or Challenger stories by blaming individual selfishness and questionable motives. But such explanations are little help in understanding what happened or in avoiding future catastrophes. Individual errors typically occur downstream from powerful forces channeling decision makers over a precipice no one sees until too late. With both 737 MAX and Challenger, key decision makers were experienced, highly trained, and intelligent. If we tried to get better people, where would we find them? Even if we could, how could we ensure that parochial interests and political pressures would not ensnare them?

Both 737 MAX and Challenger were extraordinary tragedies, but they illustrate political dynamics that are everyday features of organizational life. The political frame does not blame politics on individual foibles such as selfishness, myopia, or incompetence. Instead, it proposes that interdependence, divergent interests, scarcity, and power relations inevitably spawn political activity. It is naïve and romantic to hope organizational politics can be eliminated, regardless of individual players. Managers can, however, learn to acknowledge, understand, and manage political dynamics rather than fearing them or being overrun by them.

This chapter seeks to explain why political processes are universal, why they won't go away, and how to handle them adroitly. We first describe the political frame's basic assumptions and explain how they work. Next, we depict organizations as freewheeling coalitions or open polities (Cyert and March, 1963; Waeger and Weber, 2019; Zhang and Greve, 2019) rather than as formal hierarchies. Coalitions are tools for exercising power; we contrast power with authority and highlight tensions between authorities (who try to keep things under control) and partisans (who try to influence a system to get what they want). We also delineate multiple sources of power. Because conflict is normal among members of a coalition, we underscore the role it plays in and across organizations. Finally, we discuss an issue at the heart of organizational politics: Do political dynamics inevitably undermine moral principles and ethics?

POLITICAL ASSUMPTIONS

The political frame views organizations as roiling arenas that host ongoing contests arising from individual and group interests. Five propositions summarize the perspective:

  1. Organizations are coalitions of different individuals and interest groups.
  2. Coalition members have enduring differences in values, beliefs, information, interests, resources, and perceptions of reality.
  3. Most important decisions involve allocating scarce resources—deciding who gets what.
  4. Scarce resources and enduring differences put conflict at the center of day‐to‐day dynamics and make power the most important asset.
  5. Goals and decisions emerge from bargaining and negotiation among competing stakeholders jockeying for their respective interests.

Political Propositions, 737 MAX and Challenger

All five propositions of the political frame came into play in both the 737 MAX and Challenger incidents:

  1. Organizations are coalitions. Both Boeing and NASA housed internal coalitions (such as engineers and senior management) and operated in the context of larger coalitions. Boeing was part of a global ecosystem that included suppliers, customers, and government regulators. NASA was part of a complex coalition of contractors, Congress, the White House, the military, the media—even the American public. Consider, for example, why Christa McAuliffe was aboard. Her expertise as a teacher was not critical to the mission. But the American public was getting bored with white male pilots in space. Moreover, as a teacher, McAuliffe represented a national commitment to universal education. Human interest was good for NASA and Congress; it built public support for the space program. McAuliffe's participation was a media magnet because it was a great human‐interest story. Symbolically, Christa McAuliffe represented all Americans; everyone flew with her.
  2. Coalition members have enduring differences. Boeing's emphasis on reducing time, costs, and complexity conflicted with the FAA's responsibility for flight safety. NASA's hunger for funding competed with the public's interest in lower taxes. Pilots' concerns for safety were at odds with pressures on Boeing and NASA to move quickly
  3. Important decisions involve allocating scarce resources. In both cases, time and money were in short supply. Delay carried a high price—not just in dollars but also in further erosion of support from key constituents. Boeing feared falling behind Airbus in a critical segment of the market. In both cases, senior managers overruled engineers in the rush to keep their customers satisfied.
  4. Scarce resources and enduring differences make conflict central and power the most important asset. The teleconference on the eve of the Challenger launch began as a debate between the contractor and NASA. As sole customer, NASA was in the driver's seat. When managers at Morton Thiokol sensed NASA's level of disappointment and frustration, the scene shifted to a tense standoff between engineers and managers. Managers relied on their authority to override the engineers' technical expertise and make decisions based more on business than technical concerns.
  5. Goals and decisions emerge from bargaining, negotiation, and jockeying for position among competing stakeholders. The FAA is a huge agency with conflicting responsibilities both to promote the airline industry and to keep the skies safe, as exemplified in the FAA's decision not to ground the MAX after the first fatal accident. Boeing is a huge company and a powerful political player in its own right. The FAA has a budget of more than $15 billion a year, but has often been hampered by marginal, stopgap funding. Short on personnel, it had delegated some of its oversight responsibilities to the industries it regulates, including Boeing in the case of the 737 MAX. Similarly, political bargaining and powerful allies had propelled Morton Thiokol into the rocket motor business. Thiokol's engineers had been attempting to focus management's attention on the booster joint problem for many months. But management feared that acknowledging a problem, in addition to costing time and money, would erode the company's credibility. For both Boeing and Thiokol, a very large business was at stake.

Implications of the Political Propositions

The assumptions of the political frame explain that organizations are inevitably political. A coalition forms because its members need each other, even though their interests may only partly overlap. The assumption of enduring differences implies that political activity is more visible and dominant under conditions of diversity than of homogeneity. Agreement and harmony are easier to achieve when everyone shares similar values, beliefs, and cultural ways. Very often, that's not the case.

The concept of scarce resources suggests that politics will be more salient and intense in difficult times. Schools and colleges, for example, have lived through alternating eras of feast and famine related to peaks and valleys in economic and demographic trends. When money and students are plentiful (as they were in the 1960s and again in the 1990s), administrators spend time designing new buildings and initiating innovative programs. Work is fun when you're delivering good news and constituents applaud. Conversely, when resources dry up, you may have to shutter buildings, close programs, and lay off staff. In the run‐up to Fall 2020, the pandemic created a painful dilemma for leaders in colleges and universities. They risked spikes in Covid‐19 infections if they brought students to campus, but huge splashes of red ink if they did not. Conflict mushroomed on many campuses where administrators mandated faculty to return to the classroom, and professors concerned about their health fought back.

Differences and scarce resources make power a key resource. Power in organizations is basically the capacity to make things happen and affect outcomes (Ocasio, Pozner, and Milner, 2020). Pfeffer defines power as “the potential ability to influence behavior, to change the course of events, to overcome resistance, and to get people to do things they would not otherwise do” (1992, p. 30). Social scientists often emphasize a tight linkage between power and dependency: if A has something B wants, A has leverage. In much of organizational life, individuals and groups are interdependent; they need things from one another, and power relationships are multidirectional. From the view of the political frame, power is a “daily mechanism of our social existence” (Crozier and Friedberg, 1977, p. 32).

The final proposition of the political frame emphasizes that goals are not set by edict at the top but evolve through an ongoing process of negotiation and bargaining. Few organizations have a unitary apex. Who, for example, is at the head of a public company? The CEO? This is the structural view, but the CEO reports to the board. The board, in turn, is elected by and accountable to shareholders. And the shareholders are often a large and scattered group of absentee owners. They have little time, interest, or capacity to influence the organization in which each has a sliver of ownership. But if a corporate raider or a hedge fund acquires a major ownership stake, the stage is set for a contest for control of the company.

This political view of organization might seem strange in light of traditional assumptions of control from the top. Yet the same dynamics of conflict, coalitions, and power are found at every level of human affairs. Mann (1986, 2013) tells us that's how society works. Society is not a cohesive unit but is “constituted of multiple, overlapping and intersecting networks of power” (Mann, 1986, p. 1). David Eagleman says that the same is true of the human brain. He presents data from psychology and neuroscience to show that almost all of our mental activity takes place outside awareness. Here's what he says is going on politically inside your brain:

Small groups are constantly making decisions and sending out messages to other groups. Out of these local interactions, emerge larger coalitions. By the time you read a mental headline, the important action has already transpired, the deals are done. You have surprisingly little access to what happened behind the scenes. Entire political movements gain ground‐up support and become unstoppable movements before you ever catch wind of them as a feeling or intuition or thought that strikes you. You're the last one on the chain of command to hear the information. (Eagleman, 2011, p. 6)

Multiple constituents jockey for influence at every level, from the individual brain to global society. This is especially apparent in the public sector. When Xi Jinping came to power as head of China's Communist Party in November 2012, his first public speech made no mention of Marx or Mao but emphasized the need to solve the problem of “corruption [and] being out of touch with the people” (Demick, 2012). Xi understood that corruption represented a potentially fatal threat to the party's continued dominance. But the party elite he hoped to influence included more than 80 billionaires (Anderlini, 2013; van Kerckhove, 2013), perhaps the largest concentration of wealth the world has ever seen.

Those superrich included both successful entrepreneurs and members of the so‐called black‐collar class, Communist officials whose sway over business created opportunities to trade power for cash. Xi knew that something had to be done about rampant corruption, but he was up against formidable opposition from party and government officials who were in no hurry to change a system that was making them and their families rich. When Xi launched a new austerity campaign in 2013, ordering the elite to cut back on lavish banquets and similar luxuries, a new catchphrase became popular in Chinese officialdom, “Eat quietly, take gently and play secretly” (Jacobs, 2013).

The challenges Xi faced in fighting corruption mirrored those that had hindered China's efforts for more than a decade to protect intellectual property. When it joined the World Trade Organization in 2001, the Chinese government promised to get serious about ensuring that products carrying brands such as Coca‐Cola, Microsoft, Sony, and Rolex were authentic. The central government passed laws, threw the book at the occasional unlucky offender, blustered in the media, and put pressure on local governments. Yet 15 years later, name‐brand knockoffs and pirated music continued to be sold all over China, and Western tourists in Beijing still encountered a steady stream of vendors offering “Rolex” watches at amazing prices (Powell, 2007).

Why have the anti‐piracy efforts had limited impact? The Chinese government is far from monolithic and is only one of many players in a complex power game. Norton (2013) argues that Chinese bureaucracy operates less like a top‐down hierarchy and more like a series of concentric circles in which multiple players are involved in every significant decision. Newly affluent Chinese consumers often put a high value on foreign brands, and in 2019 products from abroad for the first time grew faster than domestic ones (Lannes and Deng, 2020). Businesses understand that a homemade carbonated fluid can fetch a better price if it carries a foreign brand name. The problem has been so widespread that Coca‐Cola's Chinese affiliate found itself not only raiding factories but also chasing pirates who slapped Coke labels on bottles in delivery trucks while on route to retail outlets.

Pirates are often local businesses with plenty of guanxi (connections) who share the loot with local government and police officials. As one New York Times reporter discovered when he was imprisoned for several hours in a toy factory, “Factory bosses can overrule the police, and Chinese government officials are not as powerful as you might suspect” (Barboza, 2007, pp. 4–3). Moreover, the concept of intellectual property rights is new to many Chinese. They find it hard to see the merit of punishing a hard‐working Chinese entrepreneur in order to protect a foreign corporation. In short, divergent interests and multiple power centers have limited officials' ability to translate intention into action.

ORGANIZATIONS AS COALITIONS

Academics and managers alike have often assumed that organizations have, or ought to have, clear and consistent goals set at the top. In a business, the owners or top managers set goals such as growth and profitability. Goals in a government agency are presumably set by the legislature and elected executives. The political frame challenges such views. Cyert and March articulate the difference between structural and political views of goals:

To what extent is it arbitrary, in conventional accounting, that we call wage payments “costs” and dividend payments “profit” rather than the other way around? Why is it that in our quasigenetic moments we are inclined to say that in the beginning there was a manager, and he recruited workers and capital? … The emphasis on the asymmetry has seriously confused the understanding of organizational goals. The confusion arises because ultimately it makes only slightly more sense to say that the goal of a business enterprise is to maximize profit than to say that its goal is to maximize the salary of Sam Smith, assistant to the janitor. (1963, p. 30)

Cyert and March are saying something like this: Sam Smith, the assistant janitor; Jim Ford, the foreman; and Celestine Cohen‐Peters, the company president are all members of a grand coalition, Cohen‐Peters Enterprises. All make demands on resources and bargain to get what they want. Cohen‐Peters has more authority than Smith or Ford and, in case of disagreement, she will often win—but not always. Her influence depends on how much power she mobilizes in comparison with that of Smith, Ford, and other members of the coalition. Xerox had a close brush with bankruptcy in 2001 under a CEO who had come from the outside and never mastered the politics at the top of the organization. The firm was adrift, and the captain lost control of his ship. His successor, Anne Mulcahy, was a canny insider who built the relationships and alliances she needed to get Xerox back on course.

If political pressures on goals are visible in the private sector, they are blatant in the public arena. As in the Challenger incident, public agencies operate amid a welter of constituencies, each making demands and trying to get its way. The result is a confusing multiplicity of goals, many in conflict. Consider Gazprom, Russia's biggest company and the world's largest producer of natural gas. Gazprom supplied almost 40 percent of Europe's natural gas in 2018. It began as a state ministry under Mikhail Gorbachev, became a public stock company under Boris Yeltsin, and then turned semi‐public under Vladimir Putin, with the Russian government the majority stockholder.

Many observers felt that Gazprom functioned as an extension of government policy. Prices for gas exports seemed to correlate with how friendly a government was to Moscow. “If people take us for the state, that doesn't make us unhappy,” said Sergey Kouprianov, a company spokesman. “We identify with the state” (Pasquier and Chevelkina, 2007, p. 43). Russian President Vladimir Putin returned the sentiment. Gazprom produced a quarter of Russia's government revenues, and Putin saw hydrocarbons substituting for the Red Army as a lever to project Russian power. At the same time, Russian consumers got their gas at about 20 percent of market price. When the company tried for a domestic price increase in 2006, it was blocked by a government that was thinking ahead to the next presidential election. Was this giant in business to benefit customers, management, stockholders, the Kremlin, or Russian citizens? All of the above and more, because all were participants in the grand and messy Gazprom coalition.

POWER AND DECISION MAKING

At every level in organizations, alliances form because members have interests in common and believe they can do more together than apart. To accomplish their aims, they need power. Power can be viewed from multiple perspectives. Structural theorists typically emphasize authority, the legitimate prerogative to make binding decisions. In this view, managers make rational decisions (optimal and consistent with purpose), monitor to ensure that decisions are implemented, and assess how well subordinates carry out directives. In contrast, human resource theorists place less emphasis on power and more on empowerment (Bennis and Nanus, 1985; Block, 1987). More than structuralists, they emphasize limits of authority and tend to focus on influence that enhances mutuality and collaboration. The implicit hope is that participation, openness, and collaboration substitute for sheer power.

The political frame views authority as only one among many forms of power. It recognizes the importance of individual (and group) needs but emphasizes that scarce resources and incompatible preferences cause needs to collide. Politically, the issue is how competing groups articulate preferences and mobilize power to get what they want. Power, in this view, is not evil: “We have to stop describing power always in negative terms: [as in] it excludes, it represses. In fact, power produces; it produces reality” (Foucault, 1975, p. 12).

Authorities and Partisans

Gamson (1968) describes the relationship between two antagonists—partisans and authorities—that are often central to the politics of both organizations and society. By virtue of the office they hold, authorities are entitled to make decisions binding on their subordinates. Any member of a coalition who wants to exert bottom‐up pressure is a potential partisan. Gamson describes the relationship in this way: “Authorities are the recipients or targets of influence, and the agents or initiators of social control. Potential partisans have the opposite roles—as agents or initiators of influence, and targets or recipients of social control” (p. 76).

In a family, parents function as authorities and children as partisans. Parents initiate social control, making binding decisions about bedtime, television viewing, or cell phone use. As the recipients of parental decisions, children in turn try to influence the decision makers. They argue for a later bedtime or point out the injustice of giving one child something another wants. They try to split authorities by lobbying one parent after the other has refused. They may form a coalition (with siblings, grandparents, and so on) in an attempt to strengthen their bargaining position.

Authority is essential to anyone in a formal position because social control depends on it. Officeholders can exert control only so long as partisans respect or fear them enough that their authority or power remains intact. If partisans are convinced that existing authorities are too evil or incompetent to continue, they will risk trying to wrest control—unless they regard the authorities as too formidable. Conversely, if partisans trust authority and see it as legitimate, they will accept and support it in the event of an attack (Baldridge, 1971; Gamson, 1968). In almost any instance of unrest or revolution, there is a sharp cleavage between rebels and loyalists.

If partisan opposition becomes too powerful, authority systems may collapse. The process can be very swift, as illustrated by events in China and Eastern Europe in 1989 and the Arab Spring of 2011–2013. In both cases, established regimes had lost legitimacy years earlier but held on through coercion and control of access to decision making. When massive demonstrations erupted, authorities faced an unnerving choice: activate the police and army in the hope of preserving power or watch their authority fade away. Authorities in China and Romania in 1989, Libya in 2011, and Egypt and Syria in 2012, chose the first course. It led to bloodshed in every case, but only the Chinese were able to quash their opposition quickly. Elsewhere, authorities' attempts to quell dissent with force were futile, and their legitimacy evaporated.

The period of evaporation is typically heady but always hazardous. When the old regime collapses, the question is whether new authority can reconstitute itself quickly enough to avoid chaos. Authorities and partisans both have reason to fear a specter such as Bosnia and Liberia in the 1990s, Somalia for much of the last three decades, Iraq in the aftermath of U.S. intervention, or Libya and Syria since the Arab Spring of 2011. All are tragic examples of chronic turmoil and misery, with no authority strong enough to bring partisan strife under control.

Sources of Power

Authorities and partisans both have many potential sources of power. A number of social scientists (Baldridge, 1971; French and Raven, 1959; Kanter, 1977; Mann, 1986; Pfeffer, 1981, 1992; Russ, 1994) have tried to identify the various wellsprings of power. Ocasio, Pozner, and Milner (2020) conceptualize power as arising from different forms of political capital, including cultural, economic, institutional, knowledge, organizational, reputational, social, and symbolic. Those forms roughly parallel our list of major types of power in organizations:

  • Position power (authority): Positions confer certain levels of legitimate authority. Professors assign grades; judges settle disputes. Positions also place incumbents in more or less powerful locations in communications and power networks. It is as helpful to be in the right unit as it is to hold the right job. A lofty title in a backwater department may not carry much weight, but junior members of a powerful unit may have substantial clout (Pfeffer, 1992).
  • Control of rewards: The ability to deliver jobs, money, political support, or other rewards brings power. Political bosses and tribal chiefs, among others, cement their power base by delivering services and jobs to loyal supporters (Mihalopoulos and Kimberly, 2006).
  • Coercive power: Coercive power rests on the ability to constrain, block, interfere, or punish. A union's ability to walk out, students' capacity to sit in, and an army's ability to clamp down exemplify coercive power. A chilling example is the rise of suicide attacks in recent decades from about three a year worldwide in the 1980s to about one a day in 2016 (Chicago Project on Security and Terrorism, 2016). They were only about 3 percent of terror incidents but accounted for almost half the fatalities (Pape, 2006, p. 4).
  • Information and expertise: Power flows to those with the information and know‐how to solve important problems. It flows to marketing experts in consumer products industries, to the faculty in elite universities, and to political consultants who can help politicians get elected.
  • Reputation: Reputation builds on expertise. In almost any field, people develop records of accomplishment based on their prior performance. Opportunities and influence flow to people with strong reputations, like the Hollywood superstars whose presence in a film sells tickets. Boivie, Graffin, and Gentry (2016) found that the reputation of the analyst, the CEO, and the firm all influenced how a firm's stock price changed in response to buy or sell recommendations from Wall Street analysts.
  • Alliances and networks: Getting things done in an organization involves working through a complex network of individuals and groups. Friends and allies make things a lot easier. Kotter (1982) found that a key difference between more and less successful senior managers was attentiveness to building and cultivating ties with friends and allies. Managers who spent too little time building networks had much more difficulty getting things done.
  • Access and control of agenda: Organizations and political systems typically give some individuals and groups more access than others to decision arenas. When decisions are made, the interests of those with “a seat at the table” are well represented, while the concerns of absentees are often distorted or ignored (Brown, 1986; Lukes, 1974). Access may come at a price. Shani and Westphal (2016) found that journalists who wrote negative stories about a firm's leadership soon found that CEOs from other firms stopped taking their calls. Because the journalists needed access to do their jobs, they tilted toward more flattering articles about corporate leaders.
  • Framing: Control of meaning and symbols is what Mann (1986, 2013) refers to as ideological power. “Establishing the framework within which issues will be viewed and decided is often tantamount to determining the result” (Pfeffer, 1992, p. 203). Elites and opinion leaders often have substantial ability to shape meaning and articulate myths that express identity, beliefs, and values. Viewed positively, this fosters meaning and hope. Viewed cynically, elites can convince others to accept and support things not in their best interests (Brown, 1986; Lakoff, 2004). Lakoff argued that Republican electoral success in 2000 and 2004 owed much to skill in framing issues—recasting, for example, the “estate tax” (which sounds like a tax on the rich) into the “death tax” (which sounds like adding insult to injury).
  • Personal power: Individuals who are attractive and socially adept—because of charisma, energy, stamina, political smarts, gift of gab, vision, or other characteristics—are imbued with power independent of other sources. French and Raven (1959) used the term referent power to describe influence that comes when people like you or want to be like you. John Kennedy and Ronald Reagan expanded their influence because they brought levels of charm, humor, and ease that Jimmy Carter and George W. Bush lacked.

A significant form of personal power is skill in the application of influence tactics. After reviewing research on persuasion, Cialdini (2008, 2016) developed a list of six techniques that skilled practitioners use to influence others, often without the targets realizing how they have been hooked:

  1. Reciprocation: If I do something for you (send you a card, give you a small gift, or make some effort on your behalf), you're likely to feel you should do something for me as well.
  2. Commitment and consistency: If I can get you to take a small step in my direction (maybe getting you to agree that you see at least some positive features in the product or idea I'm selling), I can leverage your desire to be consistent and to live up to your commitments.
  3. Social proof: If I offer evidence that everyone (at least everyone you like) is doing it, you're more likely to do it as well. Bars and cafes often salt the tip jar with cash to cue you that tipping is what people do. Sport and film stars might have no more product knowledge than you do, but you may still want the shoes they wear or the cosmetic they use.
  4. Liking: The more you like me (perhaps because I tell you how much I like you, or how well you'll do on this task, or how much we have in common), the better the chance you'll do what I ask.
  5. Authority: If the boss, or someone with a badge or a fancy title, asks you to do it, you probably will.
  6. Scarcity: We put a higher value on something that is scarce or about to become unavailable. (If I can convince you that the price is going up, there are only a few items left, what you want is very rare, or this is your last chance, you're more likely to buy.)

Partisans' multiple sources of power are always a constraint on authorities' capacity to make binding decisions. Officeholders who rely solely on position power generate resistance and get outflanked, outmaneuvered, or overrun by others more versatile in exercising multiple forms of power. Kotter (1985) argues that managerial jobs come with a built‐in “power gap” because position power is rarely enough to get the job done. Expertise, rewards, coercion, allies, access, reputation, framing, and personal power help close the gap.

Power can be volatile, rising and falling with changes in circumstances. An organization that sets new profit records each year is rarely besieged by complaints and demands for change. As many corporate leaders have learned, however, the first bad quarter triggers a stream of calls and letters from board members, stockholders, and financial analysts. In the boom of the late 1990s, “everyone” was getting rich in the stock market, and charismatic CEOs such as Jack Welch of General Electric and Jean‐Marie Messier of France's Vivendi became popular heroes. But when the economy, the market, and the image of business crashed in the first years of the new century, so did these heroic images. In 2002, Welch found himself deeply embarrassed by public revelation of the generous postretirement payouts his old company was bestowing on him. In the same year, Messier was booted out by board members dissatisfied with the company's stock price and his arrogant “American” leadership style.

Clark Kerr once remarked ruefully that his primary tasks as chancellor of the University of California at Berkeley seemed to be providing “sex for the students, parking for the faculty, and football for the alumni.” The remark was half‐facetious, but it reflects an important grain of truth: a president's power lies particularly in zones of indifference—areas only a few people care much about. The zone of indifference can expand or contract markedly, depending on how an organization is performing in the eyes of its major constituents. In the late 1960s, many college presidents lost their jobs because they were blamed for student unrest. Among them was Kerr, who remarked that he left the job just as he entered it, “fired with enthusiasm.” Managers need to track shifting boundaries of zones of indifference so as not to blunder into decisions that stir up unanticipated firestorms of criticism and resistance.

Distribution of Power: Overbounded and Underbounded Systems

Organizations and societies differ markedly in how power is distributed. Alderfer (1979) and Brown (1983) distinguish between overbounded and underbounded systems. In an overbounded system, power is highly concentrated and everything is tightly regulated. In an underbounded system, power is diffuse and the system is very loosely controlled. An overbounded system regulates politics with a firm hand; an underbounded system encourages conflict and power games.

If power is highly regulated, political activity is often forced under wraps. Before the emergence of Mikhail Gorbachev and glasnost (“openness”) in the 1980s, it was common for Westerners to view the Soviets as a vast, amorphous mass of like‐minded people, brainwashed by decades of government propaganda. It was not true, but even so‐called experts on Soviet affairs misread the underlying reality (Alterman, 1989). Ethnic, political, philosophical, and religious differences simmered quietly underground so long as the Kremlin maintained a tightly regulated society. Glasnost took the lid off, leading to an outpouring of debate and dissent that rapidly caused the collapse of the old order in the Soviet Union and throughout Eastern Europe. Almost overnight, much of Eastern Europe went from overbounded to underbounded. Most nations in Eastern Europe have since evolved into stable democracies, but many other countries have been less fortunate.

The war in Iraq, beginning in 2003, brought down the overbounded Saddam Hussein regime and created a power vacuum that attracted a host of contenders vying for supremacy. By 2006, Iraq had the formal elements of a new government, including a constitution and an elected parliament, but Iraq has struggled ever since to bring conflict and chaos under control. The Arab Spring, which began with unrest in Tunisia in 2010, brought unrest and revolt to many countries in the Middle East and North Africa, including Libya, Egypt, Syria, Bahrain, and Yemen. Fear of a similar fate drives the leaders of China's ruling Communist Party to mount an ongoing, massive effort to stem the tides of criticism and dissent welling up from China's nearly one billion Internet users.

CONFLICT IN ORGANIZATIONS

From a political perspective, conflict is not necessarily a problem or a sign that something is amiss. Organizational resources are in short supply; there is rarely enough to give everyone everything they want. Individuals compete for jobs, titles, and prestige. Departments compete for resources and power. Interest groups vie for policy concessions. If one group controls the policy process, others may be frozen out. Conflict is normal and inevitable. It's a natural by‐product of collective life.

The political prism puts more emphasis on strategy and tactics than on resolution of conflict. Conflict has benefits as well as costs:

A tranquil, harmonious organization may very well be an apathetic, uncreative, stagnant, inflexible, and unresponsive organization. Conflict challenges the status quo [and] stimulates interest and curiosity. It is the root of personal and social change, creativity, and innovation. Conflict encourages new ideas and approaches to problems, stimulating innovation. (Heffron, 1989, p. 185)

An organization can experience too much or too little conflict (Brown, 1983; Heffron, 1989; Jehn, 1995). Leaders may need to tamp down or stoke up the intensity, depending on the situation (Bolman and Deal, 2006; Heifetz and Linsky, 2002). More important than the amount of conflict is how it is managed. Poorly managed conflict leads to infighting and destructive power struggles. Well‐handled conflict, on the other hand, can stimulate creativity and innovation that make an organization a livelier, more adaptive, and more effective place (Kotter, 1985).

Conflict is particularly likely to occur at boundaries, or interfaces, between groups and units. Horizontal conflict occurs in the boundary between departments or divisions; vertical conflict occurs at the border between levels. Cultural conflict crops up between groups with differing values, traditions, beliefs, and lifestyles. Cultural quarrels in the larger society often seep into the workplace, generating tension around gender, ethnic, racial, and other differences.

But organizations also house their own value disputes. The world of management is different from that of frontline employees. Workers who move up the ladder sometimes struggle with elusive adjustments required by their new role. A classic article described foremen as both “master and victim of doubletalk” (Roethlisberger, 1945) because of the pressures they felt from above to side with management, and from below to think and talk like a worker.

The management challenge is to recognize and manage interface conflict. Like other forms, it can be productive or debilitating. One of the most important tasks of unit managers or union representatives is to be a persuasive advocate for their group on a political field with many players representing competing interests. They need negotiation skills to develop alliances and cement deals that enable their group to move forward “without physical or psychological bloodshed and with wisdom as well as grace” (Peck, 1998, p. 71).

MORAL MAZES: THE POLITICS OF GETTING AHEAD

Does a world of power, self‐interest, conflict, and political games inevitably develop into a dog‐eat‐dog jungle in which the strong devour the weak and selfishness trumps everything else? Is an unregulated organization invariably a nasty, brutish place where values and ethics are irrelevant? The continuing corporate ethics scandals of recent years reinforce a recurrent suspicion that the morals of the marketplace amount to no morals at all.

Jackall (1988) views the corporation as a world of cabals and alliances, dominance and submission, conflict and self‐interest, and “moral mazes.” He suggests that “wise and ambitious managers resist the lulling platitudes of unity, though they invoke them with fervor, and look for the inevitable clash of interests beneath the bouncy, cheerful surface of corporate life” (p. 37). Moving up the ladder inevitably involves competition for the scarce resource of status. The favored myth is that free and fair competition ensures that, at least in the long run, better performers win.

But assessing performance in managerial work is fraught with ambiguity. There are multiple criteria, some of which can be assessed only through subjective judgment by the boss and others. It is often hard to separate individual performance from group performance or a host of other factors, including good or bad luck. It often makes a difference who is judging. Did Thiokol engineers who fought to stop the launch of Challenger deserve high grades for their persistence and integrity or low grades because they did not do a better job of persuading their bosses? When some of those same engineers went public with their criticism, were they demonstrating courage or disloyalty? Whistleblowers are regularly lauded by the press yet pilloried or banished by employers. This is exemplified by Time magazine’s 2002 Person of the Year award, given to three women who blew the whistle on their employers: Enron, WorldCom, and the FBI. By the time they received the award, all had moved on from workplaces that viewed them more as traitors than as exemplars of courage and integrity.

Managers frequently learn that getting ahead is a matter of personal “credibility,” which comes from doing what is socially and politically correct. Definitions of political correctness reflect tacit forms of power deeply embedded in organizational patterns and structure (Frost, 1986). Because getting ahead and making it to the top dominate the attention of many managers (Dalton, 1959; Jackall, 1988; Ritti and Funkhouser, 1982), both organizations and individuals need to develop constructive and positive ways to engage in the political game. The question is not whether organizations will have politics but rather what kind of politics they will have.

Jackall's view is bleak:

Bureaucracy breaks apart the ownership of property from its control, social independence from occupation, substance from appearances, action from responsibility, obligation from guilt, language from meaning, and notions of truth from reality. Most important, and at the bottom of all these fractures, it breaks apart the traditional connection between the meaning of work and salvation. In the bureaucratic world, one's success, one's sign of election, no longer depends on an inscrutable God, but on the capriciousness of one's superiors and the market; and one achieves economic salvation to the extent that one pleases and submits to new gods, that is, one's bosses and the exigencies of an impersonal market. (1988, pp. 191–192)

This is not a pretty picture, but it captures the experience of many managers. Productive politics is a possible alternative, although hard to achieve. In Chapter 10, we explore ways that managers can become constructive politicians.

CONCLUSION

Traditional views see organizations as created and controlled by legitimate authorities who set goals, design structure, hire and manage employees, and ensure pursuit of the right objectives. The political view depicts a different world. Organizations are coalitions composed of individuals and groups with enduring differences who live in a world of scarce resources. That puts power and conflict at the center of organizational decision making.

Authorities have position power, but they must vie with many other contenders for other forms of leverage. Different contenders bring distinct beliefs, values, and interests. They seek access to various forms of power and compete for their share of scarce resources in a finite organizational pie.

From a political perspective, goals, structure, and policies emerge from an ongoing flux of bargaining and negotiation among major interest groups. Sometimes legitimate authorities are the dominant members of the coalition, as is often true in small, owner‐managed organizations. Large corporations are often controlled by senior management rather than by stockholders or the board of directors. Government agencies may be controlled more by the permanent civil servants than by the political leaders at the top. The dominant group in a school district may be the teachers' union instead of the school board or the superintendent. In such cases, rationalists recoil because they see the wrong people setting the agenda. But the political view suggests that exercising power is a natural part of ongoing contests. Those who get and use power to their advantage will be winners.

There is no guarantee that those who gain power will use it wisely or justly. But power and politics are not inevitably demeaning and destructive. Constructive politics is a possibility—indeed, a necessary option if we are to create institutions and societies that are both just and efficient.

Note

  1. 1.  To be precise, MCAS works by rotating the horizontal tail (horizontal stabilizer) to push the tail up, forcing the nose down.
..................Content has been hidden....................

You can't read the all page of ebook, please click here login for view all page.
Reset
18.223.172.252