Chapter 14

The Airline–Airport Relationship: Allocating Risks and Opportunities in a Vertical Partnership

Frank Fichert    Worms University of Applied Sciences, Worms, Germany

Abstract

This chapter describes the relationship between airports and airlines with a specific focus on airports in typical tourism regions and the changes induced by the rise of low-cost carriers on the respective markets. Based on a discussion of objectives of the several entities along the value chain and an analysis of airline route choice, an airport’s options for influencing airline decisions are presented. Common instruments like incentives within charging schemes and long-term contracts between airports and airlines are discussed, including their consequences for risk allocation and the potential impediments on competition. Moreover, some examples for a (partial) vertical integration between airlines and airports are presented.

Keywords

Airline route policy; Airport charging scheme; Aeronautical and nonaeronautical revenues; Risk sharing; Vertical integration

14.1 Introduction

A key feature of all transport services is their dependence on a dedicated infrastructure. For tourism destinations, if located at a larger distance from the home regions of their (potential) visitors, the existence of a (sufficiently dimensioned) airport is an indispensable condition for welcoming travellers. Moreover, the airport infrastructure has to fulfil certain technical and regulatory requirements (e.g. runway length, security control) as well as tourists’ expectations with respect to service quality. In addition to the airport, other air transport infrastructure facilities are needed (in particular air traffic control), but this will not be further discussed in this chapter. However, the existence of an airport is only a necessary, but not a sufficient condition for connectivity; airline services are required as well.

Traditionally, the provision of airport infrastructure is separated from the provision of airline services. In most parts of the world, both industries have gone through a process of considerable change over the last decades. The provision of air transport services has been liberalised on many domestic markets (first in the United States in 1978), in the European Union (EU) and between some neighbouring countries (e.g. Australia and New Zealand), as well as on an international level (open skies agreements). Amongst others, liberalisation has enabled new business models, in particular the rise of low-cost carriers (LCCs) (see Chapter 10). In parallel, and at least partly as a consequence of airline liberalisation, many airports have matured from ‘pure’ providers of infrastructure to market-oriented (commercialised) entities, with an increasing importance of ‘commercial’ revenues (in particular from shops and restaurants inside the airport and car parking).

This chapter deals with the relationship between airlines and airports in a liberalised and commercialised environment, paying special attention to the linkages with the tourism industry. First, the objectives of airlines and airports are discussed, in particular with respect to tourism policy. Second, basic information on different business models of airports is provided, again with a specific focus on tourism flows. The third part of the chapter deals with the route development strategies of airlines, followed by a comprehensive discussion of an airport’s options to influence these decisions. This part will cover different marketing activities as well as a large variety of financial incentives within and outside an airport’s charging scheme, referring also to the legal framework in the European Union. The next section deals with options for a (partial) vertical integration between airports and airlines. Before the conclusions, risks and opportunities from the perspective of the different stakeholders are discussed.

The chapter will elaborate on the relationship between airports and airlines in a general way, but mostly with the European situation as a reference point. Examples will be used to illustrate specific trends and the use of selected instruments, again usually referring to the European Union.

14.2 Ownership and Objectives of Owners

Although liberalisation and privatisation are two major trends in the air transport industry over the last decades, still many airports and even airlines are partially or even fully owned by states, regional bodies, and/or municipalities. Therefore a first step in analysing the relationship between airlines and airports is a discussion of ownership structures and the corresponding objectives of the respective entities.

In North America, the EU, and also some parts of Australasia, many airlines are in full private ownership. In particular, all low-cost carriers are privately owned (the only exceptions being low-cost subsidiaries of (partially) state-owned full-service network carriers). However, in Africa, the Middle East, large parts of Asia and Latin America, and even in the EU, ‘traditional’ airlines often are either fully publicly owned or have only been partially privatised.

For fully privatised airlines it can be assumed that they aim at maximising profits. On the other hand, if the government is involved as a shareholder, the airline usually will also have to consider overall policy goals. In the case of tourism destination countries this typically will include improving the accessibility of the airline’s home country for visitors from abroad (for one example, see Government of Malta, 2017). Competition with other airlines as well as budget constraints might limit an airline’s ability to serve the overall policy objectives if they are not in line with market requirements.

Regarding airports, the situation is even more complex. On a worldwide basis, most airports are publicly owned, with a share of privatised airports between 1% (North America) and 31% (Europe) (ACI, 2017). However, in particular many large- and medium-sized European airports have been fully or at least partially privatised, therefore serving the majority of passengers in Europe (for details, see ACI Europe, 2016). Moreover, there are several examples for Public–Private Partnerships, that is, a private firm investing in a state-owned airport and/or operating it. These long-term agreements can take different forms (e.g. management contracts, concessions, Build–Operate–Transfer models), but usually the contract period is limited, giving the government an opportunity to change the terms of the contract or even regain full public ownership and control. However, also for fully privatised airports the relationship with the government is crucial for airport managers, since business opportunities are heavily dependent on policy decisions, especially with respect to larger investment in runways or terminals and operating restrictions (e.g. night curfews).

In addition to (regional) employment, gross value added, and—in some cases—military functions, the major role of an airport from the perspective of policy makers is to enable connections to other regions, facilitating business as well as private travel. For leisure tourist destinations, in particular those located in regions where from a visitor’s perspective air transport is the only suitable way of travelling, an airport’s capacity and connectivity might be a limiting factor for tourism development. For example, the concession contract between the Greek government and a joint venture formed by the German airport operator Fraport and a Greek company obliges the private concessionaire to significantly expand the capacity of the 14 airports covered by the agreement (most of them located on islands) as well as to improve the quality of their passenger service facilities (Fraport, 2017). This clearly aims at enabling and attracting a larger number of tourist arrivals in the respective regions.

Several studies have analysed whether airports are operating under economies of scale (for an overview, see Lechmann and Niemeier, 2013). Although the empirical evidence is somehow mixed, at least for airports with less than three to five million passengers decreasing average costs can be assumed. Moreover, the revenues of airports with less than three million passengers often are not sufficient to make the airport profitable. For airports with less than one million passengers it is quite often not even possible to cover the operating costs. Therefore these airports usually depend on public funding, causing state aid issues which will be discussed in more detail in subsequent parts of the paper.

However, it is in the general interest of each (not capacity restrained) airport to increase passenger numbers since—given the high share of fixed costs—the additional aeronautical as well as nonaeronautical revenue contributes to increasing profits or reducing losses. A negative effect on the economic performance of an airport might only occur if either the growth in passenger numbers requires capacity enhancing investment (with additional costs exceeding additional revenue) and/or the airlines manage to capture the additional revenue by specific agreements with the airport. The second aspect will also be discussed in more detail later.

14.3 Airport Passenger Characteristics, Business Models, and Implications for Airport Management

There are several ways of defining and delineating business models of airports. With respect to the topic of this chapter, the shares of incoming and outgoing travellers matter. Especially in many ‘sun and beach’ destinations, the large majority of passengers are tourists from abroad. This may also lead to a high degree of seasonality in regions with pronounced peak and off-peak periods (e.g. the Mediterranean). Since most major cities in industrialised countries are also popular destinations for visitors (e.g. New York, London, Paris, Berlin) airports within the respective regions do not only serve a large number of business travellers but also many outgoing and incoming leisure tourists as well as other private travellers (esp. visiting friends and relatives—VFR). Finally, some cities or regions in industrialised countries may not attract a large number of (foreign) tourists, leading to a high share of outgoing travellers at the airport. Depending on these structural characteristics of demand, the different types of airports will also use specific strategies in their relations to the airlines.

The prevailing groups of passengers at an airport also determine the market shares of airlines following different business models. Before the emergence of low-cost carriers, most European tourists were flying to ‘sun and beach’ destinations on charter airlines (for the example of Faro airport in Portugal see Almeida, 2011) (see also Chapter 11). Even today, nonscheduled flights as part of a package holiday play an important role for many countries, for example, in Northern Africa (for the example of Tunisia, see Oxford Business Group 2016, p. 151). However, for Intra-European travel the emergence of low-cost airlines accompanied by new booking options for hotels and other accommodations via the internet has caused dramatic changes in the entire tourism industry (O’Connell and Bouquet, 2015). A growing number of travellers book their flights and their accommodation separately. Low air fares to a specific destination will in many cases boost demand for the destination (‘generating’ travel demand). Consequently, route decisions of LCCs and therewith also the relationship between airports and low-cost airlines have gained importance. Nowadays, many tourist destination airports are characterised by a high or even dominant share of low-cost traffic (for the example of Faro, see Almeida, 2011). Moreover, the boundary between charter airlines and low-cost carriers is blurring, since—if not restricted by bilateral Air Service Agreements—many charter airlines nowadays also sell tickets to individual passengers (leisure airlines).

In large cities and metropolitan areas the situation is different. The respective regions are usually served by traditional network carriers, charter flights, and low-cost carriers. Whereas in some regions one airport accommodates all types of airlines, elsewhere neighbouring airports concentrate on specific market segments, in particular ‘regional’ or ‘low cost’ airports with a focus on low-cost carriers. However, fundamental changes may even occur within a relatively short period of time, for example, Ryanair’s rather recent move towards serving primary and even hub airports (Dobruszkes et al., 2017).

Finally, many regional or low-cost airports located in industrialised countries outside the large metropolitan regions to a large degree depend on outgoing leisure tourists and some VFR traffic. Examples include UK airports like Bournemouth, and German airports like Paderborn-Lippstadt and Kassel.

14.4 Airline Route Policy

‘Traditional’ airlines (FSNCs) and low-cost carriers follow a totally different approach with respect to their network structure. FSNCs operate most or even all of their flights out of one (or sometimes two or even more) hub airport(s). This might also include connections to typical holiday destinations, but—since (at least on short-haul routes) these origin and destination (O&D) markets usually are rather competitive and passengers are price sensitive—a FSNC’s focus is rather on serving transfer passengers on those markets than on selling tickets to O&D travellers.

Due to specific investment, the dependence on a large local market as well as infrastructure requirements for hub operations, FSNCs are usually ‘tied’ to their hub airport(s). On the other hand, low-cost carriers often are considered to be ‘footloose’ (Humphreys et al., 2006), that is, they are serving point-to-point markets from many different airports and might rather easily switch aircraft from one route to another. Within the European common aviation market, carriers like Ryanair, easyJet, and Wizz Air operate on many city-pair markets outside their home countries and show a high degree of flexibility in opening as well as abandoning routes or even bases. Since the market segment of low-cost traffic has grown significantly over the past years, the number of newly served connections outweighs the number of routes that have been ceded. In general, larger low-cost airlines base aircraft (and crews) at several airports, leading to some stability in their network structure, but also some of those bases have been switched in the past (Malighetti et al., 2016).

From the perspective of an airline, the opening of a new route is always a trial-and-error process. Although route decisions are based on market research and demand modelling, revenue might be below forecasts and/or costs might be higher than expected. In general, in the first months or even years after the opening of a new route, its profitability is often low since (potential) passengers first have to be aware of the new travel opportunity. Moreover, an airline will have to take some investment, in particular marketing efforts. Compared to the opening of new routes, the risk of expanding services on a given route (e.g. increasing the number of weekly flights) is usually lower, but still not negligible.

14.5 Airport Options for Influencing Airline Route and Base Choice

14.5.1 Overview of Potential Strategies

There are several options for an airport to influence airlines’ decisions on the opening (and also expansion) of routes and/or the establishment of a base. First, as part of their overall marketing endeavours many airports employ route development managers, trying to identify potentially profitable connections and attracting new airlines, often referred to as the air service development (ASD) process (see Halpern and Graham, 2013, 2015). Although many general market data is available to airlines as well as to airports, route development managers employed by an airport can build a specific expertise on local travel requirements (e.g. information on business connections between local firms and their customers and suppliers, indicating a demand for business travel). Moreover, they might also assist an airline when getting in touch with large potential customers or other business partners. In addition to direct bilateral contacts, regular route conferences serve as a multilateral platform for bringing airlines and airports together.

Second, many airports offer direct or indirect financial benefits, especially for newly opened routes, route service expansions, or new entrants, that is, airlines not having served this airport before. In general, a multitude of options exist for granting advantages to an airline, in particular the (regulated) charging scheme, nonregulated service contracts (especially ground-handling provided by the airport and/or rental agreements on airport facilities). Moreover, airports may offer one-off (nonrecurring) as well as repeated payments, or the covering of costs which otherwise would have to be borne by the airline (e.g. staff accommodation and/or training, marketing activities). Furthermore, there are some possibilities for contracts which are not formally linked to an airline’s route decision but might be considered as part of an overall ‘package deal’ by the contracting parties, for example, an airport (or a regional body) might buy advertising space at the airline’s website or the onboard magazine after the airline has started to serve the airport or an additional route.

A particular form of assistance might comprise an airport’s marketing activities for promoting a new route or a new airline serving the airport. The airport uses its regular means of communication (e.g. press releases or airport magazines) and/or might start a dedicated marketing campaign with specific advertisements of different kind. These campaigns could also be a joint project between the airport and the airline. Depending on the expected share of incoming and outgoing passengers, other stakeholders might be involved. In particular, tourism development organisations sometimes promote their destination at the other point of a newly established route (see Chapter 15). Again, a cooperation with the respective airline is possible (e.g. ‘spend your vacation in destination X, now airline Y offers direct flights from airport Z’). Some airports have published (rather general) marketing support schemes (e.g. Abruzzo Airport, n.d.; AENA, n.d.; Shannon Airport 2017, Cork Airport, 2018, have even published detailed tables for calculating marketing support payments), whereas for other airports there is even less information publicly available on the preconditions for granting such kind of assistance and their magnitude.

14.5.2 Charging Schemes and Contractual Agreements Between Airports and Airlines

A growing number of airports include different types of incentives in their aeronautical charging scheme (Malina et al., 2012; Fichert and Klophaus, 2011). Common incentives are a reduction of (some) aeronautical charges for newly opened routes and/or growing passenger numbers on a route or of an airline. In line with the overall regulatory framework for airport charges (e.g. in the EU), regulators usually make sure that these incentives are not discriminatory. Depending on the legal framework for setting airport charges in a jurisdiction, specific arrangements with an airline might require an active role of the state or a regional body. For example, reductions in airports charges at Charleroi airport (Belgium) were granted to Ryanair under an agreement with the Walloon region (see European Commission, 2004).

Given the uncertainty about the profitability of new routes mentioned before, an airport’s financial assistance after the opening of a new route might be seen as a risk-sharing mechanism between the airline and the airport. Depending on the specific arrangement, the airport might even assume the entire risk. Quite often, airlines and airports agree on medium- to long-term contracts, where airlines guarantee a certain number of flights per period, a certain seat capacity offered, and/or a certain number of aircraft based at the airport in exchange for an airport’s commitment on keeping charges below a certain level, guaranteeing service levels and/or opening hours, investing in the airport infrastructure and/or providing financial assistance to the airline.

From an institutional economics perspective, these contracts can be seen as a mutual attempt to prevent strategic behaviour. Since both sides usually have to take some kind of specific investment (e.g. infrastructure expansion by the airport, planning and marketing activities by the airline and/or the airport), without a contractual agreement a holdup situation might occur after the opening of a route, with the airport and/or the airline trying to improve their economic results by increasing charges or reducing operations, respectively. The negotiating position of the airport depends on many structural determinants, in particular the degree of competition from neighbouring airports (or competing regions, especially in the case of ‘sun and beach’ destinations) and the overall (potential) market share of the respective airline at the airport.

Although it is publicly known that specific contracts between airports and (low cost) airlines are widespread (for the example of Poland, see Huderek-Glapska and Nowak, 2016), their provisions are typically considered a business secret. However, some of these agreements have become subject to investigations on state aid, and several decisions were published by competition authorities or courts. A path breaking case handled by the European Commission covered the contractual agreement between Ryanair and Charleroi airport in Belgium. The contract included, besides others, a commitment on the reduction of airport charges for 15 years, one-off payments by the airport, and a discount on ground handling fees in exchange for Ryanair’s contractual obligation to offer a certain number of flights over the respective period (Gröteke and Kerber, 2004).

14.5.3 Competitive Distortions and Legal Framework in the European Union

Specific contracts between an airport and an airline basically might cause two types of competitive distortions. First, if not all airlines serving an airport are given the same advantages, the preferred treatment of one airline might disturb competition between airlines, in particular if the favoured airline already has a large market share at the respective airport. At least in the EU, directive 2009/12/EC on airport charges aims at prohibiting charging schemes which include discriminatory elements. Specific requirements with respect to incentives for new routes can be found in the 2014 guidelines on state aid to airports and airlines (European Commission, 2014). However, some charging schemes seem to be ‘tailor made’ for a dominant airline at a specific airport. For example, Frankfurt-Hahn airport (a low-cost airport in the extended Frankfurt region with a local market share of Ryanair exceeding 80%) levies no movement charges if 90% of an airline’s flights have a turnaround time at the airport of less than 30 min (which should usually be the case for Ryanair) and for passenger charges a volume discount is granted, favouring Ryanair as the by far largest airline at the airport (Flughafen Frankfurt-Hahn, 2012). Moreover, in unregulated business segments, for example, provision of ground handling services or renting of airport facilities, there is less transparency and a discriminatory behaviour is more difficult to identify.

Second, in case of a subsidised airport it might be argued that benefits granted by this airport to its airline customers will distort competition with neighbouring airports as well as with other airlines operating out of neighbouring airports where charges are cost recovering and no additional support is granted. As a consequence, there might be a pressure at the neighbouring airport to also reduce charges below a cost recovering level (such ‘race to the bottom’ effects are also discussed for local tax rates or subsidies).

The EU has already taken several measures in order to prevent competitive distortions caused by specific agreements between (subsidised) airports and airlines as well as by airport subsidies in general. Already in 2005 ‘Community guidelines on financing of airports and start-up aid to airlines departing from regional airports’ were published (European Commission, 2005). With respect to start-up aid for new routes, the Commission assesses an airport’s strategy based on a private investor test. Therefore if agreements between airports and airlines improve the profitability of an airport (i.e. reduce losses or even increase profits) they are considered to be compatible with European law.

With respect to public funding, already the 2005 guidelines made a distinction between airport infrastructure, the operation of airport infrastructure, and ground handling services. The 2014 guidelines, which have replaced the 2005 guidelines, are more restrictive and state that, after a transition period, the operating costs of an airport should not be subsidised, except for those airports providing services of general economic interest or allowing for connectivity of regions with special requirements. Regarding infrastructure provision, the guidelines define a maximum share of subsidies, primarily based on the size of an airport, again allowing for a transition period. Airports with more than five million passengers per year are expected to finance their investment without additional public funding.

Since the 2014 guidelines limit the public funding of airports, the potentials for granting favourable conditions to airlines are declining. Moreover, some airports might even exit the market, in particular airports with significant overlaps in their catchment area, due to the guidelines’ additional restrictions against the ‘duplication of unprofitable airports’ (European Commission, 2014, p. 19). With respect to start-up aid to airlines, the 2014 guidelines limit the magnitude of the discount (maximum 50%) as well as its duration (maximum three years).

14.6 Vertical Integration

The connection between an airport and an airline with the (supposedly) highest degree of stability is a (partial) vertical integration. Basically three options exist. First, the airport and the airline might have the same owner. The typical case is state ownership, for example, in Middle East countries like the United Arab Emirates, ensuring a strategic link also to the governmental tourism development organisation (Lohmann et al., 2009). It can be assumed that conflicts between the airport and the airline on the allocation of risks and opportunities are minimised in such a constellation. For example, whereas European hubs usually apply a reduced passenger charge for transfer passengers (which might be a consequence of the higher intensity of competition in the transfer market), in Dubai transfer passengers are exempted from passenger charges, providing a clear benefit for the state-owned airline (Partnership for Open & Fair Skies, 2015). In Europe there is only very limited evidence of full vertical integration. Manston airport (UK) was bought by a private investor in 1998 but did not become profitable in the following years. In 2003 the company owning the airport also acquired a low-cost airline (EUJet) which operated out of Manston. However, the entire company continued to make losses and went bankrupt in 2005 (Kent County Council, 2015).

Second, the airline might own shares of the airport (or vice versa). Whereas, to the best knowledge of the author, there is no example for an airport holding shares of an airline, there is one example for an airline having acquired minority shares of an airport (Lufthansa with Fraport, the operator of Frankfurt airport). Especially for hub airports, this vertical relation might strengthen the airline’s position in influencing decisions which will affect one of their key resources (e.g. airport expansion projects).

Third, airlines might invest in terminal or other infrastructure at an airport. In the United States, airlines and airports usually agree on long-term ‘use and lease’ contracts for terminal infrastructure (for recent developments, see Messina and Smith, 2016). In Europe, joint ventures are sometimes used, for example, in the case of Munich airport’s second terminal (with Lufthansa as the partner of the airport operator). A specific situation can be found in Bremen (Germany), where Ryanair won a public tender for operating a dedicated low-cost terminal, investing approximately 10 m Euro (Niemeier and Njoya, 2011). Joint ownership of a terminal usually requires that this part of the airport infrastructure is exclusively used by the respective airline (and—if applicable—its alliance partners). From the airline’s perspective, it is possible to influence the design of the respective infrastructure based on its specific requirements. Moreover, being shareholder of a terminal also lets the airline participate in the nonaeronautical revenues generated at this facility. From a competition policy perspective, a (partial) vertical integration also causes some concerns, since the airport might have an incentive to provide privileges to its ‘partner airline’, negatively influencing the situation of (potential) competitors (Kuchinke and Sickmann, 2007).

14.7 Discussion of Risks and Opportunities

Given the different objectives of the relevant stakeholders, there are several risks as well as opportunities associated with the design of the airline-airport relationship. First of all, the cooperation between airports and airlines (sometimes complemented by tourism development organisations and/or other regional bodies) aims at increasing passenger numbers (as a precondition for reaching other objectives). Although in many cases a traffic generation—especially due to new or extended low-cost services—could be observed, there are also examples for routes which have been ceased if they turned out to be economically nonviable. Such developments might be a consequence of changes outside the control of the cooperating entities (e.g. overall political situation), but also due to determinants which can be influenced by the airline or the airport, respectively (e.g. service quality).

If passenger numbers (or average yields) are below expectations, the type of relationship between the airport and the airline matters. If only unilateral incentives exist (e.g. discounts for new routes within the charging scheme), the airline (in particular a low-cost carrier) might ask for a higher financial contribution of the airport, reduce its capacity, or simply abandon the route. However, in case of a contract between the airport and the airline, the specific provisions matter, for example, whether the airline is only obliged to offer a certain number of frequencies or whether also passenger volumes have been agreed on. Moreover, the contract might comprise consequences in case of low passenger numbers, for example, additional payments by the airport. As stated before, the allocation of risks between the airport operator and the airline will to a large degree be influenced by the competitive situation of the airport.

Second, even if passenger numbers meet or even exceed previous expectations, some stakeholders may not benefit from this development. Many airports rely on increasing nonaeronautical revenues due to higher passenger numbers, outweighing discounts on aeronautical charges and additional payments to the respective airlines. Consequently, in case of low nonaeronautical revenues per passenger, an airport might even sustain higher losses as a consequence of increasing passenger numbers. Especially with respect to passengers travelling on low-cost airlines, two opposing hypotheses might be stated. On the one hand, it might be argued that LCCs, in general, attract a higher share of passengers with an income below average (or in general customers not able or not willing to spend much money during their vacation), resulting in low spending also at the airport. Moreover, the relatively low share of business travellers on low-cost carriers is also expected to have a negative effect on average nonaeronautical revenues. On the other hand, passengers of a low-cost airline usually pay relatively low fares, so they might be able to spend more at the airport, maybe also buying goods which they will consume during the flight (since LCCs do not offer free drinks or other amenities). In addition, some LCCs operate routes to regional airports not served by ‘traditional’ carriers. On these routes the LCC passengers might show a spending profile similar to passengers of network airlines, for example, due to a high share of VFR passengers. Empirically, Yokomi et al. (2017) show for UK airports that LCC traffic generates relatively less nonaeronautical revenue than non-LCC traffic.

Finally, even if airlines as well as airports benefit (economically) from increasing passenger numbers, the effect on tourism might be dissatisfying for the regional stakeholders. First, the share of outgoing passengers might be higher than expected. Especially in industrialised countries, some regional stakeholders were hoping for more visitors in the airport region, but passenger flows are largely dominated by outgoing travellers. Second, in spite of a large number of incoming tourists, the visitors might not stay in the airport region but continue to neighbouring regions in order to spend their vacation. Third, even if the number of tourist in the region increases, their average spending in the region may be relatively low, and/or their average stay might be relatively short (for the example of Morocco, see Dobruszkes and Mondou, 2013). With respect to passengers travelling on low-cost airlines, similar arguments might be brought forward as already stated before regarding an airport’s nonaeronautical revenue. Empirically, the various effects are difficult to capture and to distinguish. With respect to passenger numbers, Rey et al. (2011) show a positive relation between low-cost flights and the number of tourists visiting Spain but without a further regional differentiation.

14.8 Conclusions

The relationship between airports and airlines is complex. At first sight, they both aim at increasing passenger numbers. However, as long as they are not vertically integrated—like for example in the Gulf countries through state ownership—there is always a potential dispute on the distribution of risks and opportunities.

The emergence of low-cost carriers, especially in Europe but also elsewhere, complemented with improved opportunities for self-booking of hotels and other types of accommodation has led to dramatic changes in the entire travel value chain. On the one hand, LCCs have proven to be able to ‘generate’ traffic, that is, to significantly increase the number of passengers and therefore in most cases also the number of tourists. On the other hand, these low-cost carriers are not confined to serve specific airports or even countries. Therefore airports, for example, in typical ‘sun and beach’ destinations do not only compete with neighbouring airports but also with airports in similar destinations in other regions. Consequently, the negotiating power of large low-cost airlines usually is considered to be quite strong. The large number of incentives within airport charging schemes as well as other types of support for airlines newly serving or growing at an airport might serve as an indicator for this type of competition. Especially for smaller airports (regional airports as well as low-cost airports) increasing passenger numbers may not lead to reduced losses, especially if additional nonaeronautical revenues remain small or are passed through to the airlines.

Since the losses of regional and low-cost airports are mostly covered by the government, contracts between (regional) airports and (low cost) airlines have been subject to criticism and also many investigations by competition authorities. Meanwhile, regulations have been amended (at least in the EU), aiming at a lower degree of airport subsidies. Assuming that these rules will not be softened, the negotiating power of low-cost airlines could be reduced to some degree. It remains to be seen, whether this will also affect tourism flows.

References

Abruzzo Airport (n.d.). Commercial Policy Development Routes. Available at http://www.abruzzoairport.com/docs/it/Commercial_Policy_Development_Routes.pdf. (Accessed June 3, 2018).

ACI Europe—Airports Council International Europe. The Ownership of Europe’s Airports. Brussels: ACI Europe; 2016.

ACI—Airports Council International. Airport ownership, economic regulation and financial performance. In: Policy Brief 2017-01. Montreal: ACI; 2017.

AENA (n.d.). Marketing Support Initiatives. Available at http://www.aena.es/csee/ccurl/960/288/Marketing%20Support%20Initiatives.pdf. (Accessed June 3, 2018).

Almeida C. The new challenges of tourism airports—the case of Faro airport. Tour. Manag. Stud. 2011;7:109–120.

Cork Airport. Route Support Cork Airport Route Support Scheme (“RSS”) Long-Haul Operations. Available at http://www.corkairport.com/docs/default-source/About-Us-Docs-/cork-airport-long-haul-route-support-scheme-2018.pdf?sfvrsn=0. 2018.

Dobruszkes F., Mourou V. Aviation liberalization as a means to promote international tourism: the EU-Morocco case. J. Air Transp. Manag. 2013;29:23–34.

Dobruszkes F., Givoni M., Vowles T. Hello major airports, goodbye regional airports? Recent changes in European and US low cost airline airport choice. J. Air Transp. Manag. 2017;59:50–62.

European Commission. Commission decision of 12 February 2004 concerning advantages granted by the Walloon Region and Brussels South Charleroi Airport to the airline Ryanair in connection with its establishment at Charleroi. Off. J. Eur. Union. 2004;L137:1–62.

European Commission. Community guidelines on financing of airports and start-up aid to airlines departing from regional airports. Off. J. Eur. Union. 2005;C312:1–14.

European Commission. Guidelines on state aid to airports and airlines. Off. J. Eur. Union,. 2014;C99/3–34.

Fichert F., Klophaus R. Incentive schemes on airport charges—theoretical analysis and empirical evidence from German airports. Res. Transp. Bus. Manag. 2011;1:71–79.

Flughafen Frankfurt-Hahn. Entgeltordnung. Available at http://www.hahn-airport.de/sycomax/files/512457_Flughafen%20Frankfurt-Hahn%20Entgeltordnung%202012.pdf. 2012.

Fraport. Fraport Greece Begins 40-Year Concession at 14 Greek Regional Airports. Available at https://www.fraport.com/content/fraport/en/our-company/media/newsroom/archive/2017/fraport-greece-begins-40-year-concession-at-14-greek-regional-ai.html. 2017.

Government of Malta. Air Malta. Available at https://tourism.gov.mt/en/aviation/Pages/Aviation-Entitities/Air-Malta.aspx. 2017.

Gröteke F., Kerber W. The case of Ryanair—EU state aid policy on the wrong runway. ORDO. 2004;55:313–331.

Halpern N., Graham A. Airport Marketing. London/New York: Routledge; 2013.

Halpern N., Graham A. Airport route development: a survey of current practice. Tour. Manag. 2015;46:213–221.

Huderek-Glapska S.A., Nowak H. Airport and low cost carrier business relationship management as a key factor for airport continuity: the evidence from Poland. Res. Transp. Bus. Manag. 2016;21:44–53.

Humphreys I., Ison S., Francis G. A review of the airport-low cost airline relationship. Rev. Netw. Econ. 2006;5(4):1–8.

Kent County Council. Manston Airport Under Private Ownership: The Story to Date and the Future Prospects. Available at https://www.kent.gov.uk/__data/assets/pdf_file/0003/29541/Manston-Airport-position-statement.pdf. 2015.

Kuchinke B., Sickmann J. The joint venture terminal 2 at Munich Airport and the consequences: a competition economic analysis. In: Fichert F., Haucap J., Rommel K., eds. Competition Policy in Network Industries. Berlin: LIT; 2007:123–154.

Lechmann M., Niemeier H.-M. Economies of scale and scope of airports—a critical survey. J. Air Transp. Stud. 2013;4(2):1–25.

Lohmann G., Albers S., Koch B., Pavlovich K. From hub to tourist destination—an explorative study of Singapore and Dubai’s aviation-based transformation. J. Air Transp. Manag. 2009;15(5):205–211.

Malighetti P., Paleari S., Redondi R. Base abandonments by low cost carriers. J. Air Transp. Manag. 2016;55:234–244.

Malina R., Albers S., Kroll N. Airport incentive Programmes: a European perspective. Transp. Rev. 2012;32:435–453.

Messina J.F., Smith E.T. Emerging trends in airport-airline use and lease agreements in the USA. J. Airport Manag. 2016;10(3):273–282.

Niemeier H.-M., Njoya E.T. Do dedicated low cost passenger terminals create competitive advantages for airports?. Res. Transp. Bus. Manag. 2011;1:55–61.

O’Connell J.F., Bouquet A. Dynamic packaging spells the end of European charter airlines. J. Vacat. Mark. 2015;21(2):175–189.

Oxford Business Group. The Report Tunisia 2016. Oxford: Oxford Business Group; 2016.

Partnership for Open & Fair Skies. Restoring Open Skies: The Need to Address Subsidized Competition from State-Owned Airlines in Qatar and the UAE. Available at http://www.openandfairskies.com/wp-content/themes/custom/media/White.Paper.pdf. 2015.

Rey B., Myro R.L., Galera A. Effect of low cost airlines on tourism in Spain. A dynamic panel data model. J. Air Transp. Manag. 2011;17(3):163–167.

Shannon Airport. Short-Haul Operations Route Support Scheme (RSS). Available at http://www.shannonairport.ie/gns/business/aviation-development/route-support-schemes.aspx. 2017.

Yokomi M., Wheat P., Mizutani J. The impact of low cost carriers on non-aeronautical revenues in airport: an empirical study of UK airports. J. Air Transp. Manag. 2017;64:77–85.

..................Content has been hidden....................

You can't read the all page of ebook, please click here login for view all page.
Reset
3.149.229.253