One

The Nature of Institutional Voids
in Emerging Markets

CONVENTIONAL WISDOM holds that the diffusion of skills, processes, and technologies throughout global markets is resulting in convergence; the gap between emerging economies and their more developed counterparts is quickly closing.1 This optimism has been bolstered by the development of high-tech global supply chains and the offshoring of professional services, but market transition and emergence often take more time than most decision makers anticipate. What is emerging in emerging markets is not only their forecast potential or liberalizing investment environments but also the institutional infrastructure needed to support their nascent market-oriented economies.

Institutional development is a complex and lengthy process shaped by a country’s history, political and social systems, and culture. Dismantling government intervention and reducing barriers to international trade and investment can spark market development, but they do not immediately produce well-functioning markets. The world may be becoming flatter, as columnist Thomas Friedman has argued, but the landscape of emerging markets, in particular, remains deeply striated by institutional legacies.2

Many observers of emerging markets are quick to recognize that, for them to be fully developed, it is important to create physical infrastructure—roads, bridges, telecommunication networks, water and sanitation facilities, and power plants. Without adequate physical infrastructure, it is hard for participants in product, labor, and capital markets to function effectively. However, less recognized is the importance of institutional development that underpins the functioning of mature markets.

The most important feature of any market is the ease with which buyers and sellers can come together to do business. In developed markets, a range of specialized intermediaries provides the requisite information and contract enforcement needed to consummate transactions. Most developing markets fall short on this count. Investors and companies quickly realize that these regions do not have the infrastructure, both physical and institutional, needed for the smooth functioning of markets. It is difficult for buyers and sellers to access information to find each other and to evaluate the quality of products and services. When disputes arise, there are limited contractual or other means, such as arbitration mechanisms, to resolve these issues. Because of a tremendous backlog of cases, resolving disputes in Indian courts, for example, can take five to fifteen years.3 Some joke that “if you litigate here, your sons and daughters will inherit your dispute.”4 Anticipation of these transactional difficulties also hinders contracting. We use the term institutional voids to refer to the lacunae created by the absence of such market intermediaries.5

To understand institutional voids in more concrete terms, consider the plight of an independent traveler from the United States visiting an emerging market on vacation. Beyond the challenges of operating in an environment having a different language, culture, and currency, the traveler also must navigate a different way of doing business, even as a tourist. Accustomed to booking flights through Expedia, Orbitz, or Travelocity, choosing hotels based on easily accessible and reliable reviews, obtaining travel-planning assistance from the AAA, paying for goods and services with a credit card in virtually any location, purchasing goods that meet enforced regulatory standards and possess enforceable warranties, paying taxi drivers according to standardized rates, receiving flight status updates by mobile phone text message, and finding restaurant phone numbers by simply dialing 4-1-1, the traveler must adapt to a different environment in the emerging market.

Although they might come in different forms, most other developed markets, such as European countries or Japan, have a comparable tourism market infrastructure to that of the United States. The institutional arrangement of an emerging market’s travel and hospitality marketplace, however, differs in fundamental ways. Internet-based airline ticket vendors, published travel reviewers, telephone directory assistance providers, credit card payment systems, and other such intermediaries are businesses, but they are also part of the U.S. market infrastructure. They help bring together buyers and sellers of travel services. (Nonprofit organizations, such as AAA, can also serve as market intermediaries, and governments provide many intermediary functions through regulatory bodies and civic services.)

In developed economies, companies can rely on a variety of similar outside institutions to minimize sources of market failure. Emerging markets have developed some of these institutions, but missing intermediaries are a frequent source of market failures. Informal institutions have developed in many emerging markets to serve intermediary roles. To reach rural consumers in India, for example, many brands rely on traveling salespeople to promote products in villages that have limited television, radio, and newspaper penetration. Salespeople stage live, infomercial-like performances out of the backs of trucks, explaining products while entertaining crowds with skits and banter. One such salesman, profiled in the Wall Street Journal, traveled more than five thousand miles per month, moving from village to village pitching products as wide ranging as tooth powder and mobile phones.6

Although some informal institutions may look like functional substitutes for the intermediaries found in developed markets, they often exist on an uneven playing field—accessible only to certain local players. A local loan provider might seem like a substitute for a venture capital industry, but only if the loan provider evaluates applicants on their merits or business plan. Seldom are informal market intermediaries truly open to all market participants.

Institutional voids come in many forms and play a defining role in shaping the capital, product, and labor markets in emerging economies. Absent or unreliable sources of market information, an uncertain regulatory environment, and inefficient judicial systems are three main sources of market failure, and they make foreign and domestic consumers, employers, and investors reluctant to do business in emerging markets. When businesses do operate in emerging markets, they often must perform these basic functions themselves.

Institutional voids, however, are not only roadblocks. They are also palpable opportunities for entrepreneurial foreign or domestic companies to build businesses based on filling these voids. To return to the example of the travel industry, Ctrip.com has emerged as China’s leading travel booking Web site, offering services similar to those of Expedia, Orbitz, and Travelocity. Established in 1999, Ctrip.com fills voids by aggregating hotel reservation and airline ticket information, providing rates and schedules, and offering a platform for customers to complete transactions—a powerful proposition in a market without a well-developed network of alternative intermediaries, such as travel agents.7 Ctrip.com registered $210.9 million in revenue in the year ending September 30, 2008, with a profit margin of 31.8 percent.8 Listed on NASDAQ, the company had a market capitalization of $1.3 billion as of January 13, 2009.9 The significant value that can be created by intermediary-based businesses illustrates the importance of such market institutions—and the cost of their absence. Transaction costs in markets, the role of market institutions in mitigating them, and the challenges of designing market institutions have been analyzed by several Nobel Prize–winning economists: Ronald Coase, Douglass North, George Akerlof, and Oliver Williamson. We draw on this vast literature in institutional economics in the following discussion.

Why Markets Fail and How to Make Them Work

Transactions vary in difficulty. It is generally easier to transact in developed than in developing markets. For example, renting a car in Boston is far easier than it is in Mumbai, São Paulo, or Ankara. Purchasing a home in London, although increasingly cost prohibitive, is a much easier feat than buying real estate in Moscow, with its infant mortgage market. Even in developed economies, however, there are degrees of transactional difficulty. For instance, U.S. consumers find it far more complex to buy health-care services than to buy groceries or consumer electronics.

Transaction costs, which offer one measure of how well a market works, include all the costs associated with conducting a purchase, sale, or other enterprise-related transaction. Well-functioning markets tend to have relatively low transaction costs and high liquidity, as well as greater degrees of transparency and shorter time periods to complete transactions.

The World Bank Group’s World Development Indicators highlight the variance in market performance between countries. Brazil, China, and India required more than twice the number of start-up procedures to register a business in 2007 than the six procedures required in the United States; Australia required only two. Another transaction cost measure is the time required to build a warehouse. A warehouse could be completed in leading developed countries in fewer than 200 days in 2007—in some cases far fewer—whereas in major developing markets such as Brazil, China, India, and Russia, it took 411, 336, 224, and 704 days, respectively. Other indicators, such as time to enforce a contract, time to register property, and time to start a business, also suggest higher transaction costs in many developing regions (see table 1-1).

All markets, irrespective of development phase, are less than perfectly efficient. Compared with emerging markets, however, developed markets are more likely to approach consistent standards for efficient transactions. Conducting even simple transactions in developing economies can be a time- and resource-intensive process, posing hazards for those expecting the fluidity of developed markets.

The challenge of transacting in the absence of well-developed market infrastructure is best illustrated through the Nobel Prize–winning economist George Akerlof’s example of a used car market. Akerlof’s work showed the difficulty of creating a well-functioning market when the quality of goods and services being bought and sold is uncertain.10 After owning and maintaining a car for five years and driving it for sixty-five thousand miles, the seller knows the condition of the car far better than the buyer. Unfamiliar with the car and its seller, the buyer will therefore approach the transaction with a degree of apprehension and mistrust. Is the seller selling a used car in decent working condition, or is he peddling a car with inferior quality relative to its price—a lemon? Is the car worth the price being asked?

TABLE 1-1


Comparing transaction costs in emerging and developed markets (2007)

image


The difference in knowledge about the car between buyer and seller—what economists call information asymmetry—and lack of trust make the buyer wary of taking the seller’s claims of quality at face value. As a result, a prudent buyer generally is reluctant to pay the price asked by the seller. Given these conditions, how can the buyer and seller consummate the transaction to their mutual satisfaction?

One obvious solution, practiced in ancient bazaars for centuries, is price bargaining. Suppose the seller is asking $10,000 for the car. The buyer can respond by offering a lower price—say, $6,000—to compensate for the variety of unknowns. If the seller finds the price acceptable, the transaction will take place; otherwise, the seller will walk away.

But simple bargaining leaves most market participants unsatisfied. Why? The seller has a pretty good idea of the true value of the car, so he will be happy with the $6,000 offer from the buyer only when it exceeds the car’s true intrinsic value. This, of course, means that the buyer would have overpaid for the car even though the bid price is substantially lower than the asking price. In contrast, if the seller were honestly representing the facts of the car’s quality and asking a reasonable price given its true value, he would find the $6,000 bid from the buyer unattractive, prompting him to walk away from the deal. Thus, with a strategy of bargaining for a price lower than the asking price, the buyer will consummate only deals that are systematically adverse to his interests.11

This type of used car market leaves buyers unhappy, because they systematically overpay for any given level of quality. Sellers of genuinely high-quality cars will find no takers, because the market-clearing prices are always lower than sellers’ assessment of fair prices. The only participants who will be happy are sellers who sell lemons at an inflated price. Clearly, this type of market will not last very long because sellers of genuinely high-quality cars will learn not to use it, and buyers will regret their purchase decisions and will learn to avoid it for future transactions.

There is, fortunately, a simple way to fix the problem in the used car market. The buyer and seller can agree to take the car to an independent expert mechanic who tests the car for its quality and provides an assessment of its intrinsic value. Based on this independent expert opinion, the buyer and seller can agree on a price.

How does the independent expert alter the situation? The expert opinion reduces information asymmetry between the buyer and seller and creates a basis for agreeing to a price based on common information. As a result, genuinely good-quality cars are likely to receive a fair price, so sellers and buyers of those cars will be happy with the transactions. Moreover, lemons will be exposed for what they are and accordingly will be priced lower. So buyers will either avoid them or, if they choose to buy them, will not overpay. The only players who will be unhappy with the introduction of the independent expert mechanic will be potential sellers of lemons. Because the used car market with the independent expert functions far more reliably than the one without such an expert, both the buyers and the sellers of good cars will be happy to pay for the services of such an expert.

All purchase and sale transactions in product markets for goods, in labor markets for talent, and in financial markets for capital and securities involve information problems and incentive conflicts. As a result, there are plenty of ways in which these markets in any economy may fail to work efficiently and effectively.

We can draw three important lessons from the used car market example. First, information asymmetries and incentive conflicts between buyers and sellers create significant problems in markets. If these issues are not addressed properly, they will lead to a loss of confidence among market participants and potentially to the breakdown of the market. Second, it is possible to devise institutional arrangements—such as the independent mechanic’s expert evaluation in a used car market, or passive intermediaries such as Kelley Blue Book and Autobytel—to mitigate these problems and make the markets work significantly better than they would otherwise. Developed economies have devised many such institutions to make their markets work well.

Third, even though such institutional arrangements make many market participants better off, their emergence will adversely affect those benefiting from institutional voids, such as those who sell faulty cars. The creation of market institutions will be resisted by such groups. Building market infrastructure is thus a matter of both economics and politics.

How Developed Markets Work

Developed markets for products, talent, and capital are full of institutions that are the equivalents of the independent car mechanic in the used car market. To reduce the transaction costs that arise from the differential information between buyers and sellers and to limit potential conflicts of interest, markets need institutions to intermediate between buyers and sellers of goods, services, and capital. High transaction costs make an economy inefficient, leading to higher cost of capital, less labor mobility, and increased cost of trading. Beyond transaction costs, absent market institutions are critical sources of operating challenges.

From protecting intellectual property to reaching customers, businesses need market institutions. Developed economies, in their quest to mitigate transaction costs and facilitate commerce, have developed several complementary solutions that together make information disclosure credible, enforce constraints reliably, and regulate markets fairly. Disclosure of high-quality, credible information reduces information asymmetries. Enforceable contracts ensure that buyers can be confident that sellers will not behave opportunistically. By providing aggregation, certification, analysis, and advice, market intermediaries help buyers and sellers come together to conduct transactions efficiently. Finally, market regulation ensures fair play by all parties by defining and enforcing a clear set of rules.12 Consider the important roles played by market intermediaries in product, capital, and labor markets.

Product Markets

In developed product markets, consumers are able to search for their desired products based on information provided by companies through advertising in newspapers and magazines, direct mail marketing, tele-marketing, Web sites, and other forms of communication. Further, consumers have access to third-party information providers, such as the Consumer Reports magazine and CNET, which produce extensive independent rating information on the quality and efficacy of a variety of products and services.

Retail chains also perform several valuable intermediary functions. They analyze consumer preferences; screen producers that seek to meet these preferences based on attributes such as quality, price, and delivery; stock and display goods so that consumers can see and evaluate them; advise consumers who visit the stores about product attributes; and allow consumers to return goods if they are dissatisfied.

Contracts between manufacturers and retailers, retailers and credit card issuers, card issuers and consumers, and manufacturers and consumers all play a critical role in ensuring that each performs its part of the obligation. Credit card issuers facilitate transactions by providing credit verification, financing, and collection of cash. Courts and consumer groups ensure that these contracts are enforced and that defaulters are penalized. If a manufacturer produces a low-quality product that fails to work as promised, for example, consumers have the right to return the product and recover their outlay. Similarly, if the consumer fails to pay the credit card company, the card company has recourse to collect the payment. Logistics suppliers such as delivery services meet the needs of transporting purchased goods from seller to buyer. Packaging contractors, shipping companies, and insurance agencies provide valuable services between seller and buyer to facilitate safe, timely, and guaranteed movement of products.

All the parties in the consumer product market are subject to a set of clearly laid-out regulations. For example, companies are prohibited from misleading potential customers through false advertising or promotion. Similarly, credit card companies are prohibited from sharing consumer information that violates customers’ privacy. Retailers are required to offer well-defined return policies. Logistics providers must be accredited and are held accountable by both transacting parties to deliver products on time and intact. All sales are accompanied by a certain implied warranty by the manufacturer that the consumer is entitled to expect. Manufacturers are prohibited from taking certain actions, such as resale price maintenance, which can reduce retail competition. Consumers can sue companies for selling goods that cause damage or injury.

All these mechanisms in a developed consumer products market rely on a comprehensive network of soft and hard infrastructure. Soft infrastructure includes advertising agencies and media outlets that facilitate corporate communication, market research companies and logistics consultants that assist retailers, and credit rating agencies that collect consumer credit information to assist credit card companies. Hard infrastructure, such as roads and bridges, is also essential for low-cost movement of goods from producers to retailers. Public institutions such as national, state, and local governments that promulgate rules, consumer unions that lobby for such rules, and courts that enforce these rules, all play an important role.

Capital Markets

Similarly complicated sets of mechanisms underpin the functioning of capital markets in well-developed economies. Financial reporting facilitates investor communication. Accounting standards and independent auditors enhance the credibility of financial reports. Information intermediaries such as analysts, rating agencies, and the financial press provide analysis. Financial intermediaries such as venture capitalists, commercial banks, insurance companies, and mutual funds help investors channel their funds to attractive investment opportunities and facilitate access to capital for entrepreneurs and established companies. Stock exchanges create liquidity by enabling investors to trade with each other at a low cost.

These markets are strictly regulated. The central bank, securities regulators, and stock exchanges enforce these rules. Courts act as arbiters of disputes between various parties. In developed markets, investors can hold corporate managers and directors accountable through the threat of securities litigation, proxy fights, and hostile takeovers. By reducing risks to investors, these institutions make it possible for new enterprises to raise capital on approximately equal terms as big, established companies.

Labor Markets

In the labor market, educational institutions not only help develop human capital but also certify its quality through graduation requirements. Placement agencies and headhunters help employers find talent. Employment contracts and numerous regulations allow both the employers and the employees to protect their interests. Unions act as intermediaries between rank-and-file labor and big corporations that have substantially more power and resources. Unemployment insurance gives companies the flexibility to hire and fire based on their needs and yet provides employees with a safety net.

In developed economies such as the United States, Canada, Western Europe, Japan, and Australia, dozens of market institutions facilitate the smooth functioning of capital, product, and labor markets. In emerging markets, by contrast, many of these intermediary institutions are either underdeveloped or absent. Chapter 2 describes a framework to help spot these institutional voids in emerging markets. Chapter 3 examines the institutional anatomy of markets in more detail as we consider opportunities for businesses to serve as intermediaries in emerging markets.

Structural Definition of Emerging Markets

This chapter highlights the myriad institutions required in product, labor, and capital markets to support simple or complex transactions between buyers and sellers of goods and services. We define emerging markets as those where these specialized intermediaries are absent or poorly functioning. That is, these markets are emerging as market participants work to find ways to bring buyers and sellers of all sorts together for productive exchange. This structural definition arrays markets along a continuum, from entirely dysfunctional—with a plethora of institutional voids—to highly developed (see figure 1-1).

This definition implies that every market, including those of the United States and other developed economies, has some degree of “emergingness” built in. For example, the subprime mortgage market in the United States, a key contributor to the financial crisis of 2008–2009, was an emerging market. Although the subprime lending market was serviced by a range of intermediaries—mortgage brokers, credit scorers, rating agencies, investment bankers, credit insurers, and regulators—these intermediaries did not effectively mitigate the information and contracting problems of a market in which the origination and financing of loans were so separated and incentives—such as credit-rating agencies being compensated by the entities whose securities they rated—were misaligned. The fast growth and increasing sophistication of transactions—the bundling and selling of mortgages in complex derivatives—outpaced the capacity of market intermediaries to handle them. More than the absolute growth or potential of a market, it is this gap in market infrastructure that defines an emerging market. The resulting financial crisis—the worst since the Great Depression—shows that institutional weaknesses can lead a market completely astray.

FIGURE 1-1


Continuum of institutional voids and market definitions

image


Working with this structural definition, Chapter 2 focuses on how to evaluate emerging markets to spot these voids and introduces a general approach for companies to use in responding to institutional voids. Markets do not emerge overnight. Product, labor, and capital markets that are missing critical intermediaries tend to be imperfect for long periods. Even when governments of developing countries establish new intermediaries to fill these voids, they do not immediately function along the same lines as those in developed economies. The existence of intermediaries does not guarantee that they will execute their roles effectively, efficiently, or even-handedly, as the U.S. subprime mortgage market example illustrates.

Institutional voids cannot be mandated away through deregulation and liberalization; it takes both significant time and substantial expertise to eliminate these voids. Indeed, the most predictable feature of an emerging market is the persistence of institutional gaps over the short and medium term. Thus, scanning emerging markets for institutional voids provides an anchor for business analysis, opportunity assessment, and strategic decision making in these markets.

..................Content has been hidden....................

You can't read the all page of ebook, please click here login for view all page.
Reset
3.134.108.197