Chapter 6

Financial Contagion From US to African Frontier Markets During the 2007–09 Global Financial Crisis

J. Ahmadu-Bello
T. Rodgers    School of Economics, Finance and Accounting, University of Coventry, Coventry, United Kingdom

Abstract

This chapter investigates financial contagion from the United States to eight African frontier markets during the 2007–09 financial crisis using a dynamic conditional correlation-based methodology. The crisis is explored from the perspectives of it being, first, a single long-period event and, second, a series of cumulative short-period subevents. For comparative purposes, contagion from the United States to a set of seven developed markets is also examined. We find strong evidence of contagion in African frontier markets during the early phases of the crisis. In contrast, contagion in developed markets was observed to occur more slowly. We speculate that the differences found are consistent with herding behavior occurring at a faster rate in the frontier markets than in their developed market counterparts.

Keywords

contagion
correlation
financial integration
herding behavior
social networking

1. Introduction, Aims, and Literature

The term “contagion” became widely used in the financial lexicon following the seminal work of King and Wadhwani (1990) and Forbes and Rigobon (2002) on financial crises in 1987 and the 1990s. The latter authors describe contagion in terms of it being “a significant increase in cross-market linkages resulting from a shock hitting one country or group of countries” (Forbes and Rigobon, 2002, p. 2223). The crises examined in the literature have been predominantly country- or region-focused events—for example, the 1997 Asian financial crisis, the 1998 Russian financial crisis, and the Mexican economic crisis in 1994. The 2007–09 crisis was different in that its reach was truly global and in that it unfolded as a series of subevents over a prolonged period. From an African perspective, the 2007–09 crisis was unique as it was the first time that a major financial crisis in another part of the world had a major impact on the continent. In some African markets (eg, Egypt and Nigeria), losses exceeded those in any developed market in percentage terms (African Development Bank, 2009).
The 2007–09 crisis was also different in that it was not a single short sharp shock, but was an event that unfolded in the United States over a period of more than a year. The event can be characterized as being a series of crisis waves (see Section 2, Fig. 6.1). The question that arises from a behavioral finance perspective is: How will markets respond? Will they treat each subevent as separate and unrelated and anchor their decisions on the US market in each instance? Or will they become conditioned to crisis-related events in the United States and stop responding to them?
image
Figure 6.1 Volatility Index (VIX), 2008–09.
This chapter explores these questions by testing for evidence of financial contagion from the US to African frontier markets. We note that the financial linkages (measured in terms of market correlation) between US and African frontier markets are much weaker than they are between US and developed markets; we believe that this may have implications as to how contagion events unfold in these two sets of countries. A secondary objective of the chapter is therefore to examine any differences found in this respect and to speculate as to whether they have any plausible behavioral-finance-related explanation.
In the remainder of this section we briefly review some of the key literature in respect to the contagion mechanism. Section 2 then presents the data and descriptive statistics. The hypotheses and methodology are described in Section 3 and the results from the study are presented and discussed in Sections 4 and 5. Last, conclusions are drawn in Section 6.
The literature has identified a number of different channels through which contagion events may unfold, with the main focus being on asset market channels, banking channels, and currency channels (Fry-McKibbin et al., 2013Tonzer, 2013Lau, 2001). Elsewhere in the literature a distinction is drawn between the relative importance of fundamental causes and investor behavior (Claessens and Forbes, 2004Dornbusch et al., 2000). Exploring contagion from a behavioral perspective, Calvo and Mendoza (2000) developed a formal model of herding. They argue that the cost of information will lead investors to follow market participants they believe are “well informed” and therefore market rumors will drive large swings in market prices through herding behavior.
A number of papers have attempted to examine the relative importance of behavioral and linkage-related factors. For example, Kaminsky et al. (2003) classify contagion theories into three groups: herding behavior, trade linkages, and financial linkages. They conclude that financial linkages and investor behavior are the most relevant factors in explaining contagion. Elsewhere in the literature a number of papers identify the importance of integration effects and note that during crises integration with global markets increases (Collins and Biekpe, 2003Kassim, 2013Cheng and Glascock, 2006).
The relatively low levels of integration may be of particular importance from an African perspective. Berger et al. (2011) analyze frontier market equities with respect to world market integration and diversification. They find little evidence of integration in respect to a number of African countries, including Kenya, Mauritius, and Nigeria. A similar picture is painted by Hatemi-J and Morgan (2007), who find that Nigeria and Zimbabwe have exhibited particularly low levels of integration with global markets.
There are considerable differences in the levels of integration that African and developed markets have with US markets (Table 6.1). There are also considerable differences in the sizes of these markets and the numbers of their respective participants (described in Sections 4 and 5). We believe that our study will show that the combination of these factors will result in considerable differences in the way in which contagion impacts African frontier markets and developed markets.

Table 6.1

Descriptive Statistics over the Period 01/01/07–10/15/2009

Country Mean Daily Return (%) Standard Deviation (%) Correlation with United Statesa Skewness Excess Kurtosis
Frontier Africa United State −0.036 1.937 1 −0.161 5.799
Botswana 0.017 0.569 −0.014 1.263 21.198
Côte d’Ivoire 0.026 25.272b −0.054 0.039 331.493b
Mauritius 0.054 1.295 0.009 0.067 6.713
Morocco 0.020 1.051 −0.027 −0.570 4.119
Namibia −0.022 3.397 0.341 0.882 113.549c
Nigeria −0.058 1.333 −0.040 0.060 0.603
Tunisia 0.087 0.656 0.126 −0.586 8.986
Zambia 0.062 1.280 −0.015 0.475 8.578
Developed Canada −0.014 1.854 0.653 −0.526 5.100
France −0.053 1.916 0.660 0.207 5.435
Germany −0.020 1.870 0.594 0.245 5.999
Italy −0.078 1.567 0.484 −0.408 4.825
Spain −0.035 1.828 0.578 0.013 4.927
United Kingdom −0.028 1.746 0.663 −0.026 4.658

a Constant correlations are estimated for the precrisis period of Jan. 1, 2007–Sep. 14, 2008, only. This period is used in order to identify precrisis differences in the level of integration with the US market.

b This unadjusted data needs to be treated with caution for reasons identified in the description associated with Figure 6.2b.

c This high value is associated with a spike in returns toward the end of the crisis period.

2. Data and Descriptive Statistics

An issue that every study of contagion faces is that of identifying the crisis starting point and ending point. The 2007–09 crisis was unique among post-1945 financial shocks in that it developed over a relatively long period and contained a number of subevents. This makes identifying the event window potentially problematical.
However, since the crisis originated from the United States, we have the Volatility Index (VIX) of the Chicago Board Options Exchange (CBOE) at our disposal to identify which events produced the greatest “shock” to investors. The index is popularly known as the “fear gauge” given its forward-looking properties. It is presented in Fig. 6.1.
The VIX showed a series of spikes associated with a number of key crisis events. The first spike in the last quarter of 2008 was associated with the lead-up to the Lehman bankruptcy (Sep. 15). Additional spikes were associated with the federal takeover of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac (Sep. 7), the emergency US$85 billion loan to insurer American International Group (AIG) (Sep. 17) and the crisis-induced sale of Merrill Lynch to Bank of America (Sep. 14).
The Lehman bankruptcy was the defining event of the crisis; we therefore use Sep. 15, 2008, to identify the start of what is defined as the long crisis period. The VIX remained high well into 2009, which is an indication that this particular crisis was not the type of short, sharp shock modeled previously in the contagion literature by the likes of Forbes and Rigobon (2002). Oct. 2008 saw further crisis measures such as the introduction of the US$700 billion Troubled Assets Relief Program (TARP) in the United States to stave off collapse in the banking system, and we saw further emergency mergers in this sector (eg, Wells Fargo taking over Wachovia). On Nov. 27 the US government had to rescue Citigroup after speculators drove its share price down 60%. Further afield, in the United Kingdom, the Royal Bank of Scotland (RBS) was rescued by the UK government on Oct. 13, and around the same time HBOS plc was forced to merge with Lloyds–TSB, which ultimately led to the partial collapse and bailout of this bank.
Defining the end point of the financial crisis is open to interpretation, but we again use the VIX. Using the mean index value from 2000 as a guide, the index can be identified as reverting back to its average by early Oct. 2009. This gives an indication of market expectations that the crisis was drawing to a close. Based on this, the long period contagion event is identified in this study as Sep. 15, 2008, to Oct. 15, 2009.a
The individual spikes observed in the VIX suggest that it may be more appropriate to treat the crisis as an accumulation of events rather than a single event. This has implications for the study of contagion from the United States to other markets from a behavioral finance perspective. We speculate that we may possibly find evidence of (1) a “decision fatigue” effect given that the crisis developed over such a long period or (2) a representativeness bias (Harman, 2009) where investors respond to each of the subcrises in the same way as they see the impact of the previous subcrisis as representative.
After the Lehman initial shock, there was a series of further fallout events and a whole series of emergency interventions into the financial markets by regulatory authorities. These are well documented in the historical studies of the crisis.b We can identify a series of subperiods in the market when fear spiked (Fig. 6.1).
Although individual subperiods are identified, the focus of this study is to examine the cumulative impact of the crisis in terms of changes in correlations as the crisis period lengthened. The subperiods identified are therefore: subperiod 1 (09/15/2008–10/10/2008), subperiod 2 (09/15/2008–10/17/2008), subperiod 3 (09/15/2008–10/27/2008), and subperiod 4 (09/15/2008–11/20/2008).

2.1. Data Sources and Descriptive Statistics

The study is based on the use of daily closing values of stock markets sourced from the Thomson Reuters Eikon Financial Database and shown in local currencies. The indices used are the principal indices from the respective countries. The data run from Jan. 1, 2007 to Sep. 15, 2009.
The daily logarithmic returns of the respective individual-country indices used are presented graphically in Fig. 6.2a–c, and the mean values and associated descriptive statistics are shown in Table 6.1.
imageimageimage
Figure 6.2 Daily returns.
(a) US market, over the period 01/01/07–10/15/09; (b) African markets, over the period 01/01/07–10/15/09; and (c) developed markets, over the period 01/01/07–10/15/09
The Standard & Poor’s (S&P) 500 index is selected as the American index on the basis that it is an index that is reflective of a general cross section of US stocks. The African frontier markets used for the study are identified from the classifications of S&P and MSCI, Inc. The African frontier markets under study includec Botswana, Côte d’Ivoire, Mauritius, Morocco, Namibia, Nigeria, Tunisia, and Zambia. The developed markets sampled represent a cross section of developed markets and consist of Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Spain, and the United Kingdom.
Fig. 6.2a provides the chart of daily returns for the US S&P 500 for the full sample period. Volatility in the market can be identified as spiking dramatically in the last quarter of 2008. This corresponded with the Lehman bankruptcy announcement and also the jump in the VIX as observed in Fig. 6.1.
The logarithmic returns in Fig. 6.2b identify that there are significant differences in patterns of volatility between African markets. For example, Morocco and Nigeria exhibit high volatility throughout the period with significant increases during the crisis period. Botswana, however, appears more volatile before the crisis period, whereas Mauritius shows relatively low precrisis volatility, which increases significantly during the crisis. Côte d’Ivoire shows an important example of why researchers need to be very careful when modeling with this type of frontier market data. The long period of close to zero returns and the sudden spike around the crisis period reflect periods of limited trading in a low-liquidity market.
Fig. 6.2c provides a graphical presentation of the daily returns of the developed markets. It can be identified that volatility in all these markets increased during the crisis period (toward the end of 2008). The similarities in volatility patterns here can be contrasted with those of the African markets identified in Fig. 6.2b. These differences possibly reflect the stronger financial linkages between US and developed markets, as can be identified in the much higher correlation levels illustrated in Table 6.1.
Table 6.1 shows there to be clear differences in the constant correlation estimates between the United States and African countries and between the United States and developed countries in the precrisis period. This can be seen as a reflection of the strength of developed countries’ financial linkages with the United States. We argue that African frontier countries, with their relatively weak linkages, can be described as being “low integration” countries and developed countries as “high integration” countries. Under normal market conditions, the standard deviations of returns would be expected to be appreciably higher in the higher-risk frontier markets. The fact that this is not the case is possibly a reflection of the extreme volatility levels in developed markets during the crisis period. It can be noted that mean returns in developed markets were negative during this period, and their standard deviations were very high relative to these returns. The values of the kurtosis and skewness presented in Table 6.1 identify that returns do not follow a normal distribution in either set of markets.

3. Hypotheses and Methodology

From the analysis of the data in Section 2, a long period and a series of shorter subperiods have been identified. We have also identified considerable differences in terms of precrisis constant correlations, returns, and risk profiles between African and developed markets. On this basis we identify the following sets of hypotheses.

3.1. Hypothesis 1

The hypothesis that contagion occurred in both African frontier and developed markets during the long crisis period of 2007–09 is formally tested as:
H1.a: There is a statistically significant increase in correlations between US and developed markets over the period 09/15/2008–10/15/2009.
H1.b: There is a statistically significant increase in correlations between US and African frontier markets over the period 09/15/2008–10/15/2009.

3.2. Hypothesis 2

The secondary hypothesis is that the crisis developed as a series of subevents and that contagion events occurred in each of these subperiods. This is formally tested as:
H2.a: There is a statistically significant increase in correlations between US and developed markets over the cumulative subperiods: 09/15/2008–10/10/2008, 09/15/2008–10/17/2008, 09/15/2008–10/27/2008, and 09/15/2008–11/20/2008.
H2.b: There is a statistically significant increase in correlations between US and African frontier markets over the cumulative subperiods 09/15/2008–10/10/2008, 09/15/2008–10/17/2008, 09/15/2008–10/27/2008 and 09/15/2008–11/20/2008.

3.3. Methodology

Contagion literature identifies four commonly used models for investigating contagion and markets’ comovement: (1) time-varying correlation techniques such as the dynamic conditional correlation (DCC) model (Engle, 2002Chiang et al., 2007), (2) correlation coefficient analysis (King and Wadhwani, 1990Forbes and Rigobon, 2002), (3) cointegration-based techniques (Longin and Solnik, 1995), and (4) the transmission mechanism approach (Eichengreen et al., 1996Forbes, 2004).
This chapter adopts the DCC–MGARCH model to test for contagion using daily time-varying correlations. The test for contagion is then a one-tailed hypothesis test for a statistically significant increase in the mean conditional correlation between the precrisis and crisis periods.
Following Forbes and Rigobon (2002), the first step of the procedure is to develop vector autoregression (VAR)–based equations to estimate the residual returns for pairs consisting of the US market and “a second market.” The returns used are 2-day averages; these are used to control for differences in market trading times. It can also be noted that the use of VAR-based mean equations in the MGARCH is necessary to control for high levels of autocorrelation in returns. The equations used take the following format:

rit=μi+k=1mαikritk+k=1mβikrjtk+ɛit

image(6.1)

rjt=μj+k=1mαjkrjtk+k=1mβjkritk+ɛjt

image(6.2)
Where r represents returns, i identifies the United States, and j is “a second market.”
The optimal lag structures for these equation pairs are determined using information criteria. Their residuals are then used to estimate time-varying variance equations, which take a GARCH(1,1) format:d

σit2=αi0+αi1ɛit12+βi1σit12

image(6.3)

σjt2=αj0+αj1ɛjt12+βj1σjt12

image(6.4)
where σt2image is the conditional variance, α0 the intercept, ɛ the standardized residuals, α1 the ARCH parameter, and β1 the GARCH parameter. The conditional correlation coefficients are estimated from the DCC equation:

Qt=(1αβ)Q¯+αυt1υ't1+βQt1

image(6.5)
where Qt is the covariance matrix and υtimage represents residuals standardized by the conditional standard deviation. The model is mean reverting as long as the nonnegative scalars satisfy the constraint: α + β < 1. A significant alpha coefficient value in the DCC equation is also an indication that correlations will vary appreciably over time. The alpha parameter was found to be insignificant for Mauritius, Nigeria, Tunisia, and Zambia. Although other GARCH specifications were tested in respect to these countries, the respective models failed to converge.
The estimated daily time-varying conditional correlations are shown graphically in Appendices 6.1 and 6.2. In order to test for contagion, mean values are calculated for the “precrisis” and “crisis” periods. Comparison-of-means tests are then used to test for contagion where the null hypothesis is that mean daily correlations during the crisis are less than or equal to those in the precrisis period. If the null is rejected, contagion is deemed to have been found. If a statistically insignificant increase in correlation is found, the result is interpreted as interdependence rather than contagion (Forbes and Rigobon, 2002).
This hypothesis is illustrated as:

H0:y2y1(absenceofcontagion)

image

H1:y2>y1(contagion)

image
where y2 and y1 are the mean daily correlation values between countries i and j during the crisis and precrisis periods, respectively. If variances are equal, the pooled variance t-test is used:

t=y2y1spool1n1+1n2t(n1+n22)

image(6.7)
where spool2=(y1iy¯1)2+(y2jy¯2)2n1+n22=(n11)s12+(n21)s22n1+n22,image
n1 = precrisis sample size, and n2 = sample size during crisis.
If variances are unequal, the Satterthwaite (1946) approximation is used:

t=y2y1spool1n1+1n2t(dfSatterthwaite)

image(6.8)
where dfSatterthwaite=(n11)(n21)(n11)(1c)2+(n21)c2image and c=s12/n1s12/n1+s22/n2image

3.4. Robustness Testing

To add to the robustness of the analysis, an alternative regression-based test is also undertaken to act as a confirmatory test. This takes the form of a test of significance in respect to a regression dummy variable representing the crisis periods.

Cij,t=μj+δjCrisisDUMMYt+ɛij,t

image(6.9)
where Cij,t is the conditional correlation at time t between the United States (i) and the second country (j). Crisis DUMMYt is a dummy variable taking on a value of 1 over the crisis period. A positive and statistically significant parameter value in respect to the dummy variable is an indication that financial contagion has occurred.

4. Results

The results from a series of tests in respect to hypotheses 1 and 2 are presented in Tables 6.2 and 6.3. These show considerable differences in respect to African frontier and developed countries. The results are presented and described next, and possible reasons for the differences found are then discussed in Section 5.

Table 6.2

Comparison-of-Means Based Contagion Tests: Long Crisis Period

African Markets Stable Period Crisis Period Test for Equality of Variancesb T-test for Equality of Meansc,d Evidence of Contagione
Mean Corr.a Standard Deviation Mean Corr.a Standard Deviation F Sig
Botswana −0.028 0.035 0.011 0.043 30.776 0.000 12.060*** Yes
Côte d’Ivoire 0.028 0.035 0.036 0.074 187.983 0.000 1.659** Yes
Mauritius 0.043 0.000 0.043 0.000 24.590 0.000 1.881** Yes
Morocco 0.011 0.036 0.017 0.081 159.192 0.000 1.060 No
Namibia 0.342 0.217 0.318 0.093 164.047 0.000 −1.965 No
Nigeria 0.043 0.000 0.043 0.000 4.982 0.026 0.904 No
Tunisia 0.066 0.002 0.066 0.002 1.811 0.179 0.935 No
Zambia −0.016 0.000 −0.016 0.000 8.478 0.004 −1.269 No
Developed Markets
Canada 0.763 0.112 0.828 0.046 121.101 0.000 10.486*** Yes
France 0.713 0.053 0.745 0.053 4.051 0.045 7.795*** Yes
Germany 0.664 0.059 0.769 0.030 67.056 0.000 30.620*** Yes
Italy 0.531 0.101 0.567 0.052 123.984 0.000 6.169*** Yes
Spain 0.602 0.065 0.704 0.046 34.937 0.000 23.574*** Yes
United Kingdom 0.665 0.033 0.720 0.028 3.672 0.056 22.150*** Yes

a Mean daily time-varying correlation over the period.

b Levine’s test of variance equality; where rejection of the null hypothesis indicates inequality.

c The t-value reported is the form appropriate for the variance identified.

d *Significant at 10%, **significant at 5%, ***significant at 1%.

e Contagion is defined as statistical significance at 5% level. Note that the test results for Mauritius, Nigeria, Tunisia, and Zambia need to be treated with caution due to an insignificant alpha in the DCC model.

Table 6.3

Comparison-of-Means Based Contagion Tests: Subcrisis Periods

African Markets Stable Period Subcrisis Period 1 Cumulative Impact of Subcrisis Periods 1–2 Cumulative Impact of Subcrisis Periods 1–3 Cumulative Impact of Subcrisis Periods 1–4
ρ σ ρ σ t-testa,b Ctn.c ρ σ t-testa,b Ctn.c ρ σ t-testa,b Ctn.c ρ σ t-testa,b Ctn.c
Botswana −0.028 0.035 0.012 0.045 4.697*** Y 0.014 0.041 5.449*** Y 0.020 0.038 7.067*** Y 0.045 0.043 13.139*** Y
Côte d’Ivoire 0.028 0.035 0.103 0.013 21.56*** Y 0.113 0.026 15.02*** Y 0.119 0.026 13.610*** Y 0.110 0.025 19.900*** Y
Mauritius 0.043 0.000 0.043 0.000 0.229 N 0.043 0.000 1.994** Y 0.043 0.000 2.806*** Y 0.043 0.000 3.813*** Y
Morocco 0.011 0.036 0.131 0.030 13.85*** Y 0.139 0.033 16.55*** Y 0.144 0.031 19.220*** Y 0.152 0.028 25.290*** Y
Namibia 0.342 0.217 0.367 0.037 1.839** Y 0.366 0.034 1.863** Y 0.367 0.031 2.083** Y 0.369 0.026 2.3170** Y
Nigeria 0.043 0.000 0.043 0.000 1.312* N 0.043 0.000 2.198** Y 0.043 0.000 1.719** Y 0.043 0.000 0.354 N
Tunisia 0.066 0.002 0.067 0.004 1.017 N 0.067 0.004 1.212 N 0.066 0.003 0.849 N 0.066 0.003 0.798 N
Zambia −0.016 0.000 −0.016 0.000 0.225 N −0.016 0.000 0.252 N −0.016 0.000 0.276 N −0.016 0.000 0.338 N
Developed Markets
Canada 0.763 0.112 0.717 0.049 −3.676 N 0.730 0.054 −2.655 N 0.744 0.056 −1.541 N 0.770 0.056 0.719 N
France 0.713 0.053 0.666 0.015 −10.962 N 0.672 0.018 −9.231 N 0.678 0.020 −7.912 N 0.724 0.027 −6.478 N
Germany 0.664 0.059 0.708 0.020 8.195*** Y 0.716 0.025 9.107*** Y 0.724 0.027 10.600*** Y 0.737 0.028 14.88*** Y
Italy 0.531 0.101 0.477 0.026 −6.935 N 0.484 0.029 −5.991 N 0.494 0.033 −4.670 N 0.516 0.039 −1.939 N
Spain 0.602 0.065 0.617 0.020 2.622*** Y 0.617 0.019 3.008*** Y 0.622 0.020 4.080*** Y 0.630 0.019 6.469*** Y
United Kingdom 0.665 0.033 0.665 0.013 −0.111 N 0.669 0.014 1.001 N 0.673 0.015 2.338*** Y 0.681 0.017 5.547*** Y

a As in Table 6.2, the t-value reported is appropriate for the form of variance identified.

b *Significant at 10%, **significant at 5%, ***significant at 1%.

c Contagion (Ctn.) is defined as statistical significance at 5% level. Note that the test results for Mauritius, Nigeria, Tunisia, and Zambia need to be treated with caution due to an insignificant alpha in the DCC model. For example, contagion shown in periods 1–2 in respect to Nigeria reflects changes in correlation beyond three decimal places.

Table 6.2 identifies evidence of contagion in both data sets over the long period (09/15/2008–10/15/2009). Although evidence of contagion is found in all developed markets, the picture in Africa is mixed. Contagion is found in Botswana, Côte d’Ivoire, and Mauritius. Increases in correlation that were not statistically significant at 5% were also found in respect to Morocco, Nigeria, and Tunisia. Reductions in correlation are found in Namibia and Zambia.
A series of interesting differences between African frontier and developed markets are also found in respect to hypothesis 2. These primarily relate to the issue of timing, as they suggest that, although the crisis had an immediate contagion effect in Africa, contagion to developed markets proceeded at a much slower pace.
The results in respect to the first subperiod (09/15/2008–10/10/2008) appear to suggest that contagion developed faster in the African markets. Contagion was identified in Botswana, Côte d’Ivoire, Morocco, and Namibia. It can be noted that lack of contagion found in the other African markets has to be treated with caution (they showed an insignificant alpha in the DCC–MGARCH model). It is noticeable from Table 6.3 that a number of the developed markets that had initial high levels of correlation with the US market had a reduction in correlation during this first period (Canada, France, Italy, and the United Kingdom). Germany and Spain are the only developed markets to exhibit contagion in this early crisis phase.
The cumulative impact of subperiod 1–2 resulted in further increases in correlations for Botswana, Côte d’Ivoire, Morocco, and Namibia. In developed countries there was a considerable increase in Germany and less marked increases in Italy, France, and the United Kingdom.
As the crisis moved to its later phases (cumulative subperiod 1–4), the increases in correlation shown in the African frontier markets was maintained. This manifests itself in contagion terms in Botswana, Côte d’Ivoire, Morocco, and Namibia. In developed markets it can be noted that there is evidence of contagion and interdependence spreading more widely, with Germany, Spain, and the United Kingdom all showing contagion effects and with interdependence also being found in Canada and France.

4.1. Robustness Tests

With the statistical power of comparison-of-means tests questionable under some circumstances, dummy variable regressions were run to test for the robustness of results. There are some marginal differences between Tables 6.3 and 6.4. For example, in respect to subperiod 1 in African markets, the differences found in relation to Nigeria and Tunisia can, however, be discounted for the statistical reasons described earlier. This leaves Namibia, where, although the comparison- of-means test shows evidence of contagion, the dummy test indicates no contagion. There is also some difference in respect to the developed markets. For example, Spain indicates contagion for subperiod 1 in Table 6.3 but not in Table 6.4.

Table 6.4

Dummy Variable Based Robustness Tests for Contagion: All Periods

African Markets Long Crisis Period Subcrisis Period 1 Cumulative Impact of Subcrisis Periods 1–2 Cumulative Impact of Subcrisis Periods 1–3 Cumulative Impact of Subcrisis Periods 1–4
Dummy Coefficient t-valuea Ctn.b Dummy Coeff. t-valuea Ctn.b Dummy Coeff. t-valuea Ctn.b Dummy Coeff. t-valuea Ctn.b Dummy Coeff. t-valuea Ctn.b
Botswana 0.039 12.642*** Y 0.040 4.697*** Y 0.042 5.449*** Y 0.048 7.067*** Y 0.073 13.139*** Y
Côte d’Ivoire 0.008 1.874** Y 0.075 8.912*** Y 0.085 11.316*** Y 0.092 13.609*** Y 0.082 15.377*** Y
Mauritius 0.000 2.001** Y 0.000 0.229 N 0.000 3.746*** Y 0.108 7.346*** Y 0.130 11.229*** Y
Morocco 0.006 1.221 N 0.120 13.846*** Y 0.128 16.553*** Y 0.000 4.861*** Y 0.000 5.699*** Y
Namibia −0.024 −1.710 N 0.025 0.513 N 0.024 0.548 N 0.132 19.224*** Y 0.141 25.291*** Y
Nigeria 0.000 0.967 N 0.000 2.190** Y 0.000 2.198** Y 0.025 0.648 N 0.027 0.856 N
Tunisia 0.000 0.935 N 0.001 2.332*** Y 0.001 2.514*** Y 0.000 1.719** Y 0.000 0.560 N
Zambia 0.000 −1.449 N 0.000 0.225 N 0.000 0.252 N 0.099 3.731*** Y 0.123 5.896*** Y
Developed Markets
Canada 0.066 9.090*** Y −0.046 −1.802 N −0.033 −1.418 N −0.018 −0.873 N 0.007 0.427 N
France 0.032 7.795*** Y −0.046 −3.906 N −0.041 −3.851 N −0.035 −3.679 N −0.025 −3.345 N
Germany 0.106 27.332*** Y 0.045 3.387*** Y 0.053 4.470*** Y 0.060 5.653*** Y 0.073 8.628*** Y
Italy 0.037 5.523*** Y −0.054 −2.372 N −0.046 −2.281 N −0.036 −2.001 N −0.015 −1.004 N
Spain 0.102 22.071*** Y 0.014 0.981 N 0.015 1.136 N 0.020 1.660** Y 0.027 2.919*** Y
United Kingdom 0.054 22.154*** Y 0.000 −0.050 N 0.003 0.486 N 0.007 1.249 N 0.016 3.350*** Y

a *Significant at 10%, **significant at 5%, ***significant at 1%.

b Contagion (Ctn.) is defined as statistical significance at 5% level. Note that the same caveat needs to be applied as in Tables 6.2 and 6.3; test results for Mauritius, Nigeria, Tunisia, and Zambia need to be treated with caution due to an insignificant alpha in the DCC model.

Although a number of differences can also be identified in the cumulative subperiod data, the general patterns identified are similar. Both tables indicate that contagion impacted African frontier markets quickly around the onset of the crisis and that it took significantly longer for contagion and interdependence effects to gather pace in developed markets.

5. Discussions

It was identified in Table 6.1 that the precrisis constant correlations were a lot lower in Africa frontier markets (low integration countries) than in developed markets (high integration countries). We also note that this chapter has found contagion to have occurred relatively early in the crisis period in Africa but that it took longer to develop in developed markets. In this section we explore potential behavioral explanations for these differences. We do not test the hypotheses put forward here, though, which means that they should therefore be treated as speculations.
There are massive differences between African frontier markets in terms of size, number of traders, the education of traders, and information systems. We therefore speculate that differences in trading behavior may reflect socionomics-related differences: specifically, information effects, social networking effects, and social mood effects.
Primary information from US financial markets (such as stock prices and volume data) travels almost instantly around the world to both developed and frontier markets. However, before this information is acted upon it has to be interpreted, and this secondary information will often depend on the advice or influence of friends and colleagues, as well as social influences. Social and professional networks are very important in the dissemination and interpretation of this information, and we argue that there are considerable differences between these networks in African and in developed markets. In times of crisis, investors may base their decisions on low-quality information and rumors disseminated through these networks, which can lead to noise trading (Thaler, 1993).
The forms of networks found in developed and frontier markets can be very different. Olsen (2004) suggests that when a network takes on an “aristocratic” structure, the speed with which information and informed opinion pass through society can be significantly faster. The structure, according to Olsen (2004), involves few perceived experts and a large number of investors who trust specific experts. We argue that such “aristocratic networks” are a characteristic of investment communities in frontier Africa, and as a result there is a rapid spread of influence and the emergence of trends. The network effect interacts with the social mood effects (Forgas, 1995Nofsinger, 2005), and we wonder whether the aristocratic networks in Africa lead to relatively rapid adjustments in the social mood among African investors.
The results in Table 6.3 suggest that African markets reacted more quickly at the onset of the financial crisis than did their developed markets counterparts. We speculate that the reason for this may lie in the small, illiquid nature of African frontier markets resulting in small, aristocratic social networks. African exchanges generally have few listed companies and relatively low levels of capitalization. This will also be reflected in the relatively low numbers of active locally based traders and therefore, by implication, relatively small social networks of these traders. This can be contrasted with the vast, and liquid, nature of developed markets with large numbers of both active professional and nonprofessional traders. The social networks in these markets are, by implication, going to be much larger than those found in African markets. Whereas in African markets there may be a few dominant opinion formers in the social network, in developed-market social networks there are likely to be a number of competing high-profile opinion formers. This suggests to us that the generation of consensus in African market social networks is likely to be substantially quicker than the generation of consensus in their developed-market counterparts.
It has been suggested that social networking effects can be viewed as a vector of noise trading (Gai and Kapadia, 2010Olsen, 2004). These processes are of particular importance in Africa, where it has been reported that markets are characterized by the concentration of trading in few stocks and the dominance of a few companies on the exchanges (Allen et al., 2011Tafirenyika, 2012). Control of these stocks is often dominated by a few individuals or families. This would suggest that these individuals are dominant players within the aristocratic social networks found in Africa, and therefore information coming from them will spread quickly and can act as a vector of noise trading in the markets. This could, in turn, lead to herding behavior.
The implication of these differences in Africa for herding behavior within markets is likely to be highly significant. Specifically, it suggests that herding may occur at a faster speed in Africa, as secondary-information-based consensus is likely to develop at a faster rate.
The case for herding being found in this study is strong, given the observed increases in correlation (Prechter, 1985 1999). It can also be noted that Hwang and Salmon (2009) argue that in developed markets the herding process can be relatively slow to develop (looked at in the context of stock market bubbles, which, they argue, can take a number of years to develop). We argue that in the 2007–09 crisis herding occurred more rapidly in African frontier markets than in developed markets and that this is reflected in our results.
Although speed of herding appears to be the most likely reason for the differences in the speed of contagion observed between African frontier and developed markets, other behavioral-related differences may also have been significant as well. We outline these later.

5.1. Decision Fatigue in Africa

From a behavioral perspective we can ask how the attitude of investors changed as subsequent phases of the crises unfolded. Did they become habituated to crisis in the United States and stop responding? We contend that the African data show evidence of decision fatigue. For instance, the correlations in Botswana, Côte d’Ivoire, and Morocco show increasing levels from the stable period through the cumulative impact of subperiod 1–4. However, it can be noted that the correlations dropped in the long period, which suggests that behavior changed. This, we speculate, was due to decision fatigue. Mood could have played a role in this regard. As the markets are small and moods are shared more quickly as a result of social networks, fatigue effects were likely to develop more quickly in African markets.

5.2. Loss Aversion in Developed Markets

Slow herding in developed markets may also be partly a function of greater loss aversion. Loss aversion can lead to a disposition effect whereby investors hold off realizing their losses until a final market capitulation occurs. It may very well be that the combination of the impact of slow decision making in large social networks and a disposition effect may explain the relatively slow process of herding becoming instigated between developed markets.

6. Conclusions

The key objective of this chapter has been to assess the impact of the 2007–09 financial crisis on financial contagion on African frontier markets. The 2007–09 crisis was unique from a contagion perspective, given that it was a truly global event that had a significant impact on most of the world’s financial markets. This has presented us with a unique opportunity to examine the impact of a single event on different types of markets (developed and frontier).
A number of previous papers in the contagion literature have identified herding as contributing to the transmission of crises. However, these have failed to identify the importance of the speed of the herding process in the transmission of contagion.
The contribution of this chapter is that we have identified differences in the speed with which contagion developed in African frontier markets and developed markets. We have also outlined a potential herding-related theoretical reason for this difference in speed—namely, that secondary information is processed and applied at a far quicker rate in markets where small social networks are observed.
The findings of this chapter will help African policy makers in their considerations of how to contain, and mitigate the impact of financial contagion on the continent. This research provides insights into the issue of contagion from the African frontier perspective. It is paramount for policy makers to be aware that it is unlikely that Africa will be immune from any future global financial crisis.

References

African Development Bank, 2009. Impact of the Global Financial Crisis and Economic Crisis on Africa. Working Paper Series 9.

Allen F, Otchere I, Senbet L. African financial systems: a review. Rev. Dev. Finance. 2011;1(2):79113.

Berger D, Pukthuanthong K, Yang J. International diversification with frontier markets. J. Financ. Econ. 2011;101(1):227242.

Calvo G, Mendoza E. Rational contagion and the globalization of security markets. J. Int. Econ. 2000;51:79113.

Cheng H, Glascock JL. Stock market linkages before and after the Asian financial crisis: evidence from three greater China economic area stock markets and the US. Rev. Pacific Basin Financ. Mark. Policies. 2006;9(2):297.

Chiang TC, Jeon BN, Li H. Dynamic correlation analysis of financial contagion: evidence from Asian markets. J. Int. Money Finance. 2007;26(7):12061228.

Claessens, S., Forbes, K., 2004. International financial contagion: the theory, evidence and policy implications. For the conference The IMF’s Role in Emerging Market Economics, Amsterdam, Nov. 18–19.

Collins D, Biekpe N. Contagion and interdependence in African stock markets. S. Afr. J. Econ. 2003;71:1.

Dornbusch R, Park CY, Claessens S. Contagion: understanding how it spreads and how it can be stopped. World Bank Res. Obser. 2000;15(2):177197.

Eichengreen B, Rose A, Wyplosz C. Contagious currency crises. Scand. J. Econ. 1996;98:463484.

Engle RF. Dynamic conditional correlation: a simple class of multivariate generalized autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity models. J. Bus. Econ. Stat. 2002;20:339350.

Forbes K. The Asian flu and Russian virus: the international transmission of crises in firm-level data. J. Int. Econ. 2004;63:5992.

Forbes K, Rigobon R. No contagion, only interdependence: measuring stock market co-movements. J. Finance. 2002;57(5):22232261.

Forgas JP. Mood and judgment: the affect infusion model (AIM). Psychol. Bull. 1995;(117):3966.

Fry-McKibbin, R., Martin, V., Tang, C., 2013. Financial Contagion and Asset Pricing. Centre for Applied Macroeconomic Analysis, Australian National University, Canberra.

Gai P, Kapadia S. Contagion in financial networks. Proc. Royal Soc. A-Math. Phys.Eng. Sci. 2010;466(2120):24012423.

Harman D. Judgment and Decision-Making: Psychological Perspectives. Chichester, UK: John Wiley & Sons; 2009.

Hatemi-J A, Morgan B. Liberalized emerging markets and the world economy: testing for increased integration with time-varying volatility. Appl. Financ. Econ. 2007;17:12451250.

Hwang, S., Salmon, M., 2009. Sentiment and Beta Herding. SSRN Working Paper Series. No. 299919.

Kaminsky, G.L., Reinhart, C.M., Vegh, C.A., 2003. The Unholy Trinity of Financial Contagion. Working paper, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.

Kassim HS. The global financial crisis and the integration of Islamic stock markets in the developed and developing countries. Asian Acad. Manag. J. Account. Finance. 2013;9(2):7594.

King M, Wadhwani S. Transmission of volatility between stock markets. Rev. Financ. Stud. 1990;3(1):533.

Lau LJ. Lessons from the East Asian Currency Crisis. Stanford, CA: Stanford University; 2001.

Longin F, Solnik B. Is the correlation of international equity returns constant: 1960–1990? J. Int. Money Finance. 1995;14(1):326.

Nofsinger JR. The Psychology of Investing. 2nd edn Upper Saddle River, NJ: Pearson Education/Prentice Hall; 2005.

Olsen R. Trust, complexity and the 1990s market bubble. J. Behav. Finance. 2004;5(4):186191.

Prechter RR. Popular culture and the stock market. In: Prechter RR, ed. Pioneering Studies in Socionomics. Gainesville, GA: New Classics Library; 1985.

Prechter, R.R., 1999. The Wave Principle of Human Social Behaviour and the New Science of Socionomics. New Classics Library, Gainesville, GA.

Satterthwaite FE. Of variance components. Biometrics. 1946;2(6):110114.

Tafirenyika, M., 2012. Harnessing African stock exchanges to promote growth [online]. Available from: http://www.un.org/africarenewal/magazine/august-2012/harnessing-african-stock-exchanges-promote-growth

Thaler R. Advances in Behavioural Finance. New York: Russell Sage Foundation; 1993.

Tonzer, L., 2013. Cross-Border Interbank Networks, Banking Risk and Contagion. FIW Working Paper (129).

Appendix 1: Time-Varying Correlations of US with African Markets

image

Appendix 2: Time-Varying Correlations of US with Developed Markets

image

a The mean daily closing value of the VIX over the period 01/03/2000–05/11/2012 was 21.72. The index began to show a significant increase above this level from the middle of 2007, peaking at 79.13 on 10/20/2008. It began to revert to the mean value during 2009 and by 10/15/2009 was at 21.72.

b See for example: <http://timeline.stlouisfed.org/>. Access date: 01/05/2014.

c With the exception of Morocco, all the markets in the sample are classified as frontier markets by S&P. Morocco is classified as a frontier market by MSCI. A number of markets are omitted as the full data required were not available at the time of this study from Thomson Reuters Eikon.

d A number of different functional forms of these equations were tested, including various asymmetric GARCH forms. None of these appreciably outperformed GARCH(1,1).

..................Content has been hidden....................

You can't read the all page of ebook, please click here login for view all page.
Reset
18.117.98.250