Chapter 15
The Rise of the Global Creative Class

Richard Florida and Charlotta Mellander

Introduction

The world economy is in the midst of an epochal transformation, from industrial capitalism to a new age of knowledge-based or creative capitalism. The canonical factors of production identified by the classical economists – land, labor, and capital – are no longer the principal drivers of economic growth. National and regional economies increasingly grow and thrive to the extent that they are able to harness science and technology, innovation, and human creativity as sources of economic and social progress.

Creativity differs in fundamental ways from more traditional, tangible factors of production. Unlike stocks of things that can be depleted or worn out, it is an infinitely renewable resource that is continually enlarging via education, job experience, and the spontaneous, often fortuitous combinations and recombinations of ideas that occur as people collaborate and compete.

Just as industrial capitalism gave rise to a new socioeconomic class of blue-collar workers, the creative economy has given rise to a new class of laborers who work with their minds and creativity. This creative class, which makes up between a third to nearly half of the workforce in the advanced economies, includes scientists and technologists; innovators and entrepreneurs; designers, musicians, entertainers, media workers, academics, and artistic and cultural creatives; and knowledge-based professionals in business, education, and health-care.

Like Marx’s (1887) working class, which was comprised of a number of very different occupations that all had physical skills in common, from skilled tradesmen to assembly-line workers, the diverse occupations that make up the creative class all draw upon an underlying set of creative skills.

This chapter, which draws off our previous work,1 summarizes our rankings for 82 nations on a metric that we call the Global Creativity Index (GCI), a composite measure based on technology, talent, and tolerance, the 3Ts of economic development (Florida 2002, 2012).

Technology is the first T. As Marx (1887) and Schumpeter (1934, 1942, 1947a, 1947b) noted long ago, technology and technological innovation enable capitalism to generate new industries and spur new growth. Solow’s (1956) now classic residual formalized the role of technology in economic growth. An enormous body of recent literature confirms and elaborates on it (Nelson 1959, 1977; Nelson and Winter 1982; Rosenberg 1983; Mowery and Rosenberg 1989; Rosenberg and Nelson 1994).

Talent is the second T. All the way back to Adam Smith, economists have noted the role of human capital and skill in economic growth, which Smith defined as the “acquired and useful abilities of all the inhabitants or members of the society” (Spengler 1977). Becker (1964) and Mincer (1974) identified a direct link at the individual level between knowledge and skill on one hand and productivity levels on the other (captured by wage levels). There is an extensive literature linking human capital to national and regional growth (Barro 1991; Rauch 1993; Simon and Nardinelli 1996; Simon 1998; Glaeser 1999; Glaeser and Saiz 2003). Moreover, these links are most easily seen and felt in cities, which act as the key economic engines for the contemporary economy (Glaeser 2011).

Drucker (1969, 1993) and Machlup (1962) long ago noted the growing economic importance of knowledge workers and the knowledge economy. Knowledge workers not only invent new machines and processes that turn out old products more efficiently, they come up with completely new products that create whole new markets. Romer (1986) formalized the role of knowledge and connected it with technology in his theory of endogenous growth.

Tolerance is the third T. Both technology and talent are best conceptualized not as stocks but flows. Talent and technology flow not just to places with great universities or robust industrial structures but places which are open and have low barriers to entry (Florida 2002). Tolerance thus operates as a non-market factor that increases the efficiency of technology and talent. Page (2007) has shown that innovation is closely associated with diversity. Silicon Valley, perhaps the most innovative place in the world, exemplifies this. Between one-third and one-half of its new technology-based enterprises have a foreign-born person on their founding team (Wadhwa et al. 2007). Detailed cross-national studies (Noland 2005; Noland and Pack 2004) found that the economic performance of nations was positively associated with more open attitudes toward homosexuality, which are also correlated with globalization, controlling for other factors. Openness to diversity is also in line with the broad cultural shift from materialist values about money and things to newer “post-materialist” values, which favor self-expression and a wider quest for happiness and well-being, as identified by Inglehart (1989, 1997).

Places that are open to new ideas, and that attract talented and creative people from across the globe, broaden both their technology and their talent capabilities, gaining an additional economic edge over and above those of technology and talent themselves. These places are increasingly found in and around major cities. Indeed, the economic activity produced within the world’s largest metropolitan areas accounts for a much greater economic value than their population sizes would suggest (Florida, Mellander, and Gulden 2010). Smaller urban areas that are rich in amenities and tolerance also punch well above their weight when it comes to technology-fueled growth.

The remainder of this chapter proceeds as follows. The next section outlines the data, variables, and methods used in our analysis. We then discuss the overall rankings of nations on the GCI and summarize the associations between the GCI and key indicators of economic and social performance. We conclude with a short summary of our key findings.

Methodology, Data, and Variables

This section discusses the methodology used in our analysis. The data covers 82 nations for the period 2000–2009. We sometimes use different years for different variables, and also utilize running averages, depending on data availability. The following describes the main variables and data sources used to construct the GCI.

Technology

We use three variables for technology: Global R&D Investment, Global Researchers, and Global Innovation (patents), which we then combine into our Global Technology Index.

Global R&D Investment

This measures R&D spending as a share of GDP. It is adapted from World Development Indicators of the World Bank, and is defined as “current and capital expenditures on creative work undertaken systematically to increase the stock of knowledge, including knowledge of humanity, culture, and society, and the use of knowledge to devise new applications. R&D covers basic research, applied research, and experimental development.”

Global Researchers

This variable measures professional researchers engaged in R&D per million capita. It is adapted from World Development Indicators and covers the years 2000–2005. Professional researchers are defined as “professionals engaged in conceiving of or creating new knowledge, products, processes, methods, and systems and in managing projects concerned. Postgraduate students at the doctoral level (ISCED97 level 6) engaged in R&D are considered researchers.” The World Development Indicators are published annually by the World Bank and the data is reported for 127–146 different countries, depending upon the year. However, since countries do not always report on an annual basis, we use averages for several years. This generates higher numbers of observations and also helps smooth extreme values.

Global Innovation

This variable measures patents granted per capita. It is adapted from the US Patent and Trademark Office (USPTO) and covers the years 2001–2008. US patents are a reasonable proxy for global innovation as inventors from around the world file for patent protection in the United States and the USPTO tracks inventors’ national origins. We count the number of granted US patents for each nation in the world.

The Global Technology Index combines these three variables in a single measure and is based on a principal component analysis, where the correlations between the overall index and the three constituent measures are as follows: Global R&D Investment (.88), Global Researchers (.89), and Global Innovation (.94). In other words, the overall technology score is based on the value for each variable, and not its ranking. We estimate the index for countries with missing values by running regressions based on the variables for which we do have values. The R2s for these regressions are as follows: 0.535 for Global R&D Investment, 0.588 for Global Researchers, and 0.702 for Global Innovation.

Talent

We employ two measures for talent: the occupationally-defined creative class, and the conventional measure of human capital based on educational attainment, which we then combine in our Global Talent Index.

Creative Class

The creative class variable is calculated as the share of a country’s labor force that is engaged in creative work that requires a high degree of problem-solving in their everyday work. This includes the following occupations: computer science and mathematics; architecture, engineering; life, physical, and the social sciences; education, training, and library science; arts and design work, entertainment, sports, and media; and professional and knowledge work occupations in management, business and finance, law, sales management, and healthcare. The data are from the International Labour Organization (ILO) and cover the years 2004–2007.

Human Capital

The human capital variable is based on the rate of enrollment in tertiary or post-high school education from the World Development Indicators. The data is reported to the UNESCO Institute for Statistics by national education agencies. Tertiary education is defined as “a wide range of post-secondary education institutions, including technical and vocational education, colleges, and universities, whether or not leading to an advanced research qualification, that normally require as a minimum condition of admission the successful completion of education at the secondary level.” The data cover the years 2004 and 2006 and are based on annual school surveys, normally conducted in the beginning of the year, and do not therefore reflect dropouts or actual attendance.

The Global Talent Index combines these two variables in a single index based on a principal component analysis, where the correlations are 0.87 for both the Creative Class and the Human Capital measures. Again, the overall score is based on the value for each variable and not its ranking. We estimate missing values through a regression analysis, which generates an R2 value of 0.501.

Tolerance

We employ two measures of tolerance to construct the Global Tolerance Index: tolerance toward ethnic and racial minorities and tolerance toward gays and lesbians. Both are from the Gallup Organization’s World Poll (2010), which covers approximately 150 nations for the year 2009. The first is based on the survey question: “Is your city or area a good or bad place to be in for ethnic and racial minorities?” The second is based on the survey question: “Is your city or area a good or bad place to be in for gay and lesbian people?” Our variable reflects the share of the respondents who said theirs was a good place.

The Global Tolerance Index combines these two measures. The two are equally weighted into a factor where both correlate at .92. We estimate missing values based on a regression analysis, which generates an R2 value of 0.432.

The Global Creativity Index (GCI)

The overall GCI Index is based on a principal component analysis of the three key indexes for global technology, talent, and tolerance. Each of the three indexes is based on the actual performance of each variable. We ranked nations on each of them, with the highest ranking going to the best performer. We then added the ranks together and divided by three. In the cases where we had a value for just two of the three variables, these two were added and divided by two. The average scores of the three indices were divided by the number of observations overall to get the overall GCI score.

Correlates for Economic Performance and Related Measures

We use the following variables to examine the relationships between the GCI and the economic and social performance of nations.

Economic Output

We employ the conventional measure of economic output: GDP per capita. The data are from World Development Indicators for the year 2005.

Global Competitiveness Index

Developed by Porter, Sachs, and Warner (2000) for the World Economic Forum, it is based on the following categories: basic requirements (including institutions, infrastructure, macroeconomic stability, and health and primary education), efficiency enhancers (including higher education and training, goods market efficiency, labor market efficiency, financial market sophistication, technological readiness, and market size), and innovation factors (including business sophistication and innovation).

Global Entrepreneurship Index

This variable is based on the Global Entrepreneurship Index developed by Acs and Szerb (2010). The index consists of several measures of entrepreneurial attitudes, activity, and aspiration, and covers the years 2004–2008.

Human Development Index

This variable is based on the United Nations Human Development Index, a composite measure which aims to capture three dimensions of human development: health and measured life expectancy, education level, and standard of living. We employ the 2009 index, which is based on data from 2007.

Happiness/Life Satisfaction

This variable is from the Gallup Organization’s 2009 Gallup World Poll. The measure is a ranking from 1 to 10, where 10 represents the highest possible level of life satisfaction. Our variable is the national average rank of life satisfaction.

Income Inequality

This variable is based on the Gini Coefficient, the standard measure of Income Inequality, which measures the distribution of incomes in a nation on a range from 0 to 100 where 0 represents absolute equality and 100 absolute inequality. This variable is from the World Bank’s World Development Indicators for the year 2007.

The Global Creative Class

We now turn to our findings for the global creative class. The creative class is essentially a measure of skill based on occupations or the kinds of work people do. It thus differs from the more conventional measure of human capital that is based on educational attainment.

While there is considerable overlap between the two, they are not the same. In the United States, for example, nearly three-fourths of adults with college degrees are members of the creative class, but less than 60% of the people whose occupations qualify them as members of the creative class have college degrees (Currid-Halkett and Stolarick 2013). In Sweden, 90% of the highly educated hold creative class jobs while only one-fourth of the creative class have university degrees (Mellander 2009).

A significant body of research shows that the occupation-based creative class measure operates in addition to and through other channels than the standard education-based human capital variable. A large-scale study found that the creative class has a bigger effect on wages – a key element of regional productivity – whereas education tends to have a greater effect on income (Florida, Mellander, and Stolarick 2008). Independent research by Gabe shows that the creative class continues to have a substantial effect on regional economic growth when controlling for the effects of education and other factors (Gabe 2009). Having a creative class job brings economic benefits that extend beyond those of going to college. A college graduate working in the same occupation as a non-college graduate earns approximately 50% higher wages. But having a creative class job adds another 16%, about the same as another 1.5 years of additional education, according to Gabe’s research (Gabe 2009). A 2012 study used advanced statistical models to compare the effects of the creative class and human capital across the 257 EU regions. “Our results,” it concluded, “indicate that highly educated people working in creative occupations are the most relevant component in explaining production efficiency” (Marrocu and Paci 2012: 369).

McGranahan and Wojan (2007) used sophisticated statistical techniques to gauge the effects of the creative class versus human capital on regional growth. To do so, they used systems of simultaneous equations rather than the conventional simple regression models to control for population and employment growth as well as influences from a range of other local conditions and attributes. Their key findings overwhelmingly confirm the “strong independent influence on employment growth from both the initial share employed in the recast creative class occupations and its growth over the decade. By contrast, the statistical association with human capital variables is quite weak.” And they add: “the econometric test of the creative class thesis provides strong support for the notion that creativity has an effect on growth independent of the endowment of human capital” (McGranahan and Wojan 2007).

Another detailed study, this one investigating regional development in the Netherlands, also found that the creative class considerably outperformed the standard education-based human capital measure in accounting for employment growth. This led its authors to conclude that the creative class measure sets a “new standard” for measuring skill and talent, especially when considering regional labor productivity (Marlet and van Woerkens 2004). “With our Dutch data set we do find evidence that Florida’s creative class is a better predictor of city growth than traditional education standards,” they wrote. “Therefore we conclude that Florida’s major contribution is his successful attempt to create a population category that is a better indicator for levels of human capital than average education levels or amounts of highly educated people. The point is, as Florida stated, not which or how much education people can boast of, but what they really do in working life” (Marlet and van Woerkens 2004: 24).

Figure 15.1 shows how the nations of the world stack up on the creative class shares of their workforces. The range on the map is quite large, from a high of nearly half to a low of just over 2%. Fourteen countries have 40% or more of their workforce in the creative class.

c15-fig-0001

Figure 15.1 The global creative class map.

Source: Florida, Mellander, and Stolarick (2011).

With nearly half (47.3%) of its workforce in the creative class, Singapore takes the top spot. Aside from Singapore and Australia in fourth place, the top-ranked countries are overwhelmingly Northern European and Scandinavian: the Netherlands (46.3%), Sweden (43.9%), Switzerland (44.8%), Belgium (43.8%), Denmark (43.7%), Finland (43.4%), Norway (42.1%), and Germany (41.7%). Ten of the top 15 countries for the creative class are European. With 35% of its workforce in the creative class the United States ranks 27th, below Slovakia (38.4%). Of the BRIC countries, Russia ranks highest at 20th (38.6%). Brazil is 57th (18.5%), and China 75th (7.4%).

The Creative Class in Global Cities

The shift to a creative economy entails a major geographic shift as well. As a growing body of research shows, cities have become the main social and economic organizing unit of the creative economy. But whether one is measuring population density, education levels, creative class share, innovation, or economic output, the world is increasingly spiky (Florida 2005b): some cities rank much higher than others. Cities act as drivers for the disparities between national competitiveness rankings. Larger, more globally connected cities are increasingly the winners in the global competition for talent.

Though no single organized source of comparable data on the creative class in global cities exists, a significant body of studies have examined the geography of the creative class in cities and metro areas within nations outside the United States, including the United Kingdom, Germany, the Netherlands, Sweden, Denmark, Finland, Norway, and China. Overall, they confirm the clustering force of the creative class and of technology assets and innovation in large cities and metro areas.

A large-scale effort to collect and organize data for Canada, Western Europe, and the Nordic countries was carried out under the auspices of the European Science Foundation (Asheim 2009; Boschma and Fritsch 2009; Lorenzen and Andersen 2009; Asheim and Hansen 2009; Andersen et al. 2010; Florida 2012; Florida and Mellander 2013a, 2013b). Table 15.1, which is adapted from this project, shows shares of the creative class in a number of selected European and Canadian cities. We should emphasize that this list is illustrative only – there are many creative class regions, nations, and cities around the world where data are either unavailable, have not been organized or published, or of which we are not aware.

Table 15.1 The creative class in global cities.

Source: Florida (2012) based on data from Boschma and Fritsch 2009 . Data for French metros provided by S. Chantelot.

Amsterdam, Netherlands 46.0% Hannover, Germany37.8%
Stockholm, Sweden46.0% Oslo, Norway37.6%
Helsinki, Finland44.0% Ottawa, Canada37.6%
Oxford, UK42.8% Bonn, Germany37.3%
Munich, Germany42.2% Toronto, Canada37.1%
Malmö-Lund, Sweden41.4% Copenhagen, Denmark36.8%
Cambridge, UK41.2% Stuttgart, Germany36.6%
London, UK41.2% Leicestershire, UK36.2%
Berlin, Germany39.3% Leeds, UK35.3%
Hamburg, Germany38.2% Paris, France35.1%

Amsterdam and Stockholm top the list, with 46% of their workforce in the creative class. The creative class makes up more than 40% of workers in Helsinki, Oxford, Munich, Malmö, London, and Cambridge. This is roughly the same as the top-ranked US metros at the time –Boulder and San Jose (Silicon Valley). The creative class made up 35–40% of the workforce in Paris, Toronto, Hamburg, Berlin, Oslo, Copenhagen, and several other metros – more than Boston, greater Washington, DC, Austin, or San Francisco at the time (Florida 2012).

The link between large metro areas and creative class growth are clear from a number of national cases. In Canada, for instance, economic prosperity has been linked to rising levels of national urbanization. Cities in that country, namely larger metros like Toronto or Vancouver, attract a disproportionate number of talented people, making them the engines of contemporary economic growth (Florida, Mellander, and Stolarick 2014). The same is true within other advanced, Anglophone countries, particularly Australia. There, the creative class is most likely to be found in the most amenity-rich cities, the economic engines of the Australian economy (Stolarick 2014).

A study of the United Kingdom (Clifton 2008) highlighted the uneven geography of the creative class, especially in and around London. Larger, denser cities with close links to the amenities and infrastructure of the capital have particularly high levels of the creative class (Clifton 2014). A study of Denmark (Andersen and Lorenzen 2009) found that the creative class is concentrated in Copenhagen and Denmark’s larger cities, which are able to provide a diverse range of service and cultural offerings and tolerance to alternative lifestyles, though interviews indicate that creatives are also attracted to smaller cities because of the cost advantages, specialized employment offerings, attractive work/life balance, authenticity, and sense of community that they offer.

A study of the Netherlands (van Aalst et al. 2014) found a substantial relationship between the creative class and employment growth, and a smaller but still significant connection between the creative class and the growth of new businesses across Dutch regions. However it found only a weak association between regional “openness” and the creative class. Moreover, cities with greater shares of the population in the creative class in the Netherlands have been shown to do much better economically than other cities, thus underscoring the pivotal role of metros in national economic well-being (Marlet and van Woerkens 2014).

Several studies of Germany highlight the uneven geography of the creative class in that country. Fritsch and Stuetzer (2009) note that while Germany’s creative class is especially concentrated in larger cities, considerable concentrations can also be found in smaller cities and rural places. In contrast with the findings for the Netherlands, the creative class weighs ethnic and cultural diversity more than employment opportunities in their location decisions. Education and public health care are strongly associated with the creative class as well.

A 2011 study (Falck, Fritsch, and Heblich) tracked economic growth in German cities that had built opera houses in the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries. “Proximity to a baroque opera house is a strong predictor of a region’s equilibrium share of high-human-capital-employees,” its authors found, even though the construction of the opera houses predated those jobs by centuries. “It is the local level of high-human-capital employees who value their proximity to a baroque opera house that shifts a location to a higher growth path.”

A comparative study (Boschma and Fritsch 2009) examined the geography of the creative class across cities in Denmark, Finland, Germany, the Netherlands, Norway, Sweden, and the United Kingdom. It found the creative class to be over-represented in larger cities across Europe, especially in London. Indeed, all of the regions in Europe with substantial creative class populations tended to be around the main urban areas of their respective countries or regions (Boschma and Fritsch 2014). It also found that tolerance and openness have a positive effect on the regional share of the creative class, while the provision of public facilities in healthcare and education have only minor, if any, impacts.

A separate study (Andersen et al. 2010) examined the creative class across the Scandinavian and Nordic countries. It found the creative class to be highly concentrated in “capital regions,” which possess the thickest labor markets. That city size is an especially important factor in fueling economic growth and attracting the creative class is borne out by the Swedish case, where one of the best indicators of creative class share has been shown to be city size (Hansen 2014). Exploring the relative effects of the “people climate” and “business climate” in creative class locations, it found that both play a role, though an attractive job market or business climate is especially important. This underlines the important point that people climates are heterogeneous, varying considerably from place to place. The authors also examine the impact of welfare state policies in the Nordic countries.

A study of China (Florida, Mellander, and Qian 2012) found that the distribution of the creative class and talent is considerably more concentrated there than in the United States or any other advanced economies. Universities are a key factor in shaping the distribution both of talent and of technological innovation in China; tolerance also plays an important role. All that said, neither talent nor technology are associated with the economic performance of Chinese regions, a finding that stands in sharp contrast to the pattern in more advanced economies, and casts doubt on China’s transition from a traditional manufacturing to a creativity-driven economy.

Taken as a whole, this body of work confirms the uneven geography of the creative class and its tendency to concentrate in large cities or those with knowledge-based institutions like universities.

Innovation and Cities

In the industrial age, the key role in innovation was played by nation-states, which subsidized large-scale research, the R&D departments of major corporations, and also clusters of smaller, more entrepreneurial firms which spearheaded and commercialized breakthrough technologies. With the rise of knowledge-based capitalism, cities and locations themselves have come to play a more central role. Marshall (1890) initially noted the role that agglomerations or clusters of firms played in spurring innovation and productivity improvement. Agglomeration is a way of organizing the division of labor horizontally between firms as posed to vertically within large firms.

Later Porter (1996, 1998), Piore and Sabel (1984) and others noted the rise of clusters of firms and of industrial districts as key features of knowledge-based capitalism. Saxenian (1994) applied the theory of industrial districts to leading innovative centers like California’s Silicon Valley. Jacobs (1969, 1984) identified the role of talent clustering in locations as the primary economic driver of activity. Her insights were later formalized by Lucas (1988, 2001) who identified the role of human capital externalities tied to location as the primary motor force or basic underlying “mechanism” of economic development. There is now a large body of literature on the higher rate of innovation and entrepreneurship and on the accumulation of talent and human capital in cities.

Studies of innovation identify the geographic concentration of innovation and university R&D and science and technology in cities, metro areas, and mega-regions. Florida notes that science and innovation are the spikiness of all economic activity, concentrated in an even smaller number of larger cities and metro areas than are population or economic activity (Florida 2005b).

A study of mega-regions (Florida, Gulden, and Mellander 2008), clusters of economically interconnected cities whose boundaries are delineated by night-time light emissions, identified 40 worldwide, including the Boston-Washington corridor, Greater London, Amsterdam-Brussels-Antwerp, Rome-Milan-Turin, Osaka-Nagoya, and Greater Tokyo. Those mega-regions house 23% of the world’s population but account for 59% of its economic output and 77% of patents globally. Another study (Florida et al. 2010) identified approximately 680 metropolitan regions with half a million inhabitants or more. Together, these regions account for more than 60% of the world’s economic activity, while housing just a quarter of the world’s population.

Elite academic activity, particularly in science and technology, is also spiky, concentrated and clustered in a small number of cities globally. Figure 15.2 (via Florida 2010 and based on the Academic Ranking of World Universities) charts the concentration of academic activity in metros around the world. The leading centers are Boston-Cambridge, New York, San Francisco, and Los Angeles in the United States, and London, Paris, and Zurich in Europe. In general, there is a strong geographic concentration of top universities on the East and West Coasts of North America, Western Europe, and a few places in Asia and Australia/New Zealand.

c15-fig-0002

Figure 15.2 Total academic score of world universities by metro.

Source: Florida (2010).

Venture capital and startup activity is also extremely concentrated across the globe. Figure 15.3 shows the location of start-up companies across the world (via Florida 2013a and SeedTable). The leading centers include the San Francisco Bay Area, New York, London, Los Angeles, Toronto, Boston-Cambridge, Chicago, Berlin, Bangalore, Austin, Seattle, and São Paulo. This is due to the fact that technology has a more complex set of inputs and is more closely tied to end users; also technology talent in general prefers urban locations. A similar pattern is revealed for innovation (Florida 2013b). In the period 2001–2011, the top 20 patent-producing metros accounted for close to 64% of all patent applications. Silicon Valley and the Bay area in California alone accounted for 13.6%.

c15-fig-0003

Figure 15.3 Start-ups founded by global metro.

Source: Florida (2013a).

Florida (2002, 2012) suggests that places spur innovation not just through their ability to accumulate technology and talent, but also by the ability to engender tolerance and open-mindedness, which enables them to attract a broader range of talent. Roughly a third to a half of entrepreneurial companies in Silicon Valley have a foreign-born founder on their team (Wadhwa et al. 2008). Related studies (e.g., Inglehart 1989, 1997) found that talent is drawn to the combination of economic opportunity, tolerance and open-mindedness, and quality of place provided by certain locations.

For all these reasons, global cities and mega-cities have emerged as the loci of talent and knowledge accumulation, technological innovation, and entrepreneurial business formation in knowledge-based capitalism, taking on roles previously played by corporations and the nation-state (Florida, Gulden et al. 2008). In the long run, this shift from national to regional and local will affect the way we think about innovation and innovation systems.

The Global Talent Index

We now turn to the broader Global Talent Index which combines two separate measures of talent: creative class share and Human Capital as measured by the share of adults who have completed tertiary education.

Figure 15.4 shows how countries fare on talent. Scandinavian countries rank high – Finland and Sweden are in first and second place; Denmark and Norway are fourth and sixth; Singapore ranks third; New Zealand is fifth; and Australia seventh. The United States is eighth, just ahead of Greece and Slovenia in the ninth and tenth spots. Of the BRIC countries, Russia ranks highest at 13th, with Brazil in 66th, India in 75th, and China in 76th place.

c15-fig-0004

Figure 15.4 The global talent index map.

Source: Florida, Mellander, and Stolarick (2011).

The Global Technology Index

The Global Technology Index combines three measures: R&D Investment as a percent of GDP; the number of professional researchers in a country as a share of population; and the number of patents granted per capita. The first two measure critical inputs to the process of technology generation and come from the World Bank; the third is a measure of innovative output and is from the US Patent and Trademark Office.

Figure 15.5 shows how the nations of the world stack up on the Global Technology Index. Finland, the home of Nokia, ranks first in researchers, third in R&D investment, and fourth in innovation. Japan ranks fourth in R&D investment, third in researchers, and second in innovation. Japanese companies have not only consistently pushed the technology envelope, they have been if anything even better at building reliable, follow-on generations of products, from high-quality cars to flat panel displays.

c15-fig-0005

Figure 15.5 The global technology index map.

Source: Florida, Mellander, and Stolarick (2011).

The United States ranks third, finishing sixth in R&D investment and seventh in researchers, but solidly in first place for innovation. With its infrastructure for entrepreneurial venture capital finance in Silicon Valley and elsewhere, the United States has seen a long list of high-tech start-ups turn into global giants, such as Microsoft, Apple, Google, and Yahoo.

Fourth-ranked Israel has the highest concentration of engineers in the world – 135 per 10,000 people, compared to 85 per 10,000 people in the United States (Senor and Singer 2009). Sweden takes fifth place and Switzerland, Denmark, Korea, Germany, and Singapore round out the top ten. Canada ranks 11th. While much has been made of the ascendance of the BRIC countries, they do not rank highly on our technology measure. The highest ranking of them is Russia, in the 28th spot. China ranks 37th, about the same as Latvia and Bulgaria. Brazil takes 48th place and India 49th, just behind Serbia and Croatia.

The Global Tolerance Index

The Global Tolerance Index combines two measures of tolerance, both from the Gallup World Poll. The first captures a country’s openness to ethnic and racial minorities; the second its openness to gay and lesbian people.

Figure 15.6 shows how the nations of the world stack up on global tolerance. Canada ranks first of the 82 countries and Ireland second. The Netherlands ranks third: it is the only country among the top five that is more open to gay and lesbian people (83%) than it is to racial and ethnic minorities (73%). New Zealand ranks fourth, followed by Australia in fifth place. Spain is in sixth place, followed by Sweden and the United States.

c15-fig-0006

Figure 15.6 The global tolerance index map.

Source: Florida, Mellander, and Stolarick (2011).

The Global Creativity Index

The 3Ts, technology, talent, and tolerance, work together in mutually reinforcing ways. Any one T is a necessary but in itself insufficient condition for economic success. For a nation or region to effectively compete in the creative economy, all three Ts have to work together. The GCI combines all three indexes into an integrated measure of a nation’s overall creative economic potential.

Figure 15.7 charts how the nations of the world compare on the overall GCI. Sweden is first, topping the United States in second place. Finland takes third place, followed by Denmark in fourth, Australia in fifth, and New Zealand in sixth place. Canada and Norway take seventh and eighth place and Singapore and the Netherlands round out the top ten. Of the BRIC nations, Russia scores the best in 36th place, followed by Brazil in 46th, India in 50th, and China in 58th place.

c15-fig-0007

Figure 15.7 The global creativity index map.

Source: Florida, Mellander, and Stolarick (2011).

Creativity and National Economic Performance

We now turn to the associations between creativity measured by the GCI and economic and social performance. Our analysis is structured around four key questions.

  • Are more creative economies also more productive and competitive?
  • Are more creative nations associated with higher levels of human development more generally?
  • Do more creative economies generate higher levels of happiness for their residents?
  • Are creative economies more or less equal?

Creativity and Economic Output

We begin with the relationship between creativity as measured by the GCI and economic output per capita.

Figure 15.8 shows the relationship between the GCI and gross domestic product per capita. There is a considerable correlation between the two (.84); there are only a few extreme outliers at the top and the bottom of the chart. Nations above the fitted line have higher gross domestic product per capita than their GCI scores would predict, while those below the line have lower economic output than predicted. On the one hand, the United States, Norway, Switzerland, Japan, Hong Kong, the United Kingdom, Israel, Austria, Germany, and Korea all have levels of gross domestic product per capita which are slightly higher than their GCI scores would predict. On the other hand, Canada, the Netherlands, Finland, Australia, and New Zealand have levels of gross domestic product per capita which are slightly lower than their GCI scores would seem to warrant. Perhaps more significantly, very low GCI scores appear to be associated with even lower levels of economic output per capita, as the cases of Nicaragua, Mongolia, Kyrgyzstan, Uganda, and Madagascar indicate.

c15-fig-0008

Figure 15.8 Global creativity and economic output.

Source: Florida, Mellander, and Stolarick (2011). Economic output measured as log of GDP per capita.

Creativity and Economic Competitiveness

We now turn to the relationship between the GCI and a well-established measure of global competitiveness: the Global Competitiveness Index developed by Michael Porter et al. (2000) for the World Economic Forum.

Figure 15.9 plots the relationship between the GCI and the Global Competitiveness Index. The correlation between the two is again substantial (.79), however there is more “scatter” about the line. The United States, Singapore, Switzerland, the United Kingdom, Japan, Hong Kong, Germany, and Denmark all perform better in terms of competitiveness than their GCI scores would lead one to expect. Canada performs just slightly better than its GCI scores predict. China and India both perform significantly better on competitiveness than their GCI scores suggest they should. On the other hand, New Zealand, Ireland, and Spain perform lower on competitiveness than their GCI scores would seem to predict.

c15-fig-0009

Figure 15.9 Global creativity and competitiveness.

Source: Florida, Mellander, and Stolarick (2011).

Creativity and Entrepreneurship

Schumpeter (1934, 1942, 1947a, 1947b) long ago showed how innovation and entrepreneurship come together to set in motion the “creative destruction” that drives economies forward. Research in psychology finds close connections between creative and entrepreneurial people (Sternberg and Lubart 1999). We chart the relation between the GCI and the Global Entrepreneurship Index (Acs and Szerb 2010), a measure of entrepreneurial activity which covers 54 nations worldwide.

Figure 15.10 plots the relationship between the GCI and the Global Entrepreneurship Index. The correlation between the two is strong (0.81). The fit is good but there are a large number of countries above and below the line. On the one hand, New Zealand, Australia, Sweden, Denmark, the United Kingdom, and Hong Kong all perform better on the Global Entrepreneurship Index than their GCI scores would predict. Canada is just slightly above the fitted line, while the United States, perhaps surprisingly, is just below it. On the other hand Germany, France, Belgium, and Singapore have lower levels of entrepreneurial activity than the GCI would predict.

c15-fig-0010

Figure 15.10 Global creativity and entrepreneurship.

Source: Florida, Mellander, and Stolarick (2011).

Creativity and Human Development

We now look at the connection between creativity and underlying human development based on the United Nations Human Development Index, which takes a wide variety of human development factors into account, from health conditions and life expectancy to education levels and standards of living.

Figure 15.11 plots the GCI against the Human Development Index for the nations of the world. The fit is good, with outliers mainly at the lower left hand quadrant of the graph, where some of the least developed nations of the world are found. The overall correlation between GCI and the Human Development Index is again substantial (0.82). The United States performs considerably less well on the Human Development Index than its GCI score would predict; Canada performs slightly better. Of the BRIC countries, India performs significantly worse on Human Development Index than its GCI score would seem to warrant. Four less developed nations, Cambodia, Pakistan, Madagascar, and Uganda, lag significantly on Human Development when their GCI score is taken into account.

c15-fig-0011

Figure 15.11 Global creativity and human development.

Source: Florida, Mellander, and Stolarick (2011).

Creativity and Well-Being

There is a considerable ongoing debate concerning the relationship between economic development and subjective well-being, much of it revolving around the effects of money or material well-being on happiness. While it was initially found that the relationship between income and happiness only holds within and not across countries – the so-called “Easterlin effect” (Easterlin 1995) – more recent econometric studies by Deaton (2008) and Stevenson and Wolfers (2008) have challenged this view, finding that income exerts strong effects on happiness across the board.

We examine the relationship between the GCI and a comprehensive measure of happiness and life satisfaction collected by the Gallup Organization’s World Poll (2010), using a standard set of core questions that asks individuals to rank their satisfaction with aspects of their lives.

Figure 15.12 plots the GCI against life satisfaction. The correlation between the two is substantial (0.74). The fit is reasonably good, with outliers mainly at the bottom quadrants of the graph, that is, among the less developed nations. The relationship between the GCI and life satisfaction is strongest among the more advanced nations. Denmark, Finland, the Netherlands, Ireland, Switzerland, New Zealand, and Canada have higher levels of life satisfaction than their GCI scores would predict. The United States has a level of life satisfaction that is roughly in line with its GCI score. Singapore, the United Kingdom, Taiwan, Hong Kong, and Korea have lower levels of life satisfaction than their GCI scores would predict. Among the BRIC countries, Brazil has a significantly higher level of life satisfaction than its GCI score would predict, while Russia’s is considerably lower. Both India and China have lower levels of life satisfaction than the GCI would predict.

c15-fig-0012

Figure 15.12 Global creativity and life satisfaction.

Source: Florida, Mellander, and Stolarick (2011).

Creativity and Inequality

It is widely believed that the shift from an industrial to an innovative, knowledge, and creativity-driven economy exacerbates inequality, as former high-paying, family-supporting manufacturing jobs decline and the labor market is bifurcated into higher-pay, higher-skill knowledge and professional jobs and lower-pay, lower-skill service jobs. A series of studies document the growth in income inequality across the advanced world (e.g., Sherman and Stone 2010). But do higher levels of creative performance and higher levels of income inequality necessarily go together?

Figure 15.13 plots the association between the GCI and the basic measure of income inequality, the Gini coefficient. The line slopes downward and the correlation between the two is negative (–0.43); in other words, the GCI is systematically associated with lower levels of income inequality – and hence greater equality – across the nations of the world.

c15-fig-0013

Figure 15.13 Global creativity and income inequality.

Source: Florida, Mellander, and Stolarick (2011). Income inequality measured as a Gini Index.

A closer look at the chart reveals two distinctive trajectories for the relationship between creativity and inequality. On the one hand, there are countries like the United States, the United Kingdom, Singapore, and to a lesser extent, Australia and New Zealand, in which high levels of creativity as well as productivity and economic competitiveness go hand in hand with higher levels of inequality. But there are also a substantial number of countries in which high levels of creativity, competitiveness, and productivity combine with much lower levels of inequality. These are largely Scandinavian and Northern European countries, including Sweden, Denmark, Finland, Norway, the Netherlands, and Germany. Japan is represented as well. Among the less developed nations, we find high levels of inequality in South American nations like Paraguay, Bolivia, Panama, Brazil, Honduras, Ecuador, and Argentina. Of the BRIC nations, China, Russia, and especially Brazil all exhibit much higher levels of inequality than their GCI scores would predict.

Each high-creativity, high-inequality nation has a high-creativity, low-inequality counterpart. This is a likely reflection of these countries’ differing levels of social welfare. Though more systematic study is needed before we can draw any firm conclusions, this finding gives reason for optimism. At the same time, it suggests that sustainable, long-term prosperity requires a significant investment in education and skill development.

Conclusion

This chapter has charted the role of creativity in the economic and social performance of 82 nations across the advanced and developing worlds, using both the Global Creativity Index, a composite measure of the technology, talent, and tolerance capabilities of nations based on Florida’s (2002, 2012) theory of the creative class and the 3Ts of economic development, and the three indexes that make it up. It has also systematically examined the relationship between the GCI and key measures of economic output and competitiveness, as well as a broader set of measures of human development, subjective well-being, and income inequality.

The creative class makes up more than 40% of the workforce in 40 nations, but our analysis suggests that the creative economy is emerging unevenly across the world. The creative economy is most established in Scandinavia and Northern Europe, the United States and Canada, and Australia and New Zealand. Moreover, the creative economy has emerged unevenly within countries as well as between it. Factors like amenities, quality of place, and openness and tolerance play an increasingly important role in attracting people to certain cities and creative centers. Larger cities in particular allow for the iterative and cumulative processes of creativity and skill-accumulation that make them the preeminent spatial homes of technology, talent, tolerance, and economic growth within the nation state. These larger cities are emerging as economic winners in an increasingly spiky world.

When it comes to the overall GCI, Scandinavian and English-speaking nations dominate the top ten spots. Sweden takes first place on the overall GCI. The United States is second, followed by Finland, Denmark, and Australia; Canada ranks eighth; New Zealand, Norway, Singapore, and the Netherlands round out the top ten. Despite their rapid economic rise, the BRIC nations still do not crack the upper tiers on the GCI: Russia ranks 31st, Brazil 46th, India 50th, and China 58th.

The GCI is closely associated with key measures of economic and social progress. Nations that score high on the GCI have higher levels of economic output, entrepreneurship, and overall economic competitiveness. Nations that invest in creativity and that achieve on the 3Ts of economic development also have higher levels of human development, life satisfaction, and happiness.

This chapter suggests that the economic, technological, and entrepreneurial performance of nations is due to a set of factors that extend beyond just science and technology. In line with other research at the national and subnational levels (see Barro 1991; Rauch 1993; Simon and Nardinelli 1996; Simon 1998; Glaeser 1999; Glaeser and Saiz 2003), we find that talent plays a substantial role in national economic performance. Our research further suggests that talent spans more than the conventional educational measure of human capital, but also includes occupational skill based on the kind of work people do. Overall, our research suggests that technology and talent are mutually reinforcing and complementary factors in cross-national economic performance.

This chapter further suggests that non-market factors, which we refer to as tolerance and openness to human capital, play an additional complementary role in the economic performance of nations. Nations that are more open to talent, which have lower barriers to entry for talent, benefit from the ability to attract and to mobilize a wider pool of talented individuals. This is in line with other research that finds that tolerance, diversity, and openness are associated with higher rates of innovation (Page 2007) and higher levels of national economic performance (Noland 2005; Noland and Pack 2004). Generally speaking, technology, talent, and tolerance operate as capabilities that reinforce each other.

This chapter also sheds light on the complex relationship between creativity, economic progress, and inequality. Generally speaking we find creativity (measured via the GCI) to be negatively associated with income inequality. While some countries, like the United States and the United Kingdom, achieve high GCI scores alongside relatively high levels of inequality, in general elevated levels of global creativity are associated with lower levels of inequality. We identify two paths here: a low road path where higher creativity is associated with greater levels of inequality, and a high road path where higher levels of creativity are associated with lower levels of inequality. This is at odds with the notion that it is large disparities in income that create the incentives and motivations that drive economic progress.

This provides some cause for optimism, even in the wake of the global economic crisis, as it suggests that economic growth and development can go along with lower levels of inequality – and that our future prosperity increasingly turns on the full development of each and every human being.

References

  1. Acs, Zoltan J., and László Szerb. 2010. “A Global Entrepreneurship Index.” Foundations and Trends in Entrepreneurship 5: 341–435.
  2. Andersen, Kristina Vaarst, and Mark Lorenzen. 2009. Den Danske Kreative Klasse: Hvem er den, hvordan ser den ud, hvor bor den – og hvad betyder det? [The Danish Creative Class: Who, How, and Where – and So What?] Aarhus: Klim.
  3. Andersen, Kristina Vaarst, Markus M. Bugge, Høgni Kalsø Hansen, Arne Isaksen, and Mika Raunio. 2010. “One Size Fits All? Applying the Creative Class Thesis onto a Nordic Context.” European Planning Studies 18: 1591–1609.
  4. Asheim, Bjørn. 2009. “Guest Editorial: Introduction to the Creative Class in European City Regions.” Economic Geography 85: 425–442.
  5. Asheim, Bjørn, and Høgni Kalsø Hansen. 2009. “Knowledge Bases, Talents, and Contexts: On the Usefulness of the Creative Class Approach in Sweden.” Economic Geography 85: 425–442.
  6. Barro, Robert J. 1991. “Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 106(2): 407–443.
  7. Becker, Gary. 1964. Human Capital. New York: Columbia University Press for the National Bureau of Economic Research.
  8. Boschma, Ron, and Michael Fritsch. 2009. “Creative Class and Regional Growth: Empirical Evidence from Seven European Countries.” Economic Geography 85(4): 391–423.
  9. Boschma, Ron, and Michael Fritsch. 2014. “The Location of the Creative Class in Seven European Countries.” In The Creative Class Goes Global, ed. Charlotta Mellander, Richard Florida, Bjørn Asheim, and Meric Gertler, 227–240. Abingdon: Routledge.
  10. Clifton, Nick. 2008. “The Creative Class in the UK: An Initial Analysis.” Geografiska Annaler, Series B, Human Geography 90(1): 63–82.
  11. Clifton, Nick. 2014. “Location, Quality of Place, and Outcomes: Applying the ‘3Ts’ Model to the UK.” In The Creative Class Goes Global, ed. Charlotta Mellander, Richard Florida, Bjørn Asheim, and Meric Gertler, 183–209. Abingdon: Routledge.
  12. Currid-Halkett, Elizabeth, and Kevin Stolarick. 2013. “Baptism by Fire: An Occupational Analysis of Creative Sector Impact on Regional Economies.” Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society 6(1): 55–69.
  13. Deaton, Angus. 2008. “Income, Health and Wellbeing around the World: Evidence from the Gallup World Poll.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 22(2): 53–72.
  14. Drucker, Peter. 1969. The Age of Discontinuity: Guidelines to Our Changing Society. New York: Harper and Row.
  15. Drucker, Peter. 1993. Post-Capitalist Society. New York: HarperCollins.
  16. Easterlin, Richard. 1995. “Will Raising the Incomes of All Increase the Happiness of All?” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 27(1): 35–47.
  17. Falck, Oliver, Michael Fritsch, and Stephan Heblich. 2011. “The Phantom of the Opera: Cultural Amenities, Human Capital, and Regional Economic Growth.” Labor Economics 18(6): 755–766.
  18. Florida, Richard. 2002. The Rise of the Creative Class. New York: Basic Books.
  19. Florida, Richard. 2005a. The Flight of the Creative Class: The New Global Competition for Talent. New York: HarperBusiness.
  20. Florida, Richard. 2005b. “The World is Spiky.” The Atlantic Monthly October: 48–51.
  21. Florida, Richard. 2010. The Great Reset: How New Ways of Living and Working Drive Post-Crash Prosperity. New York: Harper Collins.
  22. Florida, Richard. 2012. The Rise of the Creative Class, Revisited. New York: Basic Books.
  23. Florida, Richard. 2013a. “The New Global Start-Up Cities.” Citylab.com, June 4, http://www.theatlanticcities.com/jobs-and-economy/2013/06/new-global-start-cities/5144 (accessed January 1, 2014).
  24. Florida, Richard. 2013b. “Where America’s Inventors Are.” Citylab.com, October 9, http://www.theatlanticcities.com/jobs-and-economy/2013/10/where-americas-inventors-ara/7069/ (accessed January 1, 2014).
  25. Florida, Richard, and Charlotta Mellander. 2013a. “The Creative Class Goes Global.” In The Creative Class Goes Global, ed. Charlotta Mellander, Richard Florida, Bjørn Asheim, and Meric Gertler, 1–8. Abingdon: Routledge.
  26. Florida, Richard, and Charlotta Mellander. 2013b. “The Creative Class around the World.” In The Creative Class Goes Global, ed. Charlotta Mellander, Richard Florida, Bjørn Asheim, and Meric Gertler, 308–312. Abingdon: Routledge.
  27. Florida, Richard, and Irene Tinagli. 2004. Europe in the Creative Age. London: Demos.
  28. Florida, Richard, Tim Gulden, and Charlotta Mellander. 2008a. “The Rise of the Mega-Region.” Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society 1: 459–476.
  29. Florida, Richard, Charlotta Mellander, and Tim Gulden. 2010. “Global Metropolis: Assessing Economic Activity in Urban Centers Based on Night Time Satellite Images.” The Professional Geographer 64: 178–187.
  30. Florida, Richard, Charlotta Mellander, and Haifeng Qian. 2012. “China’s Development Disconnect.” Environment and Planning A 44: 628–648.
  31. Florida, Richard, Charlotta Mellander, and Kevin Stolarick. 2008b. “Inside the Black Box of Regional Development.” Journal of Economic Geography 8: 615–649.
  32. Florida, Richard, Charlotta Mellander, and Kevin Stolarick. 2011. The Global Creativity Index. Toronto: University of Toronto Martin Prosperity Institute.
  33. Florida, Richard, Charlotta Mellander, and Kevin Stolarick. 2014. “Talent, Technology and Tolerance in Canadian Regional Development.” In The Creative Class Goes Global, ed. Charlotta Mellander, Richard Florida, Bjørn Asheim, and Meric Gertler, 50–84. Abingdon: Routledge.
  34. Fritsch, Michael, and Michael Stuetzer. 2009. “The Geography of Creative People in Germany.” International Journal of Foresight and Innovation Policy 5(1–3): 7–23.
  35. Gabe, Todd. 2009. “Knowledge and Earnings.” Journal of Regional Science 49(3): 439–457.
  36. Gallup. 2010. Gallup World Poll, see http://www.gallup.com/services/170945/world-poll.aspx.
  37. Glaeser, Edward L. 1999. “Learning in Cities.” Journal of Urban Economics 46: 254–277.
  38. Glaeser, Edward L. 2011. The Triumph of the City: How Our Greatest Invention Makes Us Richer, Smarter, Greener, Healthier, and Happier. London: Pan Macmillan.
  39. Glaeser, Edward L., and Albert Saiz. 2003. “The Rise of the Skilled City.” NBER Working Papers 10191, National Bureau of Economic Research.
  40. Hansen, Høgni Kalsø. 2014. “Florida’s Creative Class in a Swedish Context: The Problem of Measuring Tolerance and Amenity-Driven Growth.” In The Creative Class Goes Global, ed. Charlotta Mellander, Richard Florida, Bjørn Asheim, and Meric Gertler, 87–102. Abingdon: Routledge.
  41. Inglehart, Ronald. 1989. Culture Shifts in Advanced Industrial Society. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
  42. Inglehart, Ronald. 1997. Modernization and Post-Modernization. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
  43. Jacobs, Jane. 1969. The Economies of Cities. New York: Random House.
  44. Jacobs, Jane. 1984. Cities and the Wealth of Nations. New York: Random House.
  45. Lorenzen, Mark, and Kristina Vaarst Andersen. 2009. “Centrality and Creativity: Does Richard Florida’s Creative Class Offer New Insights into Urban Hierarchy?” Economic Geography 85(4):363–390.
  46. Lucas, Robert. 1988. “On the Mechanics of Economic Development.” Journal of Monetary Economics 22: 3–42.
  47. Lucas, Robert. 2001. “Externalities and Cities.” Review of Economic Dynamics 4: 245–274.
  48. Machlup, Fritz. 1962. The Production and Distribution of Knowledge in the United States. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
  49. Marlet, Gerard, and Clemens van Woerkens. 2004. “Skills and Creativity in a Cross-Section of Dutch Cities.” Utrecht: Tjalling C. Koopmans Institute, Discussion Paper Series 04–29.
  50. Marlet, Gerard, and Clemens van Woerkens. 2014. “Tolerance, Aesthetics, Amenities or Jobs?: The Attraction of the Dutch City to the Creative Class.” In The Creative Class Goes Global, edited by Charlotta Mellander, Richard Florida, Bjørn Asheim, and Meric Gertler, 138–163. Abingdon, UK: Routledge.
  51. Marrocu, Emanuela, and Raffaele Paci. 2012. “Education or Creativity: What Matters Most for Economic Performance?” Economic Geography 88(4): 369–401.
  52. Marshall, Alfred. 1890. Principles of Economics, 8th edn. London: Macmillan.
  53. Marx, Karl. 1887. Capital, vol. 1. London: Sonnenschein.
  54. McGranahan, David, and Timothy Wojan. 2007. “Recasting the Creative Class to Examine Growth Processes in Rural and Urban Counties.” Regional Studies 41(2): 197–216.
  55. Mellander, Charlotta. 2009. “Creative and Knowledge Industries: An Occupational Distribution Approach.” Economic Development Quarterly 23(4): 294–305.
  56. Mincer, Jacob. 1974. Schooling, Experience and Earnings. New York: Columbia University Press for the National Bureau of Economic Research.
  57. Mowery, David C., and Nathan Rosenberg. 1989. Technology and the Pursuit of Economic Growth. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  58. Nelson, Richard. 1959. “The Simple Economics of Basic Scientific Research.” Journal of Political Economy 67: 297–306.
  59. Nelson, Richard. 1977. “In Search of Useful Theory of Innovation.” Research Policy 6: 36–76.
  60. Nelson, Richard, and Sidney Winter. 1982. An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
  61. Noland, Marcus. 2005. “Popular Attitudes, Globalization and Risk.” International Finance 8(2): 199–229.
  62. Noland, Marcus, and Howard Pack. 2004. “Islam, Globalization, and Economic Performance in the Middle East.” Washington, DC: Petersen Institute for International Economics.
  63. Page, Scott E. 2007. The Difference: How the Power of Diversity Creates Better Groups, Firms, Schools, and Societies. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
  64. Piore, Michael, and Charles Sabel. 1984. The Second Industrial Divide: Possibilities for Prosperity. New York: Basic Books.
  65. Porter, Michael. 1996. “Competitive Advantage, Agglomeration Economies, and Regional Policy.” International Regional Science Review 19(1): 85–94.
  66. Porter, Michael. 1998. “Clusters and the New Economics of Competition.” Harvard Business Review, November-December: 77–90.
  67. Porter, Michael, Jeffrey Sachs, and Andrew Warner. 2000. The Global Competitiveness Report. New York: McGraw-Hill.
  68. Rauch, James. 1993. “Productivity Gains from Geographic Concentration of Human Capital: Evidence from the Cities.” Journal of Urban Economics 34: 380–400.
  69. Romer, Paul M. 1986. “Increasing Returns and Long-run Growth.” Journal of Political Economy 90: 1002–37.
  70. Rosenberg, Nathan. 1983. Inside the Black Box: Technology and Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  71. Rosenberg, Nathan, and Richard R. Nelson. 1994. “American Universities and Technical Advance in Industry.” Research Policy 23(3): 323–348.
  72. Saxenian, AnnaLee. 1994. Regional Advantage: Culture and Competition in Silicon Valley and Route 128. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
  73. Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1934. The Theory of Economic Development (trans. Redvers Opie). Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
  74. Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1942. “The Process of Creative Destruction.” In Schumpeter, Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy, 81–86. New York: Harper and Brothers.
  75. Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1947a. “The Creative Response in Economic History.” Journal of Economic History 7(2): 149–159.
  76. Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1947b. “Theoretical Problems of Economic Growth.Journal of Economic History 7: 1–9.
  77. Senor, Dan, and Saul Singer. 2009. Start-Up Nation: The Story of Israel’s Economic Miracle. Toronto: McClelland and Stewart.
  78. Sherman, Arloc, and Chad Stone. 2010. “Income Gaps Between Very Rich and Everyone Else More Than Tripled in Last Three Decades, New Data Show.” Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, http://www.cbpp.org/cms/index.cfm?fa=view&id=3220 (accessed January 1, 2014).
  79. Simon, Curtis J. 1998. “Human Capital and Metropolitan Employment Growth.” Journal of Urban Economics 43: 223–243.
  80. Simon, Curtis J., and Clark Nardinelli. 1996. “The Talk of the Town: Human Capital, Information and the Growth of English Cities, 1861–1961.” Explorations in Economic History 33: 384–413.
  81. Solow, Robert M. 1956. “A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 70: 65–94.
  82. Spengler, Joseph J. 1977. “Adam Smith on Human Capital.” American Economic Review 67: 32–36.
  83. Sternberg, Robert J., and Todd I. Lubart. 1999. “The Concept of Creativity: Prospects and Paradigms.” In Handbook of Creativity, ed. Robert J. Sternberg, 3–15. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  84. Stevenson, Betsey, and Justin Wolfers. 2008. “Economic Growth and Subjective Well-Being: Reassessing the Easterlin Paradox.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1: 1–87.
  85. Stolarick, Kevin. 2014. “The Creative Class ‘Down Under’: Exploring the Creative Class Theory in Australia.” In The Creative Class Goes Global, ed. Charlotta Mellander, Richard Florida, Bjørn Asheim, and Meric Gertler, 243–261. Abingdon: Routledge.
  86. van Aalst, Irina, Oedzge Atzema, Ron Boschma, and Frank van Oort. 2014. “The Creative Class, Related Variety and Economic Growth in Dutch City-Regions.” In The Creative Class Goes Global, ed. Charlotta Mellander, Richard Florida, Bjørn Asheim, and Meric Gertler, 164–182. Abingdon: Routledge.
  87. Wadhwa, Vivek, AnnaLee Saxenian, Ben A. Rissing, and Gary Gereffi. 2007. “America’s New Immigrant Entrepreneurs: Part I.” Duke University, Duke Science, Technology & Innovation Paper 23.
  88. Wadhwa, Vivek, AnnaLee Saxenian, Ben A. Rissing, and Gary Gereffi. 2008. “Skilled Immigration and Economic Growth.” Applied Research in Economic Development 5(1): 6–14.

Note

..................Content has been hidden....................

You can't read the all page of ebook, please click here login for view all page.
Reset
18.191.14.196