3.6. Summary

To recap, the canonical model provides a parsimonious framework for thinking about the skill premium and the determinants of the earnings distribution. Its simplicity leads to several sharp results, including:

1. Changes in the wage structure are linked to changes in factor-augmenting technologies and relative supplies.

2. Overall inequality rises in tandem with the skill premium (as within group inequality is either invariant when the skill premium changes or co-moves with the skill premium).

3. The economy-wide average wage and the real wage of each skill group should increase over time as a result of technological progress, particularly if the supply of high skill labor is increasing.61

4. The rate and direction of technological change do not respond to the relative abundance or scarcity of skill groups.

Applied to the data, this simple supply-demand framework, emphasizing a secular increase in the relative demand for college workers combined with fluctuations in relative skill supplies, successfully accounts for some of the key patterns in the recent evolution of between-group inequality, including the contraction and expansion of the college/high school gap during the 1970s and 1980s and the differential rise in the college/high school gap by experience group in the 1980s and 1990s. However, the admirable parsimony of the canonical model also renders it a less than wholly satisfactory framework for interpreting several of the key trends we highlighted in the previous section.

1. It does not provide a natural reason for why certain groups of workers would experience real earnings declines, yet this phenomenon has been quite pronounced among less-educated workers, particularly less-educated males, during the last three decades.

2. It does not provide a framework for the analysis of “polarization” in the earnings distribution, which we documented earlier, and relatedly, it does not easily account for differential changes in inequality in different parts of the skill distribution during different periods (decades).

3. Because the model does not distinguish between skills and tasks (or occupations), it does not provide insights into the systematic changes observed in the composition of employment by occupation in the United States and in other advanced economies— in particular, the disproportionate growth of employment in both high education, high wage occupations and, simultaneously, low education, low wage service occupations (i.e., employment polarization).

4. The model is also silent on the question of why the allocation of skill groups across occupations has substantially shifted in the last two decades, with a rising share of middle educated workers employed in traditionally low education services, or why the importance of occupations as predictors of earnings may have increased over time.

5. Because it incorporates technical change in a factor-augmenting form, it does not provide a natural framework for the study of how new technologies, including computers and robotics, might substitute for or replace workers in certain occupations or tasks.

6. Because it treats technical change as exogenous, it is also silent on how technology might respond to changes in labor market conditions and in particular to changes in supplies.

7. Finally, the canonical model does not provide a framework for an analysis of how recent trends in offshoring and outsourcing may influence the labor market and the structure of inequality (beyond the standard results on the effect of trade on inequality through its factor content).

Recognizing the virtues of the canonical model, we propose a richer conceptual framework that nests the canonical model while allowing for a richer set of interactions among job tasks, technologies, trading opportunities, and skill supplies in determining the structure of wages.

4. A ricardian model of the labor market

Many of the shortcomings of the canonical model can, we believe, be addressed by incorporating a clear distinction between workers’ skills and job tasks and allowing the assignment of skills to tasks to be determined in equilibrium by labor supplies, technologies, and task demands, as suggested by Autor et al. (2003).62 In this terminology, a task is a unit of work activity that produces output. A skill is a worker’s endowment of capabilities for performing various tasks. This endowment is a stock, which may be either exogenously given or acquired through schooling and other investments. Workers apply their skill endowments to tasks in exchange for wages. Thus, the task-based approaches emphasize that skills are applied to tasks to produce output—skills do not directlyproduce output. Task models provide a natural framework for interpreting patterns related to occupations in the labor market, as documented above, since we can think of occupations as bundles of tasks. In this light, the canonical model may be seen as a special case of the general task-based model in which there is a one-to-one mapping between skills and tasks.63

The distinction between skills and tasks becomes relevant, in fact central, when workers of a given skill level can potentially perform a variety of tasks and, moreover, can change the set of tasks that they perform in response to changes in supplies or technology. Although a growing literature adopts the task-based approach to study technology and its role in the labor market, this literature has not yet developed a flexible and tractable task-based model for analyzing the interactions among skill supplies, technologies, and trade in sharping the earnings distribution.64 The absence of such a framework has also meant that the power of this approach for providing a unified explanation for recent trends has not been fully exploited.

We believe that a useful task-based model should incorporate several features that are absent in the canonical model, while at the same time explicitly subsuming the canonical model as a special case. In particular,

1. Such a model should allow an explicit distinction between skills and tasks, and allow for general technologies in which tasks can be performed by different types of skills, by machines, or by workers in other countries (“offshored”). This will enable the model to allow for certain tasks to be become mechanized (as in Autor et al., 2003) or alternatively produced internationally.

2. To understand how different technologies may affect skill demands, earnings, and the assignment (or reassignment) of skills to tasks, it should allow for comparative advantage among workers in performing different tasks.

3. To enable a study of polarization and changes in different parts of the earnings distribution during different periods, it should incorporate at least three different skill groups.

4. As with the canonical model, the task-based approach should give rise to a well-defined set of skill demands, with downward sloping relative demand curves for skills (for a given set of technologies) and conventional substitutability and complementarity properties among skill groups.

The following sections present a succinct framework that enriches the canonical model in these three dimensions without sacrificing the underlying logic of the canonical model. This model is a generalization of Acemoglu and Zilibotti (2001) and is also related to Costinot and Vogel (forthcoming).65 The relationship between the framework here and these models will be discussed further below. Given the central role that the comparative advantage differences across different types of workers play in our model and the relationship of the model to Dornbusch et al. (1977), we refer to it as a Ricardian model of the labor market.66

4.1. Environment

We consider a static environment with a unique final good. For now, the economy is closed and there is no trade in tasks (a possibility we allow for later). The unique final good is produced by combining a continuum of tasks represented by the unit interval, [0, 1]. We simplify the analysis by assuming a Cobb-Douglas technology mapping the services of this range of tasks to the final good. In particular,

image (11)

or equivalently, image, where Y denotes the output of a unique final good and we will refer to y(i) as the “service” or production level of task i. We will also alternately refer to workers “performing” or producing a task. We assume that all markets are competitive. Throughout, we choose the price of the final good as the numeraire.

There are three factors of production, high, medium and low skilled workers. In addition, we will introduce capital or technology (embedded in machines) below. We first assume that there is a fixed, inelastic supply of the three types of workers, L, M and H. We return to the supply response of different types of skills to changes in technology later in this section.

Each task has the following production function

image (12)

where A terms represent factor-augmenting technology, and αL (i), αM (i) and αH (i) are the task productivity schedules, designating the productivity of low, medium and high skill workers in different tasks. For example, αL(i) is the productivity of low skill workers in task i, and l(i) is the number of low skill workers allocated to task i. The remaining terms are defined analogously. Given this production function, we can think of AL as (factor-augmenting) low skill biased technology, of AM as medium skill biased technology, and of AH as high skill biased technology. It is critical to observe that this production function for task services implies that each task can be performed by low, medium or high skill workers, but the comparative advantage of skill groups differ across tasks, as captured by the α terms. These differences in comparative advantage will play a central role in our model.

We impose the following assumption on the structure of comparative advantage throughout:

Assumption 1.

αL (i) /αM (i) and αM (i) /αH (i) are continuously differentiable and strictly decreasing.

This assumption specifies the structure of comparative advantage in the model. It can be interpreted as stating that higher indices correspond to “more complex” tasks in which high skill workers are better than medium skill workers and medium skill workers are better than low skill workers. Though not very restrictive, this assumption ensures a particularly simple and tight characterization of equilibrium in this economy.

Factor market clearing requires

image (13)

When we introduce capital, we will assume that it is available at some constant price r.

4.2. Equilibrium without machines

An equilibrium is defined in the usual manner as an allocation in which (final good) producers maximize profits and labor markets clear. For now there is no labor supply decision on the part of the workers.

Let us first ignore capital (equivalently, αK (·) ≡ 0). This implies that initially there are no machines that can substitute for labor in the production of specific tasks.

Allocation of skills to tasks

We first characterize the allocation of skills to tasks.

The characterization of equilibrium in this economy is simplified by the structure of comparative advantage differences in Assumption 1. In particular, there will exist some IL and IH such that all tasks i < IL will be performed by low skill workers, and all tasks i > Ih will be performed by high skill workers. Intermediate tasks will be performed by medium skilled workers. We can think of these intermediate tasks as the routine tasks performed by workers in many production, clerical, and administrative support occupations. More formally, we have:

Lemma 1.

In any equilibrium there exist IL and IH such that 0 < IL < IH < 1 and for any i < IL,m(i) = h(i) = 0, for any i ∈ (IL, IH), l(i) = h(i) = 0, and for any i > IH, l(i) = m (i) = 0.

The proof of this lemma follows a similar argument to a lemma presented in Acemoglu and Zilibotti (2001), extended to an environment in which there are three types of workers. Intuitively, if at given prices of three types of labor, wL, wM and wH, the costs of producing a unit of services of task IL using either low skill or medium skill workers are the same, then in view of the fact that αL (i) /αM (i) is strictly decreasing (Assumption 1), it will cost strictly less to perform tasks i < IL using low skill rather than medium skill workers; and similarly, it will be strictly less costly to perform tasks i > IL using medium skill rather than low skill workers. The same argument applies to the comparison of medium and high skill workers below or above the threshold IH. Note also that given Assumption 1, we do not need to compare the cost of producing a given task using low and high skill workers, since if the cost were the same with low and high skill workers, it would necessarily be strictly less with medium skill workers. Furthermore, because there is a positive supply of all three types of labor, the threshold tasks IL and IH must be both interior and different (i.e., 0 < IL < IH < 1).

Lemma 1 shows that the set of tasks will be partitioned into three (convex) sets, one performed by low skill workers, one performed by medium skill workers and one performed by high skill workers. Crucially, the boundaries of these sets, IL and IH, are endogenous and will respond to changes in skill supplies and technology. This introduces the first type of substitution that will play an important role in our model: the substitution of skills across tasks. Given the types of skills supplied in the market, firms (equivalently workers) will optimally choose which tasks will be performed by which skill groups.

The law of one price for skills

Even though workers of the same skill level perform different tasks, in equilibrium they will receive the same wage—a simple “law of one price” that has to hold in any competitive equilibrium. We now derive these prices.

Let p(i) denote the price of services of task i. Since we chose the final good as numeraire (setting its price to 1), we have

image

In any equilibrium, all tasks employing low skill workers must pay them the same wage, w l, since otherwise, given the competitive market assumption, no worker would supply their labor to tasks paying lower wages. Similarly, all tasks employing medium skill workers must pay a wage wM, and all tasks employing high skill workers must pay a wage wH. As a consequence, the value marginal product of all workers in a skill group must be the same in all the tasks that they are performing. In particular, in view of Lemma 1 and the production function (12), this implies:

image

image

image

This observation has a convenient implication. We must have that the price difference between any two tasks produced by the same type of worker must exactly offset the productivity difference of this type of worker in these two tasks. For example, for low skill workers we have

image (14)

for any i, i’ < IL, where the last equality defines PL as the price “index” of tasks performed by low skill workers. Note, however, that this price is endogenous not only because of the usual supply-demand reasons, but also because the set of tasks performed by low skill workers is endogenously determined. Similarly, for medium skill workers, i.e., for any IH > i, i’ > IL, we have

image (15)

and for high skill workers and any i, i’ > IH,

image (16)

The Cobb-Douglas technology (the unitary elasticity of substitution between tasks) in (11) implies that “expenditure” across all tasks should be equalized, and given our choice of numeraire, this expenditure should be equal to the value of total output. More specifically, the first-order conditions for cost minimization in the production of the final good imply that p(i)y(i) = p(i′)y(i′) for any i, i′. Alternatively, using our choice of the final good as the numeraire, we can write

image (17)

(In particular, note that the ideal price index for the final good, P, is defined such that y(i) / Y = p (i) /P, and our choice of numeraire implies that P = 1, which gives (17)).

Now consider two tasks i, i′ < IL (performed by low skill workers), then using the definition of the productivity of low skill workers in these tasks, we have

image

Therefore, for any i, i′ < IL, we conclude that l(i) = l(i′ and using the market clearing condition for low skilled workers, we must have

image (18)

This is a very convenient implication of the Cobb-Douglas production structure. With a similar argument, we also have

image (19)

image (20)

The above expressions are derived by comparing expenditures on tasks performed by the same type of worker. Now comparing two tasks performed by high and medium skill workers (IL < i < IH < i′), we obtain from Eq. (17) that image. Next using (14) and (15), we have

image

or

image (21)

Similarly, comparing two tasks performed by medium and high skill workers, we obtain

image (22)

No arbitrage across skills

The above derivations show that the key equilibrium objects of the model are the threshold tasks IL and IH. These will be determined by a type of “no arbitrage” condition equalizing the cost of producing these threshold tasks using different skills. We now derive these no arbitrage conditions and determine the threshold tasks.

Recall, in particular, that the threshold task IH must be such that it can be profitably produced using either high skilled or medium skilled workers. This is equivalent to task IH having the same equilibrium supply either when produced only with skilled or unskilled workers.67 That is, it implies our first no arbitrage condition (between high and medium skills) is:

image (23)

With an analogous argument, we obtain our second no arbitrage condition (between low and medium skills) as:

image (24)

Equilibrium wages and inequality

Once the threshold tasks, IL and IH, are determined, wage levels and earnings differences across skill groups can be found in a straightforward manner. In particular, wages are obtained simply as the values of the marginal products of different types of skills. For example, for low skill workers, this is:

image (25)

Equally, or perhaps even more, important than the level of wages are their ratios, which inform us about the wage structure and inequality. For example, comparing high and medium skill wages, we have

image

A more convenient way of expressing these is to use (21) and write the relative wages simply in terms of relative supplies and the equilibrium allocation of tasks to skill groups, given by IL and IH. That is,

image (26)

Similarly, the wage of medium relative to low skill workers is given by

image (27)

These expressions highlight the central role that allocation of tasks to skills plays in the model. Relative wages can be expressed simply as a function of relative supplies and equilibrium task assignments (in particular, the threshold tasks, IL and IH).

These equations, together with the choice of the numeraire, image, fully characterize the equilibrium. In particular, using (14)-(16), we can write the last equilibrium condition as:

image (28)

Equations (26) and (27) give the relative wages of high to medium and medium to low skill workers. To obtain the wage level for any one of these three groups, we need to use the price normalization in (28) together with (21) and (22) to solve out for one of the price indices, for example, PL, and then (25) will give wl and the levels of wM and wH can be readily obtained from (26) and (27).

4.2.1 Summary of equilibrium

The next proposition summarizes our equilibrium characterization and highlights several important features of the equilibrium.

Proposition 1.

There exists a unique equilibrium summarized by (IL ,IH , PL ,PM ,PH, wL, wM, wH) given by Eqs (21)-(28).

The only part of this proposition that requires proof is the claim that equilibrium is unique (the rest of it follows from the explicit construction of the equilibrium preceding the proposition). This can be seen by noting that in fact the equilibrium is considerably easier to characterize than it first appears, because it has a block recursive structure. In particular, we can first use (23) and (24) to determine IL and IH. Given these we can then compute relative wages from (26) and (27). Finally, to compute wage and price levels, we can use (21), (22), (25) and (28).

Figure 22 shows a diagrammatic representation of the equilibrium, in which curves corresponding to (23) and (24) determine IL and IH. Both curves are upward sloping in the (IL, IH) space, but the first one, (23), is steeper than the second one everywhere, (24)—see below for a proof. This establishes the existence of a unique intersection between the two curves in Fig. 22, and thus there exist unique equilibrium values of IL and IH. Given these values, PL, PM, PH, wL, wM and wH are uniquely determined from (21), (22) and (25)-(28).

image

Figure 22 Determination of equilibrium threshold tasks.

While Fig. 22 depicts the determination of the two thresholds, IL and , it does not illustrate the allocation of tasks to different types of skills (workers). We do this in Fig. 23, which can also be interpreted as a diagram showing “relative effective demand” and “relative effective supply”. In particular, we write (23) as follows:

image (29)

image

Figure 23 Equilibrium allocation of skills to tasks.

The right-hand side of this equation corresponds to the relative effective supply of high to medium skills (we use the term “effective” since the supplies are multiplied by their respective factor-augmenting technologies). The left-hand side, on the other hand, can be interpreted as the effective demand for high relative to medium skills. The left-hand side of (29) is shown as the outer curve (on the right) in Fig. 23. It is downward sloping as a function of IH (for a given level of IL) since αM (IH) /αH (IH) is strictly decreasing in view of Assumption 1. Similarly, we rewrite (24) as:

image

for given IH, and this expression has the same relative effective demand and supply interpretation. Since αL (IH) M (IH) is strictly decreasing again from Assumption 1, the left-hand side traces a downward sloping curve as a function of IL (for given IH) and is shown as the inner (on the left) curve in Fig. 23. Where the outer curve equals AHH/AMM, as shown on the vertical axis, gives the threshold task IH, and where the second curve is equal to AMM/ALL gives IL. This picture does not determine the two thresholds simultaneously as Fig. 22 does, since the dependence of the two curves on the other threshold is left implicit. Nevertheless, Fig. 23 is helpful in visualizing the equilibrium because it shows how equilibrium tasks are partitioned between the three types of skills. We will return to this figure when conducting comparative static exercises.

4.3. Special cases

We now study some special cases that help clarify the workings of the model. Suppose first that there are no medium skill workers. Assumption 1 in this case simply implies that αL (i) /αH (i) is strictly decreasing in i. Then we are back to a two-factor world as in the canonical model.

In addition, we could assume that instead of a continuum of tasks, there are only two tasks, one in which high skill workers have a strong comparative advantage and the other one in which low skill workers have a strong comparative advantage.68 This would be identical to the canonical model, except with a Cobb-Douglas production function (elasticity of substitution between high and low skill workers equal to one).

Another special case is found in the model studied by Acemoglu and Zilibotti (2001), who also assume that there are only two types of workers, high and low skill. In addition, Acemoglu and Zilibotti impose the following functional form on the schedule of comparative advantage schedules:

image (30)

Then an equivalent of (23) implies that all tasks below I will be performed by low skill workers and those above I will be performed by high skill workers. Moreover, exactly the same reasoning that led to the no arbitrage conditions, (23) and (24), now determines the single threshold task, I, separating tasks performed by low and high skill workers. In particular, using (30), the equivalent of (23) and (24) gives I as

image

In addition, the equivalent of (21) and (22) now gives the relative price of tasks performed by skilled compared to unskilled workers as

image

and the equivalent of (26) and (27) gives the skill premium as

image

Therefore, in this case the model is isomorphic to the canonical model with an elasticity of substitution equal to 2. This also shows that by choosing different forms for the comparative advantage schedules in the special case with only two types of skills, one could obtain any elasticity of substitution, or in fact any constant returns to scale production function (with an elasticity of substitution greater than or equal to 1) as a special case of the model shown here. This is the sense in which the canonical model, and thus all of economic forces emphasized by that model, are already embedded in our more general task-based framework.

Finally, another special case is useful both to show how insights from the two-skill model continue to hold in the three-skill model and also to illustrate how technical change in this task-based model can reduce the wages of some groups. For this, let us return to our general three-skill model introduced above, but suppose that

image (31)

where image is large and image is small. While this task productivity schedule for low skill workers is neither continuous nor strictly decreasing (and thus does not satisfy Assumption 1), we can easily take a strictly decreasing continuous approximation to (31), which will lead to identical results. The implication of this task schedule is that the no arbitrage condition between low and medium skills, (24), can only be satisfied at the threshold task image. This fixes one of the equilibrium thresholds, while the other one, image, is still determined in the usual fashion from the other no arbitrage condition, (23). Figure 24 adapts Fig. 22 and shows how the determination of equilibrium task thresholds looks in this case.

image

Figure 24 Determination of threshold high skill task (IH)with task assignment for low skilled workers fixed.

This case is of interest for two reasons. First, the model is now essentially identical to the two-skill version we have just discussed, since the set of tasks performed by low skill workers is fixed by the task productivity schedule (31) (without reference to other parameters in the model). Thus the mechanics of the equilibrium are simpler. Second, in the three-skill model, as we will see further in the next subsection, a variety of changes that directly affect IH will have an indirect impact on IL and these tend to “soften the blow” of some of these changes on the medium skill workers. With IL fixed at image, this will not be the case and thus the wage effects of certain types of technical change on medium skilled workers will be exacerbated in this case. We return to this special case again in the next subsection.

4.4. Comparative statics

The usefulness of any framework is related to the insights that it generates, which are most clearly illustrated by its comparative static results. We discuss these here.

To derive these comparative statics, we return to the general model, and take logs in Eq. (23) and (24) to obtain slightly simpler expressions, given by the following two equations:

image (32)

and

image (33)

where we have defined

image

both of which are strictly decreasing in view of Assumption 1. It can be easily verified that both of these curves are upward sloping in the (LH, IL) space, but (32) is everywhere steeper than (33) as claimed above, which also implies that there is indeed a unique intersection between the two curves as shown in Fig. 22.

Basic comparative statics

Basic comparative statics for the allocation of tasks across different skill groups can be obtained from this figure. For example, an increase in AH, corresponding to high skill biased technical change, shifts (32) inwards, as shown in Fig. 25, so both IL and IH decrease (the implications of an increase in H for task allocation, though not for wages, are identical). This is intuitive: if high skill workers become uniformly more productive because of high skill biased technical change—generating an expansion of the set of tasks in which they hold comparative advantage—then they should perform a larger range of tasks. Thus the allocation of tasks endogenously shifts away from medium to high skill workers (IH adjusts downward). If IL remained constant following the downward movement of IH, this would imply from (19) an “excess” supply of medium skill workers in the remaining tasks. Therefore, the indirect effect of the increase in AH (or H) is also to reduce IL, thus shifting some of tasks previously performed by low skill workers to medium skill workers.

image

Figure 25 Comparative statics.

Similarly, we can analyze the implications of skill biased technical change directed towards low skill workers, i.e., an increase in AL, (or a change in the supply of low skill workers, L), which will be to increase IL and IH. This has exactly the same logic (there are either more low skill workers or low skill workers are more productive, and thus they will perform more tasks, squeezing medium skill workers, who now have to shift into some of the tasks previously performed by high skill workers). The implications of an increase in Am, i.e., medium skill biased technical change, or of an increase in M again have a similar logic, and will reduce IL and increase , thus expanding the set of tasks performed by medium skill workers at the expense of both low and high skill workers. (Formally, in this case, the curve corresponding to (32) shifts up, while that for (33) shifts down). Each of these comparative statics illustrates the substitution of skills across tasks.

It is also useful to return to Fig. 23 to visually represent changes in the task allocation resulting from an increase in Ah, and we do this in Fig. 26. Such a change shifts the outer curve in Fig. 23 downward, as shown in Fig. 26, reducing IH. This first shift holds IL constant. However, the inner curve in this figure also shifts, as noted above and as highlighted by Figs 22 and 24. The decline in IH also shifts this curve down, this time reducing IL. Then there is a second round of adjustment as the decline in IL shifts the outer curve further down. Ultimately, the economy reaches a new equilibrium, as shown in Fig. 26.

image

Figure 26 Changes in equilibrium allocation.

It is a little more difficult to visually represent the changes in the wage structure resulting from changes in technology or supplies, because these depend on how IL changes relative to IH. Nevertheless, obtaining these comparative static results is also straightforward. To do this, let us consider a change in AH and let us totally differentiate (32) and (33). We thus obtain:

image

It can be easily verified that all of the terms in the diagonals of the matrix on the left hand side are negative (again from Assumption 1). Moreover, its determinant is positive, given by

image

Therefore,

image

confirming the insights we obtained from the diagrammatic analysis. But in addition, we can also now see that

image

Using these expressions, we can obtain comparative statics for how relative wages by skill group change when there is high skill biased technical change. A similar exercise can be performed for low and medium skill biased technical change. The next proposition summarizes the main results.

Proposition 2.

The following comparative static results apply:

1. (The response of task allocation to technology and skill supplies):
image, image and image; image, image and image; image, image and image.

2. (The response of relative wages to skill supplies):
image, image, image, image, image, and image if and only if image.

3. (The response of wages to factor-augmenting technologies):
image, image, image; image, image, image; image, image, and image if and only if image

Part 1 of this proposition follows by straightforward differentiation and manipulation of the expressions in (32) and (33) for IL and IH. Parts 2 and 3 then follow readily from the expressions for relative wages in (26) and (27) using the behavior of these thresholds. Here we simply give the intuition for the main results.

First, the behavior of IL and IH in Part 1 is intuitive as already discussed above. In particular, an increase in Ah or H expands the set of tasks performed by high skill workers and contracts the set of tasks performed by low and medium skill workers. This is equivalent to IL decreasing and IH increasing. An increase in Am or M similarly expands the set of tasks performed by medium skill workers and contracts those allocated to low and high skill workers. Mathematically, this corresponds to a decline in IL and an increase in IH. The implications of an increase in AL or L are analogous, and raise both IL and IH, expanding the set of tasks performed by low skill workers.

Second, the fact that relative demand curves are downward sloping for all factors, as claimed in Part 2, parallels the results in the canonical model (or in fact the more general results in Acemoglu (2007), for any model with constant or diminishing returns at the aggregate level). The new result here concerns the impact of an increase in M on wH/wL. We have seen that such an increase raises IH and reduces IL, expanding the set of tasks performed by medium skill workers at the expense of both low and high skill workers. This will put downward pressure on the wages of both low and high skill workers, and the impact on the relative wage, wH/wL, is ambiguous for reasons we will encounter again below. In particular, it will depend on the form of the comparative advantage schedules in the neighborhood of IL and IH. When the absolute value of image is high (relative to image), this implies that low skill workers have a strong comparative advantage for tasks below IL. Consequently, medium skill workers will not be displacing low skill workers much, instead having a relatively greater impact on high skill workers, and in this case wH/wL will decline. Conversely, when the absolute value of image is low relative to the absolute value of image, high skill workers have a strong comparative advantage for tasks right above IH, and medium skill tasks will expand at the expense of low skill workers relatively more, thus increasing wH/wL.

Third, the results summarized in Part 3 of the proposition, linking wages to technologies, are also intuitive. For example, an increase in AH, corresponding to high skill biased technical change, increases both wH/wL and wH/wM (i.e., high skill wages rise relative to both medium skill and low skill wages) as we may have expected from the canonical model. Perhaps more interestingly, an increase in AH also unambiguously reduces wm /wl despite the fact that it reduces the set of tasks performed by both medium and low skill workers. Intuitively, the first order (direct) effect of an increase in AH is to contract the set of tasks performed by medium skill workers. The impact on low skill workers is indirect, resulting from the fact that medium skill workers become cheaper and this makes firms expand the set of tasks that these workers perform. This indirect effect never dominates the direct effect, and thus the wages of medium skill workers decrease relative to those of low skill workers when there is high skill biased technical change.

The implications of medium skill biased technical changes are distinct from the canonical case. Medium skill biased technical changes have a direct effect on both high skill and low skill workers. Consequently, the behavior of wH/wL is ambiguous. Similarly to how an increase in M affects wH/wL, the impact of a rise in AM on wH/wL depends on the exact form of the comparative advantage schedules. When image is larger in absolute value than image, wH/wL is more likely to decline. Intuitively, this corresponds to the case in which low skill workers have strong comparative advantage for tasks below IL relative to the comparative advantage of high skill workers for tasks above IH. In this case, medium skill workers will expand by more into (previously) high skill tasks than (previously) low skill tasks. The levels of IL and 1 − IH also matter for this result; the higher is IL, the smaller is the effect on low skill wages of a given size reduction in the set of tasks performed by low skill workers (and vice versa for 1 − IH).

Finally, we can further parameterize the task productivity schedules, αL (i), αH (i) and αH (i), and perform comparative statics with respect to changes in these schedules. Naturally in this case unambiguous comparative statics are not always obtainable— though, as discussed below, changes that twist or shift these schedules in specific ways lead to intuitive results.

One attractive feature of the model, highlighted by the characterization results and the comparative statics in Proposition 2, is that all equilibrium objects depend on the set of tasks performed by the three different groups of workers. Depending on which set of tasks expands (contracts) more, wages of the relevant group increase (decrease). This is useful for understanding the workings of the model and also provides a potentially tractable connection between the model and the data.

Wage effects

Given the comparative static results on the relative wages and the numeraire equation, Eq. (28), we can derive predictions on the effects of technical change on wage levels. Although these are in general more complicated than the effects on relative wages, it should be intuitively clear that there is a central contrast between our framework and the canonical model: any improvement in technology in the canonical model raises the wages of all workers, whereas in our task-based framework an increase in Ah (high skill biased technical change), for example, can reduce the wages of medium skilled workers because it erodes their comparative advantage and displaces them from (some of) the tasks that they were previously performing.69

To see how high skill biased technical change, i.e., an increase in AH, can reduce medium skill wages more explicitly, let us work through a simple example. Return to the special case discussed above where the task productivity schedule for the low skill workers is given by (31), implying that image. Suppose also that βH (i) ≡ ln αM (i) − ln αH (i) is constant, so that the no arbitrage condition between high and medium skills in Fig. 25 (or Fig. 22) is flat. Now consider an increase in AH. This will not change IL (since image in any equilibrium), but will have a large impact on IH (in view of the fact that the no arbitrage locus between high and medium skills is flat). Let us next turn to an investigation of the implications of this change in Ah on medium skill wages.

Recall from the same argument leading to (25) that

wM = PMAM.

Since AM is constant, the effect on medium skill wages works entirely through the price index for tasks performed by medium skill workers. To compute this price index, let us use (21) and (22) to substitute for PL and PH in terms of PM in (28). This gives

image

Now differentiating this expression, we obtain

image

image

The first term is positive and results from the indirect effect of the increase in productivity of high skill workers on the wages of medium skill workers operating through q-complementarity (i.e., an increase in productivity increases the wages of all workers because it increases the demand for all types of labor). We know from our comparative static analysis that dIH/d ln AH is negative, and moreover given the assumptions we have imposed here, this effect is large (meaning that there will be a large expansion of high skill workers into tasks previously performed by medium skill workers following an increase in AH). Therefore, if αM (IH) ≥ αH (IH), AHHAMM, and 1 − IHIHIL, the remaining terms in this expression are all negative and can be arbitrarily large (and in fact, some of these inequalities could be reversed and the overall expression could still be negative and arbitrarily large). This implies that an increase in AH can significantly reduce PM and thus wM.

This result illustrates that in our task-based framework, in which changes in technology affect the allocation of tasks across skills, a factor-augmenting increase in productivity for one group of workers can reduce the wages of another group by shrinking the set of tasks that they are performing. This contrasts with the predictions of the canonical model and provides a useful starting point for interpreting the co-occurrence of rising supplies of high skill labor, ongoing skill biased demand shifts (stemming in part from technical change), and falling real earnings among less educated workers.

4.5. Task replacing technologies

A central virtue of our general task-based framework is that it can be used to investigate the implications of capital (embodied in machines) directly displacing workers from tasks that they previously performed. In general, we expect that tasks performed by all three skill groups are subject to machine displacement. Nevertheless, based on the patterns documented in the data above, as well as the general characterization of machine-task substitution offered by Autor et al. (2003), we believe the set of tasks most subject to machine displacement in the current era are those that are routine or codifiable. Such tasks are primarily, though not exclusively, performed by medium skill (semiskilled) workers. For this reason, let us suppose that there now exists a range of tasks [I′,I″] ⊂ [IL, IH ] for which αK (i) increases sufficiently (with fixed cost of capital r) so that they are now more economically preformed by machines than middle skill workers. For all the remaining tasks, i.e., for all ∉ [I′, I″], we continue to assume that αK (i) = 0. What are the implications of this type of technical change for the supply of different types of tasks and for wages?

Our analysis directly applies to this case and implies that there will now be a new equilibrium characterized by thresholds image and image. Moreover, we have the following proposition generalizing Lemma 1 and Proposition 1 for this case:

Proposition 3.

Suppose we start with an equilibrium characterized by thresholds [IL, IH] and technical change implies that the tasks in the range [I′, I″] ⊂ [IL, IH ] are now performed by machines. Then after the introduction of machines, there exists new unique equilibrium characterized by new thresholds image and image such that image for any image, m (i) = h(i) = 0 and image; for any image, l(i) = h(i) = 0 and image; for any i ∈ (I′, I″), l(i) = m(i) = h(i) = 0; and for any image, l(i) = m (i) = 0 and image.

This proposition immediately makes clear that, as a consequence of machines replacing tasks previously performed by medium skill workers, there will be a reallocation of tasks in the economy. In particular, medium skill workers will now start performing some of the tasks previously allocated to low skill workers, thus increasing the supply of these tasks (the same will happen at the top with an expansion of some of the high skill tasks). This proposition therefore gives us a way of thinking about how new technologies replacing intermediate tasks (in practice, most closely corresponding to routine, semiskilled occupations) will directly lead to the expansion of low skill tasks (corresponding to service occupations).

We next investigate the wage inequality implications of the introduction of these new tasks. For simplicity, we focus on the case where we start with [I′, I″] = ∅, and then the set of tasks expands to an interval of size ε′, where ε′ is small. This mathematical approach is used only for expositional simplicity because it enables us to apply differential calculus as above. None of the results depend on the set of tasks performed by machines being small.

Under the assumptions outlined here, and using the results in Proposition 3, we can write the equivalents of (32) and (33) as

image (34)

and

image (35)

When ε = 0, these equations give the equilibrium before the introduction of machines replacing medium skill tasks, and when ε = ε′ > 0, they describe the new equilibrium. Conveniently, we can obtain the relevant comparative statics by using these two equations. In particular, the implications of the introduction of these new machines on the allocation of tasks is obtained from the following system:

image

It is then straightforward to verify that

image

where recall that Δ is the determinant of the matrix on the left hand side. These results confirm the statements in Proposition 3 concerning the set of tasks performed by low and high skill workers expanding.

Given these results on the allocation of tasks, we can also characterize the impact on relative wages. These are stated in the next proposition. Here, we state them for the general case, rather than the case in which the range of tasks performed by machines is infinitesimal, since they can be generalized to this case in a straightforward manner (proof omitted).

Proposition 4.

Suppose we start with an equilibrium characterized by thresholds [IL, IH] and technical change implies that the tasks in the range [I′, I″] ⊂ [IL, IH] are now performed by machines. Then:

1. wH/wM increases;

2. wM/wL decreases;

3. wH/wL increases if image and wH/wL decreases if image.

The first two parts of the proposition are intuitive. Because new machines replace the tasks previously performed by medium skill workers, their relative wages, both compared to high and low skill workers, decline. In practice, this corresponds to the wages of workers in the middle of the income distribution, previously performing relatively routine tasks, falling compared to those at the top and the bottom of the wage distribution. Thus the introduction of new machines replacing middle skilled tasks in this framework provides a possible formalization of the “routinization” hypothesis and a possible explanation for job and wage polarization discussed in Section 2.

Note that the impact of this type of technical change on the wage of high skill relative to low skill workers is ambiguous; it depends on whether medium skill workers displaced by machines are better substitutes for low or high skill workers. The condition image is the same as the condition we encountered in Proposition 3, and the intuition is similar. The inequality image implies that medium skill workers are closer substitutes for low than high skill workers in the sense that, around IH, there is a stronger comparative advantage of high skill relative to medium skill workers than there is comparative advantage of low relative to medium skill workers around IL. The terms IL and (1 − IH) have a similar intuition. If the set of tasks performed by high skill workers is larger than the set of tasks performed by low skill workers ((1 − IH) > IL), the reallocation of a small set of tasks from high to medium skill workers will have a smaller effect on high skill wages than will an equivalent reallocation of tasks from low to medium skill workers (in this case, for low skill wages).

It appears plausible that in practice, medium skill workers previously performing routine tasks are a closer substitute for low skill workers employed in manual and service occupations than they are for high skill workers in professional, managerial and technical occupations.70 Indeed the substantial movement of medium skill high school and some college workers out of clerical and production positions and into service occupations after 1980 (Fig. 14) may be read as prima facie evidence that the comparative advantage of middle skill workers (particularly middle skill males) is relatively greater in low rather than high skill tasks. If so, Part 3 of this proposition implies that we should also see an increase in wH/wL. Alternatively, if sufficiently many middle skill workers displaced by machines move into high skill occupations, wH/wL may also increase. This latter case would correspond to one in which, in relative terms, low skill workers are the main beneficiaries of the introduction of new machines into the production process.

Let us finally return to the basic comparative statics and consider a change in the task productivity schedule of high skill workers, αH (i). Imagine, in particular, that this schedule is given by

image (36)

where image is a function that satisfies Assumption 1 and θ ≥ 1, and suppose that image is in the neighborhood of the equilibrium threshold task for high skill workers, IH. The presence of the term image in (36) implies that an increase in ? creates a rotation of the task productivity schedule for high skill workers around image.

Consider next the implications of an increase in θ. This will imply that high skill workers can now successfully perform tasks previously performed by medium skill workers, and hence high skill workers will replace them in tasks close to image (or close to the equilibrium threshold IH). Therefore, even absent machine-substitution for medium skill tasks, the model can generate comparative static results similar to those discussed above. This requires that the task productivity schedule for high skill (or low skill) workers twists so as to give them comparative advantage in the tasks that were previously performed by medium skill workers. The parallel roles that technology (embodied in machinery) and task productivity schedules (represented by α (·)) play in the model is also evident if we interpret the task productivity schedule of high skill workers more broadly as including not only their direct productivity when performing a task, but also their productivity when supervising (or operating) machinery used in those tasks. Thus the framework offers a parallel between the analytics of , on the one hand, new machinery that replaces medium skill workers and, on the other hand, changes in the task productivity schedule of high skill workers that enable them to replace medium skill workers in a subset of tasks.

4.6. Endogenous choice of skill supply

We have so far focused on one type of substitution, which we referred to as substitution of skills across tasks. A complementary force is substitution of workers across different skills, meaning that in response to changes in technology or factor supplies, workers may change the types of skills they supply to the market. We now briefly discuss this additional type of substitution.

Environment

To allow for substitution of workers across different types of skills, we now assume that each worker j is endowed with some amount of “low skill,” “medium skill,” and “high skill,” respectively 2.1j, mj and hj. Workers have one unit of time, which is subject to a “skill allocation” constraint

image

The worker’s income is

image

which captures the fact that the worker with skill vector (lj, mj, hj) will have to allocate his time between jobs requiring different types of skills. Generally, we will see that each worker will prefer to allocate his or her time entirely to one type of skill.

The production side of the economy is identical to the framework developed so far. Our analysis then applies once we know the aggregate amount of skills of different types. Let us denote these by

image

where El, Em and Eh are the sets of workers choosing to supply their low, medium and high skills respectively.

Clearly, the worker will choose to be in the set Eh only if

image

There are similar inequalities determining when a worker will be in the sets Em and El. To keep the model tractable, we now impose a type of single-crossing assumption in supplies. We order workers over the interval (0, 1) in such a way that lower indexed workers have a comparative advantage in supplying high relative to medium skills and in medium relative to low skills. More specifically, we impose:

Assumption 2.

hj/mj and mj/lj are both strictly decreasing in j and image and image.

This assumption implies that lower index workers have a comparative advantage in high skill tasks and higher index workers have a comparative advantage in low skill tasks. Moreover, at the extremes these comparative advantages are strong enough that there will always be some workers choosing to supply high and low skills. An immediate implication is the following lemma:

Lemma 2.

For any ratios of wages wH/wM and wM/wL , there exist J * (wH/wM) and J** (wM/wL) such that image for all j < J * (wH/wM), image for all j ∈ (J * (wH/wM), J ** (wM/wL)) and image for all j > J ** (wM/wL). J* (wH/wM) and J** (wM/wL) are both strictly increasing in their arguments.

Clearly, J* (wH /wM) and J ** (wM/wL) are defined such that

image (37)

In light of this lemma, we can write

image (38)

Note that given Assumption 2, J* (wH/wM) and J** (wM/wL) are both strictly increasing in their arguments. This implies that all else equal, a higher wage premium for high relative to medium skills encourages more workers to supply high rather than medium skills to the market. The same type of comparative static applies when there is a higher premium for medium relative to low skills. In particular, rewriting (38), we have

image (39)

The first expression, together with the fact that J* (wH/wM) is strictly increasing, implies that holding wM/wL constant, an increase in wH/wM increases H/L. Similarly, holding wH/wM constant, an increase in wM/wL increases M/L. Consequently, in addition to the comparative advantage of different types of skills across different tasks, we now have comparative advantage of workers in supplying different types of skills, which can be captured by two “upward sloping” relative supply curves.

The next proposition and the associated comparative static results exploit these insights.

Proposition 5.

In the model with endogenous supplies, there exists a unique equilibrium summarized by (IL, IH, PL, PM, PH, wL, wM, wH, J*(wH/wM), J**(wM/wL), L, M, H) given by Eqs (21)-(28), (37) and (38).

To prove the uniqueness of the equilibrium requires a little more work in this case, and the argument is thus relegated to the Theoretical Appendix.

Comparative statics and interpretation

The major change to the analysis introduced by allowing for the endogenous supply of skills is that when there is factor-augmenting technical change (or the introduction of capital that directly substitutes for workers in various tasks), the induced changes in wages will also affect supplies (even in the short run). Accordingly, there will also be substitution of workers across different types of skills. When, for example, new machines replace medium skill workers in a set of tasks, this will induce some of the workers that were previously supplying medium skills to now supply either low or high skills. If the more elastic margin is the one between medium and low skills, we would expect a significant fraction of the workers previously supplying medium skills and working in intermediate tasks to now supply low skills and perform relatively low-ranked tasks. This type of substitution therefore complements the substitution of skills across tasks. Finally, assuming that effective supplies are distributed unequally across workers, this model also generates a richer distribution of earnings inequality (and richer implications for overall inequality).

We can potentially interpret the changes in the US wage and employment structures over the last several decades through the lens of this framework. Let us take the comparative advantage schedules as given, and consider what combinations of factor-augmenting technical changes, introduction of new machines replacing tasks previously performed by different types of workers, and supply changes would be necessary to explain the patterns we observe. As we have seen, during the 1980s the US labor market experienced declining wages at the bottom of the distribution together with a relative contraction in employment in low wage occupations (though notably, a rise in employment in service occupations as underscored by Autor and Dorn (2010)), and also rising wages and employment in high skill occupations. In terms of our model, this would be a consequence of an increase in AH/AM and AM/ AL, which is the analog of skill biased technical change in this three factor model. We see a different pattern commencing in the 1990s, however, where the behavior of both employment shares and wage percentiles is U-shaped, as documented above. In terms of our model, this would result from rising penetration of information technology that replaces middle skill tasks (i.e., those with a substantial routine component). This will depress both the wages of medium skill workers and reduce employment in tasks that were previously performed by these medium skill workers. In the most recent decade (2000s), employment in low wage service occupations has grown even more rapidly. In terms of our model, this could be an implication of the displacement of medium skill workers under the plausible assumption that the relative comparative advantage of middle skill workers is greater in low than high skill tasks. This would therefore be an example of substitution of skills across tasks. This process is amplified in our model if we also allow for substitution of workers across skills. In that case, some of the workers previously supplying medium skills to routine tasks switch to supplying low skills to manual and service tasks.

We stress that this interpretation of the gross patterns in the data is speculative and somewhat coarse. Our objective here is not to provide a definitive explanation for the rich set of facts offered by the data but rather to offer a set of tools that may be applied towards a more refined set of explanations.71

4.7. Offshoring

Alongside technological advances, a major change potentially affecting the US and other advanced market economies over the past two decades has been the change in the structure of international trade, whereby instead of simply trading finished goods and services, there has been a greater tendency to engage in trade in tasks through “outsourcing” and “offshoring” certain tasks to countries where they can now be performed at lower cost. This process particularly applies to information-based tasks, which in recent years have become nearly costless and instantaneous to transport. An advantage of our task-based model is that it provides a unified framework for the analysis of this type of offshoring (or outsourcing) in a way that parallels the impact of machines replacing tasks previously performed by certain types of workers.

To illustrate how offshoring of tasks affects the structure of wages, suppose that a set of tasks [I′, I″] ⊂ [IL, IH can now be offshored to a foreign country, where wages are sufficiently low that such offshoring is cost minimizing for domestic final good producers. This assumption, of course, parallels our analysis of machines replacing tasks. In return, these firms can trade in the final good to ensure trade balance. In this case, it is straightforward to see that the equivalents of Propositions 3 and 4 will hold. In particular, the next proposition contains the relevant results summarizing the implications of offshoring for the allocation of tasks across workers and for wage inequality.

Proposition 6.

Suppose we start with an equilibrium characterized by thresholds [IL, IH ] and changes in technology allow tasks in the range [I′, I″] ⊂ [IL, IH] to be offshored. Then after offshoring, there exists new unique equilibrium characterized by new thresholds image and image such that image and for any image, m(i) = h(i) = 0 and image; for any image and image; for any i ∈ (I′, I″),l(i) = m (i) = h(i) = 0; and for any image and image. The implications of offshoring on the structure of wages are as follows:

1. wH/wM increases;

2. wM/wL decreases;

3. wH/wL increases if image and wH/wL decreases if image.

While the extension of the model to offshoring is immediate, the substantive point is deeper. The task-based model offers an attractive means, in our view, to place labor supply, technological change, and trading opportunities on equal economic footing. In our model, each is viewed as offering a competing supply of tasks that, in equilibrium, are allocated to productive activities in accordance with comparative advantage and cost minimization. This approach is both quite general and, we believe, intuitively appealing.

4.8. Directed technical change

We have so far investigated the implications of extending and, in some senses rewriting, the canonical model by allowing for the endogenous allocation of skill groups across tasks and workers across skill groups, and considering how technology and offshoring interact with this process. A final, potentially significant aspect of the economic environment absent from the canonical model is the endogeneity of technological progress to other changes in the labor market. We now discuss how this endogenous technology aspect can be incorporated to enrich our understanding of the operation of the labor market as well as the task-based model we have so far developed.

General discussion

Acemoglu (1998, 2002a) argues that both long run and medium run changes in US labor markets can be understood, at least partly, as resulting from endogenous changes in technology that responds to changes in supplies. From this perspective, Tinbergen’s race between supplies and technology is endogenously generated. Autonomous changes in skill supplies—resulting from demographic trends, evolving preferences, and shifts in public and private education—induce endogenous changes in technology, which increase the demand for skills. These demand shifts in turn lead to endogenous increases in skill supplies and, subsequently, further technological progress. While the impact of technological change on the supply of skills (responding to the skill premium) is standard, the response of technology to (relative) supplies is the more central and novel part of this explanation.

Formally, papers by Acemoglu (1998, 2002b) generalize the canonical model with two types of skills and two types of factor-augmenting technologies so as to endogenize the direction of technical change (and thus the relative levels of the two technologies). This work shows that an increase in the relative supply of skills will endogenously cause technology to become more skill biased. Moreover, this induced skill bias could be strong enough that endogenous technology (or “long-run”) relative demand curves can be upward sloping rather than downward sloping. This contrasts with the necessarily downward sloping relative demand for skills in the canonical model and also in the Ricardian model studied here (which, so far, holds technology constant). If the induced response of technology is sufficiently strong to make the endogenous relative demand curves upward sloping, then the increase in the skill premium that the US and many OECD labor markets experienced during the last three decades may be, at least in part, a response to the large increase in the supply of skills that commenced in these economies some decades earlier (around the 1960s).

Acemoglu (2002b) showed that for this strong form of endogenous skill bias (in the context of the canonical model), an elasticity of substitution between high and low skill labor greater than a certain threshold (which is somewhere between one and two) is sufficient. Thus for reasonable values of the elasticity of substitution, the induced response of technology to supplies will be strong enough to make the long-run price of skills increase in response to increases in the supply of skills—a stark contrast to the neoclassical model with constant technology, which always predicts that demand curves for factors are downward sloping.

A shift in focus from the canonical model to a task-based framework significantly enriches the mechanisms by which technology can respond endogenously to changes in (relative) supplies. In particular, in the context of our Ricardian model, we can allow two types of endogenous responses of technologies to changes in supplies. First, we can assume that factor-augmenting technologies respond to skill supplies (namely the terms AL, AM, and AH). This idea is analyzed by Acemoglu and Zilibotti (2001) for the special case of our model discussed in Section 4.3.72 Second, we can also allow for the comparative advantage schedules (the α (·)’s) to respond endogenously to skill supplies. This case is both more novel and more relevant to our discussion of the importance of tasks to understanding major labor market developments, and we pursue it here.

While we would have to impose specific functional forms to derive exact results on how comparative advantage schedules will endogenously respond to skill supplies, we can derive more abstract (though nevertheless quite tight) predictions about the direction of change of technology by using the more general framework introduced in Acemoglu (2007). To do this, let us suppose that technologies are presented by a finite dimensional variable (vector) θ ∈ Θ, and all three comparative advantage schedules are functions of this vector of technology, i.e., we have αL (i | θ), αM (i | θ) and αH(i | θ). Since any changes in the factor-augmenting terms, AL, AM, and AH, can be incorporated into these comparative advantage schedules, we hold the factor-augmenting terms constant.

We assume as in Acemoglu (2007) that a set of monopolistically competitive or oligopolistic firms invest in technologies θ, produce intermediate goods (or machines) embedding this technology, and sell them to final good producers. We also assume that the cost of producing technology θ is convex in θ. An equilibrium is given by a set of allocations (prices, employment levels and technology levels) such that taking technology levels as given, final good producers maximize profits, and simultaneously, taking the demands for technologies from the final good sector as given, technology monopolists (oligopolists) maximize profits. Also, following Acemoglu (2007), we will say that a change in technology is (absolutely) biased towards factor f (where f ∈ {L, M, H}) if the change in technology increases the price of that factor, wf (where again f Ῥ {L, M, H}) at the prevailing factor proportions (i.e., when the supplies of the three factors are given by L, M, and H).73 Mathematically, a change in technology is biased towards factor f if wf(L, M, H | θ), written as a function of the supply levels of the three factors, is nondecreasing in θ. In particular, when θ is a continuous one-dimensional variable (i.e., θent) and the wage levels are differentiable, this is equivalent to:74

image

Moreover, we say that an increase in the supply of a factor induces technical change that is weakly biased towards that factor (again focusing on the continuous one-dimensional variable representing technology) if

image

where Ef is the supply level of factor f (for f ∈ {L, M, H}), wf(E-f, Ef | θ) = wf (L, M, E|θ), and dθ/dEf is the induced change in technology resulting from a change in the supply of this factor. Using the same notation, we also say that an increase in the supply of a factor induces technical change that is strongly biased towards that factor if

image

where the notation makes it clear that in contrast to the weak bias case, we are evaluating in this case the change in the price as the supply also changes (and thus we have the first term, which is the direct effect of a change in supply for given technology). Put differently, we are now tracing an “endogenous technology” demand curve. In the case of weak bias, however, factor supplies are held constant (as emphasized by the use of the partial derivative), so weak bias requires only that the technology-constant demand curve shifts in favor of the factor whose increased supply induced the initial change in technology (represented by dθ/dEf).

Without specifying either the shape of the comparative advantage schedules or how specifically they depend upon θ, the results in Acemoglu (2007) enable us to have the following two results. Here we state the results without the full mathematical details. More rigorous statements of these propositions follow the formulation in Acemoglu (2007), where proofs for these results can be found.

Proposition 7.

Under regularity conditions (which ensure the existence of a locally isolated equilibrium), an increase in the supply of factor f (for f ∈ {L,M, H}) will induce technical change weakly biased towards that factor.

This proposition thus shows that even under the richer form of technical change considered in our Ricardian model (in particular shifts in the comparative advantage schedules in response to changes in supplies), the response of the economy to any increase in the supply of a factor will be to undergo an endogenous change in technology that weakly increases the demand for that factor. Therefore, even in the context of the richer task-based approach developed here, this result implies that there are strong theoretical reasons to expect the increase in the supply of high skill workers, which the US and OECD economies experienced over the past three decades, to have induced the development of technologies favoring these high skill workers. This result does not, however, state that this induced response will be strong enough to increase the price of the factor that it is becoming more abundant (i.e., it does not state that long-run demand curves incorporating endogenous technological change will be upward sloping). This question is investigated in the next proposition.

Proposition 8.

Under regularity conditions (which ensure the existence of a locally isolated equilibrium), an increase in the supply of factor f (for f ∈ {L, M, H}) will induce technical change strongly biased towards that factor—thus increasing the wage of that factor—if and only if the aggregate production possibilities set of the economy is locally nonconvex in factor f and technology θ.

This local nonconvexity condition implies, loosely, that if we double both the supply of factor f and the quality or quantity of technology θ, output will more than double. This form of nonconvexity is quite common in models of endogenous technical change (e.g., Romer, 1990, and see Acemoglu, 2002b), and it is not a very demanding condition for one primary reason: the technology is not chosen by the same set of firms that make the factor demand decisions; if it were, and if these firms were competitive, then the equilibrium could not exhibit such local nonconvexity. In our setting (as in Acemoglu, 2007), however, final good producers make factor demands decisions taking technology as given (while facing constant or diminishing returns), and technology monopolists or oligopolists make technology decisions taking the factor demands of final good producers as given (while again facing convex decision problems). In this formulation, the aggregate production possibilities set of the economy need not be locally convex (in each of the factors and the vector of technologies). For example, the result on upward sloping relative demand curves with endogenous technologies in Acemoglu (1998, 2002b) mentioned above corresponds to this type of nonconvexity, and as explained above, only relies on an elasticity of substitution greater than a certain threshold (between one and two). Therefore, strong bias of technology does not require unduly strong conditions, though of course whether it applies in practice is an empirical question on which there is limited evidence.

An example

We now provide a simple example illustrating how endogenous technology enriches the insights of our task-based model here (and conversely, how the task-based approach enriches the implications of existing models of directed technical change). Let us return to the task productivity schedule for high skill workers in (36) discussed in Section 4.5. Suppose, as we did there, that the equilibrium threshold task for high skill workers, IH, is close to image. Assume, however, that θ is now an endogenous variable, taking the value or θlow or θhigh > θlow. As in the general directed technical change framework described so far in this section, we continue to assume that θ is chosen by profit maximizing technology firms, which then sell machines (intermediate goods) embodying this technology to final good producers.

When will technology firms choose θhigh instead of θlow? Recall that, as a starting point, the equilibrium threshold IH is close to image. This implies that high skill workers are not performing many tasks below image (or in fact, if image, they are not performing any tasks below image). As a result, the return from increasing their productivity in tasks lower than image would be limited. Therefore, we can presume that to start with, θ = θlow.

Now imagine that the supply of high skill workers, H, increases. The general results we have discussed so far imply that technology will adjust (if technology is indeed endogenous) in a way that is biased towards high skill workers. However, these results are silent on what the impact of this induced change in technology will be on medium skill (or low skill) workers. With the specific structure outlined here, however, this endogenous technology response will create effects that are predictable. In particular, as H increases, the equilibrium threshold task for high skill workers, IH, will decline given the existing technology (θlow). Suppose that after the change, IH lies significantly below image. This generates a potentially large economic return to increasing the productivity of high skill workers in the tasks on the interval IH to image. This is accomplished by raising θ from θlow to θhigh. From our discussion in Section 4.5, however, we know that this corresponds to a change in technology that will induce high skill workers to become more productive in tasks previously performed by medium skill workers, which potentially further contracts the set of tasks performed by medium skill workers. As per our interpretation in Section 4.5, this process is analytically similar to the case in which new machines replace medium skill workers in the tasks that they were previously performing.

Hence, the endogenous technology response to an expansion in the supply of high skill workers (in this case from θlow to θhigh) may not only bias technology in their favor (i.e., raising their productivity), but may also induce them to perform some of the tasks previously performed by medium skill workers (either directly, or by supervising the operation of new machinery). With an analysis similar to that in Section 4.4, this process of endogenous technological change can lead to a decline in the wages of medium skill workers.

Overall, this example illustrates how the endogenous response of technology to changes in relative supplies—or, similarly, to changes in trade or offshoring possibilities— may lead to a rich set of changes in both task productivities and the allocation of skills to tasks. Whether this endogenous technology response is in fact a central determinant of the changes in task allocations that have taken place over the past 30 years is an area for further research.

5. Comparative advantage and wages: an empirical approach

We finally take a step back from the theoretical framework to consider how the broad implications of the model might be brought to the data. A key implication of the theory is that holding the schedule of comparative advantage (that is, the α (·)’ s) constant, changes in the market value of tasks should affect the evolution of wages by skill group. In particular, our model makes a relatively sharp prediction: if the relative market price of the tasks in which a skill group holds comparative advantage declines, the relative wage of that skill group should also decline—even if the group reallocates its labor to a different set of tasks (i.e., due to the change in its comparative advantage).

Critical to this prediction is the distinction made between the wages paid to a skill group and the wages paid to a given task—a distinction that is meaningful because the assignment of skills to tasks is endogenous. To see the implications of this distinction, consider a technological change that raises the productivity of high skill workers in all tasks (e.g., an increase in AH). The model implies that this would expand the set of tasks performed by high skill workers (i.e., lower IH), so that some tasks formerly performed by medium skilled workers would now be performed by high skill workers instead. Thus, relative wages paid to workers performing these (formerly) “middle skill” tasks would actually increase (since they are now performed by the more productive high skill workers). But crucially, our analysis also shows that the relative wage of medium skill workers, who were formerly performing these tasks, would fall.75

This discussion underscores that because of the endogenous assignment of skills to tasks, it is possible for the relative wage paid to a task to move in the opposite direction from the relative wage paid to the skill group that initially performed the task.76 By contrast, the relative wage paid to a given skill group always moves in the same direction as its comparative advantage—that is, a technological change that increases the productivity of a skill group necessarily raises its relative wage. Simultaneously, it alters the set of tasks to which that skill is applied.

As a stylized example of how this insight might be brought to the data, we study the evolution of wages by skill groups, where skill groups are defined according to their initial task specialization across abstract-intensive, routine-intensive, and manualintensive occupations. We take these patterns of occupational specialization as a rough proxy for comparative advantage. Consider the full set of demographic groups available in the data, indexed by gender, education, age, and region. At the start of the sample in 1959 , we assume that these groups have self-selected into task specialities according to comparative advantage, taking as given overall skill supplies and task demands (reflecting also available technologies and trade opportunities). Specifically, let image and image be the employment shares of a demographic group in abstract, routine and manual/service occupations in 1959, where s denotes gender, e denotes education group, ‘ denotes age group, and k denotes region of the country.77 By construction, we have that image.

Let wsejkt be the mean log wage of a demographic group in year t and Δwsejkτ be the change in w during decade τ. We then estimate the following regression model:

image (40)

where δ, ϕ, λ, and π are vectors of time, education, age and region dummies. The image and image coefficients in this model estimate the decade specific slopes on the initial occupation shares in predicting wage changes by demographic group. The routine task category image serves as the omitted reference group. Thus we are conceiving of demographic groups as skill groups, and the γ parameters as reflecting their patterns of comparative advantage in 1959.

Our working hypothesis is that the labor market price of routine tasks has declined steeply over the last three decades due to rising competition from information technology. Conversely, we conjecture that the labor market prices of abstract and manual tasks will have increased since these tasks are relatively complementary to the routine tasks (now produced at lower cost and in greater quantity by capital). This hypothesis implies that we should expect the wages of workers with comparative advantage in either abstract or manual/service tasks to rise over time while the opposite should occur for skill groups with comparative advantage in routine tasks. Formally, we anticipate that image and image will rise while the intercepts measuring the omitted routine task category (δτ) will decline. These expected effects reflect the rising earnings power of skill groups that hold comparative advantage in abstract and manual/service tasks relative to skill groups that hold comparative advantage in routine tasks.

Table 10 presents initial descriptive OLS regressions of Eq. (40) using Census wage and occupation data from years 1959 through 2008. Although this empirical exercise is highly preliminary—indeed, it is intended as an example of an empirical approach rather than a test of the theory—the pattern of results appears roughly consistent with expectations. Starting with the estimate for males in column 1, we find a rise in relative wages from the 1980s forward for male skill groups that were initially specialized in abstract tasks. Similarly, starting in the 1980s, we see a substantial increase in the relative wage of male demographic subgroups that had an initial specialization in manual/service tasks. In fact, this task specialty moved from being a strongly negative predictor of wages in the 1960s and 1970s, to a positive predictor from the 1980s forward.

Since the interactions between time dummies and each demographic group’s initial routine occupation share image serves as the omitted reference category in the regression model, these time intercepts estimate wage trends for demographic groups that hold comparative advantage in routine tasks. Consistent with a decline in the wages of workers with comparative advantage in routine tasks, the routine occupation intercepts fall from strongly positive in the 1960s to weakly positive in the 1970s, and then become negative from the 1980s forward.

The second column repeats the initial estimate, now adding main effects for education, age group, and region. Here, the model is identified by differences in initial comparative advantage among workers within education-age-region cells. The inclusion of these demographic group main effects does not appreciably alter the results.

Columns 3 and 4 repeat these estimates for females. As with males, the estimates indicate rising relative wages from 1980 forward for female demographic subgroups that were initially specialized in abstract tasks. The pattern for the service tasks is less clear cut for females, however. Service task specialization is surprisingly associated with strong wage gains during the 1960s and 1970s. This association becomes negative in the 1980s, which is not consistent with the hypothesis above. It then becomes positive (as predicted) in the final two decades of the sample (column 4).

Finally, the routine task specialty intercepts for females go from weakly positive in the 1960s to strongly negative in the 1970s forward. Thus, the decline in the routine task intercepts starts a decade earlier for females than males. Inclusion of main effects for education, age group and region generally strengthens these results and brings them closer in line with our hypotheses.

We stress that this initial cut of the data is intended as an example of how linking the comparative advantage of skill groups to changes over time in the demands for their task specialties could be used to explore and interpret the evolution of wages by skill group. The evidence in Table 10 is therefore only suggestive. But we believe the premise on which this exercise is based is a sound one and has the virtue of exploring a theoretically-grounded set of empirical implications. This exercise and our discussion at the beginning of this section, also emphasize that an alternative, and at first appealing, approach of regressing wages on measures of current tasks performed by workers could generate potentially misleading results.78 In contrast, the approach here exploits the fact that task specialization in the cross section is informative about the comparative advantage of various skill groups, and it marries this source of information to a well-specified hypothesis about how the wages of skill groups that differ in their comparative advantage should respond to changes in technology, shifts in trade and offshoring opportunities, and fluctuations in skill supplies.79

6. Concluding remarks

In this paper, we argue that to account for recent changes in the earnings and employment distribution in the United States and other advanced economies, and also to develop a better understanding of the impact of technology on labor market outcomes, it is necessary to substantially enrich the canonical model. Specifically, we propose relaxing the assumptions implicit in this model that: (i) the assignment of skills to tasks is fixed (or, more precisely, that skills and tasks are equivalent); and (ii) technical change takes a purely factor-augmenting form. These strictures, we believe, prevent the model from shedding light on key phenomena presented by the data and documented above. These include: (1) substantial declines in real wages of low skill workers over the last three decades; (2) marked, non-monotone changes in earnings levels in different parts of the earnings distribution during different decades; (3) the polarization in the earnings distribution, particularly associated with a “convexification” in the returns to schooling (and perhaps in the returns to other skills); (4) systematic, non-monotone changes in the distribution of employment across occupations of various skill levels; (5) the introduction of new technologies—as well as offshoring possibilities in part enabled by those technologies— that appear to directly substitute machines (capital) for a range of tasks previously performed by (moderately-skilled) workers.

Having documented these patterns and highlighted why they are particularly challenging for the canonical model, we argue that a task-based framework, in which tasks are the basic unit of production and the allocation of skills to tasks is endogenously determined, provides a fruitful alternative framework.

In the task-based framework proposed in this chapter, a unique final good is produced combining services of a continuum of tasks. Each worker has one of three types of skills, low, medium and high. We assume a pattern of comparative advantage such that tasks are ranked in order of complexity, and medium skill workers are more productive than low skill workers, and less productive than high skill workers in more complex tasks. We show that the equilibrium allocation of skills to tasks is determined by two thresholds, IL and IH, such that all tasks below the lower threshold (IL) are performed by low skill workers, all tasks above the higher threshold (IH) are performed by high skill workers, and all intermediate tasks are performed by medium skill workers. In terms of mapping this allocation to reality, we think of the lowest range of tasks as corresponding to service occupations and other manual occupations that require physical flexibility and adaptability but little training. These tasks are straightforward for the large majority of workers, but require a degree of coordination, sightedness, and physical flexibility that are not yet easily automated. The intermediate range corresponds to moderately skilled blue-collar production and white-collar administrative, clerical, accounting and sales positions that require execution of well-defined procedures (such as calculating or monitoring) that can increasingly be codified in software and performed by inexpensive machinery. Finally, the highest range corresponds to the abstract reasoning, creative, and problem-solving tasks performed by professionals, managers and some technical occupations. These tasks require a skill set that is currently challenging to automate because the procedures used to perform these tasks are poorly understood.

We show that despite the endogenous allocation of skills to tasks, the model is tractable, and that relative wages among skill groups depend only on relative supplies and the equilibrium threshold tasks. Comparative statics of relative wages then depend on how these thresholds change. For example, whenever IL increases (for fixed supplies of low, medium and high skills in the market), there is a larger range of tasks performed by low skill workers and their relative wages increase. Similarly, when IH decreases, the wages of high skill workers increase and when IHIL increases, the relative wages of medium skill workers increase. We also show that an increase in the supply of high skills, or alternatively, technical change that makes high skill workers uniformly more productive, reduces IH (intuitively, because there is greater “effective supply” of high skills). In addition to this direct effect, such a change also has an indirect effect on IL, because the decrease in IH, at given IL, creates an “excess supply” of medium skill workers in intermediate tasks and thus induces firms to substitute these workers for tasks previously performed by low skill workers.

A noteworthy implication of this framework is that technical change favoring one type of worker can reduce the real wages of another group. Therefore, the richer substitution possibilities between skill groups afforded by the endogenous allocation of skills to tasks highlights that, distinct from canonical model, technical change need not raise the wages of all workers. As importantly, this framework enables us to model the introduction of new technologies that directly substitute for tasks previously performed by workers of various skill levels. In particular, we can readily model how new machinery (for example, software that corrects spelling and identifies grammatical errors) can directly substitute for job tasks performed by various skill groups. This type of technical change provides a richer perspective for interpreting the impact of new technologies on labor market outcomes. It also makes negative effects on the real wages of the group that is being directly replaced by the machinery more likely. These same ideas can also be easily applied to the process of outsourcing and offshoring. Since some tasks are far more suitable to offshoring than others (e.g., developing web sites versus cutting hair), it is natural to model offshoring as a technology (like computers) that potentially displaces domestic workers of various skill levels performing certain tasks, thereby altering their wages by increasing their effective supply and causing a shift in the mapping between skills and tasks (represented by IL and IH).

We also show how the model can be extended to incorporate choices on the side of workers to allocate their labor hours between different types of activities and how technical change can be endogenized in this framework. When the direction of technical change and the types of technologies being adopted are endogenous, not only do we obtain the same types of insights that the existing literature on directed technical change generates, but we can also see how the development and the adoption of technologies substituting machines for tasks previously performed by (middle skill) workers can emerge as a response to changes in relative supplies.

We view our task-based framework and the interpretation of the salient labor market facts through the lenses of this framework as first steps towards developing a richer and more nuanced approach to the study of interactions between technology, tasks and skills in modern labor markets. Indeed, it will be a successful first step if this framework provides a foundation for researchers to generate new theoretical ideas and test them empirically. In the spirit of a first step, we suggest one means of parsing changes in real wages over time by demographic groups that is motivated by this theoretical model. Clearly, more needs to be done to derive tighter predictions from this framework and from other complementary task-based approaches for the evolution of earnings and employment distribution both in the United States and other countries. We view this as a promising area for future research.

We also believe that the study of a number of closely related topics in labor economics may be enriched when viewed through this task perspective, though we must only mention them cursorily here:

Organizational change: Acemoglu (1999), Bresnahan (1999), Bresnahan et al. (1999), Caroli and van Reenen (1999), Kremer and Maskin (1996), Garicano (2000), Autor et al. (2002), Dessein and Santos (2006), and Garicano and Rossi-Hansberg (2006) among others, have emphasized the importance of organizational changes as an autonomous factor shaping the demand for skills or, alternatively, as a phenomenon accompanying other equilibrium changes impacting earnings inequality. A task-based approach is implicit in several of these studies, and a systematic framework, like the one proposed here, may enrich the study of the interactions between organizational changes and the evolution of the distribution of earnings and employment. We also note that substitution of machines for tasks previously performed by semi-skilled workers, or outsourcing and offshoring of their tasks, may necessitate significant organizational changes. One might reinterpret the changes in equilibrium threshold tasks in our model as corresponding to a form of organizational change. One might alternatively take the perspective that organizational change will take place in a more discontinuous manner and will involve changes in several dimensions of the organization of production (managerial and job practices, the allocation of authority within the organization, the form of communication, and the nature of responsibility systems). In addition, organizational change might also create tasks, demanding both low and high skill labor inputs, that were not previously present, exerting another force towards polarization. These considerations suggest that the two-way interaction between these organizational changes and the allocation of tasks to different skill groups and technologies is an important area for theoretical and empirical study.

Labor market imperfections: The framework proposed here crucially depends on competitive labor markets, where each worker is paid the value of his or her marginal product. In reality, many frictions—some related to information and search and others resulting from collective bargaining, social norms, firing costs and minimum wage legislation—create a wedge between wages and marginal products. The allocation of skills to tasks is more complex in the presence of such labor market imperfections. Moreover, some of these imperfections might directly affect the choice of threshold tasks. The implications of different types of technical change are potentially quite different in the presence of labor market imperfections, and may in particular depend on the exact form of these frictions. Further work tractably integrating various forms of labor market imperfections within a framework that incorporates the endogenous allocation of skills to tasks appears to be another fruitful area for research.

The role of labor market institutions: Closely related to labor market imperfections, a perspective that emphasizes the importance of tasks also calls for additional study of the role of labor market institutions in the changes in employment and inequality in recent decades. Certain work practices, such as collective bargaining and unionized workplace arrangements, might have greater impact on the earnings distribution because of the way they impact the assignment of tasks to labor or capital. These institutions may restrict the substitution of machines for certain tasks previously performed by workers, particularly in the case of labor unions. Additionally, even if the substitution of machines for labor is not fully impeded, it may occur more slowly than otherwise due to the influence of these institutions. If this force raises the opportunity cost of union membership for some subset of workers (for example, by depressing the return to skill), it may undermine union coalitions, leading to an amplified impact on employment and wages (e.g., Acemoglu et al., 2001). Richer and empirically more important forms of two-way interactions between technology and unions and other workplace arrangements are another fruitful area for future research.

Cross-country trends: We have shown that changes in the occupation of distribution are surprisingly comparable across a sizable set of advanced economies. This fact not withstanding, changes in the earnings distribution have been quite different in different countries (e.g., Davis, 1992; Blau and Kahn, 1996; Card et al., 1996; Katz and Autor, 1999; Card and Lemieux, 2001a,b; Atkinson, 2008; Dustmann et al., 2009; Atkinson et al., 2010; Boudarbat et al., 2010). One interpretation of these facts is that while many advanced countries have experienced similar technological forces that have altered occupational structures, the manner in which their labor markets (in particular their wage schedules) has responded to them have been far from identical. As of yet, there is no satisfactory understanding of the root causes of these differences. One possibility is that the adoption of new technologies either replacing or complementing workers in certain tasks requires up-front fixed investments, and the incentives for adopting these technologies are not only affected by labor supply and demand, but also by existing regulations. It is then possible that firms select different technologies in different countries in accordance with these constraints, and this may affect the evolution of real wages for various skill groups. For example, Acemoglu (2003) suggests a model in which institutionally-imposed wage compression encourages the adoption of technologies that increase the productivity of low skill workers and thus slows demand shifts against these skill groups.

Changes in male-female and white-nonwhite wage differentials: Our empirical analysis highlighted the substantial differences in the evolution of employment and earnings between men and women. The framework and data both suggest that the comparatively poor labor market performance of males may in part be due to the fact that men were more heavily represented in middle skill production occupations that were undercut by automation and offshoring.80 A similar contrast might exist between white and nonwhite workers. Juhn et al. (1991) provided an early attempt to explain the differential evolution of earnings and employment by race and gender as a result of skill biased demand shifts. A similar comprehensive exercise, with a richer conception of technology potentially rooted in a task-based approach, is a logical next step to obtain a more complete understanding of the recent changes in the distribution of employment and earnings among minority and non-minority groups.

The importance of service occupations: Our framework highlights why recent technical change might have increased employment in service occupations. The idea here is related to Baumol’s classic argument, where the demand for labor from sectors experiencing slower technical advances might be greater if there is sufficient complementarity between the goods and services that they and more rapidly growing sectors produce (Baumol, 1967; see also, Acemoglu and Guerrieri, 2007; Pissarides and Ngai, 2007; Autor and Dorn, 2009, 2010). Our framework captures this phenomenon to some degree, but because of the unit elasticity of substitution across all tasks, the extent of this effect is limited. A somewhat different variant of our framework may be necessary to better capture the evolution of the demand for services during the past several decades.

Data appendix

May/Outgoing Rotation Groups Current Population Survey

Wages are calculated using May/ORG CPS data for earnings years 1973–2009 for all workers aged 16–64 who are not in the military, institutionalized or self-employed. Wages are weighted by CPS sample weights. Hourly wages are equal to the logarithm of reported hourly earnings for those paid by the hour and the logarithm of usual weekly earnings divided by hours worked last week for non-hourly workers. Top-coded earnings observations are multiplied by 1.5. Hourly earners of below $1.675/hour in 1982 dollars ($3.41/hour in 2008 dollars) are dropped, as are hourly wages exceeding 1/35th the top-coded value of weekly earnings. All earnings are deflated by the chain-weighted (implicit) price deflator for personal consumption expenditures (PCE). Allocated earnings observations are excluded in all years, except where allocation flags are unavailable (January 1994 to August 1995).

March Current Population Survey

Wages are calculated using March CPS data for earnings years 1963–2008 for full-time, full-year workers aged 16–64, excluding those who are in the military or self-employed. Full-time, full-year workers are those who usually worked 35 or more hours per week and worked forty or more weeks in the previous year. Weekly earnings are calculated as the logarithm of annual earnings divided by weeks worked. Calculations are weighted by CPS sampling weights and are deflated using the personal consumption expenditure (PCE) deflator. Earnings of below $67/week in 1982 dollars ($136/week in 2008 dollars) are dropped. Allocated earnings observations are excluded in earnings years 1967 forward using either family earnings allocation flags (1967–1974) or individual earnings allocation flags (1975 earnings year forward).

Census/American Community Survey

Census Integrated Public Use Micro Samples for years 1960,1970,1980,1990, and 2000, and American Community Survey for 2008 are used in this paper. All Census samples include 5% of the population, except 1970, which includes 1% of the population. Wages are calculated for full-time, full-year workers aged 16–64, excluding those who are in the military, institutionalized or self-employed. Weekly earnings are calculated as the logarithm of annual earnings divided by weeks worked. Calculations are weighted by Census sampling weights and are deflated using the personal consumption expenditure (PCE) deflator.

Education categories used for the May/ORG and March CPS files and Census/ACS files are equivalent to those employed by Autor et al. (2003), based on the consistent classification system proposed by Jaeger (1997).

Dictionary of Occupational Titles

The US Labor Department’s Dictionary of Occupational Titles (DOT) task measures used in this paper follow the construction of Autor et al. (2006), who collapse Autor et al.’s (2003) original five task measures into three categories: routine, manual and abstract. Routine corresponds to a simple average of two DOT measures: “set limits, tolerances and standards,” and “finger dexterity.” Manual corresponds to the DOT measure “eye-hand-foot coordination”. Abstract is the simple average of two DOT measures: “direction, control and planning” and “GED math.” DOT task measures are converted from their original 14,000 detailed occupations to 326 consistent occupations, which allow for merging with CPS and Census data files.

O*net

O*NET task measures used in this paper are composite measures of O*NET Work Activities and Work Context Importance scales:

Non-routine cognitive: Analytical

4.A.2.a.4 Analyzing data/information

4. A. 2. b. 2 Thinking creatively

4. A. 4. a. 1 Interpreting information for others

Non-routine cognitive: Interpersonal

4. A. 4. a. 4 Establishing and maintaining personal relationships

4. A. 4. b. 4 Guiding, directing and motivating subordinates

4. A. 4. b. 5 Coaching/developing others

Routine cognitive

4.C.3.b.7 Importance of repeating the same tasks

4.C.3.b.4 Importance of being exact or accurate

4.C.3.b.8 Structured v. Unstructured work (reverse)

Routine manual

4.C.3.d.3 Pace determined by speed of equipment

4.A.3.a.3 Controlling machines and processes

4.C.2.d.1.i Spend time making repetitive motions

Non-routine manual physical

4.A.3.a.4 Operating vehicles, mechanized devices, or equipment

4.C.2.d.1.g Spend time using hands to handle, control or feel objects, tools or controls

1.A.2.a.2 Manual dexterity

1.A.1.f.1 Spatial orientation

Offshorability

4.C.1.a.2.l Face to face discussions (reverse)

4.A.4.a.5 Assisting and Caring for Others (reverse)

4.A.4.a.8 Performing for or Working Directly with the Public (reverse)

4.A.1.b.2 Inspecting Equipment, Structures, or Material (reverse)

4.A.3.a.2 Handling and Moving Objects (reverse)

4.A.3.b.4 0.5 *Repairing and Maintaining Mechanical Equipment (reverse)

4.A.3.b.5 0.5 *Repairing and Maintaining Electronic Equipment (reverse)

O*NET scales are created using the O*NET-SOC occupational classification scheme, which we collapse into SOC occupations. Each scale is then standardized to have mean zero and standard deviation one, using labor supply weights from the pooled 2005/6/7 Occupational Employment Statistics (OES) Survey, one of the few large surveys that uses the SOC occupational classification system. The composite task measures listed above are equal to the summation of their respective constituent scales, then standardized to mean zero and standard deviation one. In order to merge the composite task measures with the Census data, the task measures are collapsed to the Census 2000 occupational code level using the OES Survey labor supply weights and then collapsed to the 326 consistent occupations as detailed in Autor and Dorn (2010), using Census 2000 labor supply weights.

Theoretical appendix: uniqueness of equilibrium in proposition 5

Let us proceed in steps. First, rewrite (23) and (24) as

image (41)

and

image (42)

where recall that βH (I) ≡ ln αM (I) − ln αH (I) and βL (I) ≡ ln αL (I) − ln αM (I) are both strictly decreasing in view of Assumption 1. Now substituting these two equations into (38), we have

image

where we denote derivatives of these functions by image, image, and image and image for the first and second derivatives of ΓM. The arguments so far immediately imply that image, image and image and image. Now rewriting (32) and (33) substituting for these, we again have a two-equation system in IH and IL characterizing the equilibrium. It is given by

image (43)

and

image (44)

Let us evaluate the Jacobian of this system at an equilibrium. Following similar steps to those we used in the comparative static analysis before, this can be written as

image

Since image, image, image and image, the diagonal elements of this matrix are always negative. In addition, we verify that the determinant of this matrix is also always positive. In particular, denoting the determinant by Δ, we have

image

image

All five lines of the last expression are positive, and thus so is Δ. This implies that the Jacobian is everywhere a P-matrix, and from Simsek et al. (2007), it follows that there exists a unique equilibrium.

Moreover, given that the determinant is everywhere positive, comparative static results are similar to those of the equilibrium with fixed supplies. For example, an increase in AH will reduce IH and increase wH/wM and wM/wL as before, but also it will increase H/L. Similarly, if new machines replace tasks previously performed by middle skills, this will increase wH/wM and reduce wM/wL, as workers previously performing middle skill tasks are reallocated to low and high skills. In addition, there will now be a supply response, and workers previously supplying their middle skills will shift to supplying either low or high skills. In particular, if the relevant margin of substitution in the supply side is between middle and low, many of these workers will start supplying low skills to the market, leading to an expansion of low skill tasks.

References

1. Acemoglu Daron. Why do new technologies complement skills? Directed technical change and wage inequality. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 1998;113:1055–1090.

2. Acemoglu Daron. Changes in unemployment and wage inequality: an alternative theory and some evidence. American Economic Review. 1999;89:1259–1278.

3. Acemoglu Daron. Technology and the labor market. Journal of Economic Literature. 2002a;40:7–72.

4. Acemoglu Daron. Directed technical change. Review of Economic Studies. 2002b;69:781–810.

5. Acemoglu Daron. Cross-country inequality trends. Economic Journal. 2003;113:F121–149.

6. Acemoglu Daron. Equilibrium bias of technology. Econometrica. 2007;75:1371–1410.

7. Acemoglu, Daron, 2009. When does labor scarcity encourage innovation? NBER working paper 14819, March.

8. Acemoglu, Daron, Aghion, Philippe, Violente, Gianluca, 2001. Deunionization, technical change, and inequality, Carnegie-Rochester conference series on public policy.

9. Acemoglu Daron, Zilibotti Fabrizio. Productivity differences. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 2001;116:563–606.

10. Acemoglu Daron, Guerrieri Veronica. Capital deepening and nonbalanced economic growth. Journal of Political Economy. 2007;116(3):467–498.

11. Acemoglu, Daron, Gancia, Gino, Zilibotti, Fabrizio, 2010. Offshoring, innovation and wages. Mimeo.Antonczyk, Dirk, DeLeire, Thomas, Fitzenberger, Bernd, 2010. Polarization and rising wage inequality: comparing the US and Germany. University of FreiburgWorking Paper, March.

12. Antonczyk Dirk, DeLeire Thomas, Fitzenberger Bernd. Polarization and rising wage inequality: comparing the US and Germany. University of Freiburg Working Paper, March 2010.

13. Antonczyk Dirk, Fitzenberger Bernd, Leuschner Ute. Can a task-based approach explain the recent changes in the German wage structure? Jahrbücher fur Nationalökonomie und Statistik (Journal of Economics and Statistics). 2009;229(2–3):214–238.

14. Atkinson Anthony B. The Changing Distribution of Earnings in OECD Countries (The Rodolfo De Benedetti Lecture Series). New York: Oxford University Press; 2008.

15. Atkinson, Anthony B., Piketty, Thomas, Saez, Emmanuel, 2010. Top incomes in the long run of history. UC Berkeley Working Paper, January.

16. Autor, David H., Dorn, David, 2009. This job is getting old: measuring changes in job opportunities using occupational age structure. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 99.

17. Autor, David H., Dorn, David, 2010. Inequality and specialization: the growth of low-skilled service employment in the United States. MIT Working Paper, April.

18. Autor, David H., Manning, Alan, Smith, Christopher L., 2009. The minimum wage’s role in the evolution of US wage inequality over three decades: a modest reassessment. MIT Mimeograph, April.

19. Autor, David H., Handel, Michael, 2009. Putting tasks to the test: human capital, job tasks and wages, NBER Working Paper No. 15116, June.

20. Autor David H, Levy Frank, Murnane Richard J. Upstairs downstairs: computers and skills on two floors of alarge bank. Industrial and Labor Relations Review. 2002;55(3):432–447.

21. Autor David H, Levy Frank, Murnane Richard J. The skill content of recent technological change: an empirical exploration. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 2003;116.

22. Autor, David H., Katz, Lawrence F., Kearney, Melissa S., 2005. Rising wage inequality: the role of composition and prices. NBER Working Paper No. 11628, September.

23. Autor David H, Katz Lawrence F, Kearney Melissa S. The polarization of the US labor market. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings. 2006;96(2):189–194.

24. Autor David H, Katz Lawrence F, Kearney Melissa S. Trends in US wage inequality: re-assessing the revisionists. Review of Economics and Statistics. 2008;90(2):300–323.

25. Autor David, Katz Lawrence, Krueger Alan. Computing inequality: have computers changed the labor market? Quarterly Journal of Economics. 1998;1131:1169–1214.

26. Bartel Ann P, Ichniowski Casey, Shaw Kathryn L. How does information technology affect productivity? Plant-level comparisons of product innovation, process improvement and worker skills. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 2007;122(4):1721–1758.

27. Baumol William J. Macroeconomics of unbalanced growth: anatomy of an urban crisis. American Economic Review. 1967;57(3):415–426.

28. Black Dan, Kolesnikova Natalia, Taylor Lowell J. Earnings functions when wages and prices vary by location. Journal of Labor Economics. 2009;27(1):21–47.

29. Black Sandra E, Spitz-Oener Alexandra. Explaining women’s success: technological change and the skill content of women’s work. The Review of Economics and Statistics. 2010;92:187–194.

30. Blau Francine D, Kahn Lawrence M. International differences in male wage inequality: institutions versus market forces. Journal Political Economy. 1996;104:791–837.

31. Blinder, Alan, 2007. How many US jobs might be offshorable? Princeton University Center for Economic Policy Studies, Working Paper No. 142, March.

32. Blinder, Alan, Krueger, Alan B., 2008. Measuring off shorability: a survey approach. Princeton University Working Paper, October.

33. Borghans Lex, ter Weel Bas, Weinberg Bruce A. Interpersonal styles and labor market outcomes. Journal of Human Resources. 2008;43(4):815–858.

34. Boskin, Michael, Dulberger, Ellen, Gordon, Robert, Griliches, Zvi, Jorgenson, Dale, 1996. Toward a more accurate measure of the cost of living, Final Report to the Senate Finance Committee.

35. Boudarbat, Brahim, Lemieux, Thomas, Craig Riddell, W., 2010. The evolution of the returns to human capital in Canada, 1980–2005. IZA Working Paper No. 4809, March.

36. Bresnahan Timothy F. Computerisation and wage dispersion: an analytical reinterpretation. The Economic Journal. 1999;109(456):390–415.

37. Bresnahan, Timothy F., Brynjolfsson, Erik, Hitt, Lorin M., 1999. Information technology, workplace organization and the demand for skilled labor: firm-level evidence, NBER Working Paper 7136, May.

38. Burkhauser, Richard V., Feng, Shuaizhang, Larrimore, Jeff, 2008. Improving imputations of top incomes in the public-use current population survey by using both cell-means and variances. NBER Working Paper #14458, October.

39. Card David, DiNardo John. Skill biased technological change and rising wage inequality: some problems and puzzles. Journal of Labor Economics. 2002;20:733–783.

40. Card David, Lemieux Thomas. Can falling supply explain the rising return to college for younger men? A cohort-based analysis. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 2001a;116:705–746.

41. Card David, Lemieux Thomas. Dropout and enrollment trends in the postwar period: what went wrong in the 1970s? In: Gruber Jonathan, ed. Risky Behavior among Youths: An Economic Analysis. Chicago: University of Chicago Press; 2001b; (Chapter 9).

42. Card, David, Kramartz, Francis, Lemieux, Thomas, 1996. Changes in the relative structure of wages and employment: a comparison of the United States, Canada and France. Mimeo.

43. Carneiro, Pedro, Lee, Sokbae, 2009. Trends in quality-adjusted skill premia in the United States, 1960–2000 CEMMAP Working Paper, CWP02/09.

44. Caroli, Eve, van Reenen, John, 1999. Wage inequality and organizational change, Mimeo UCL.

45. Champernowne David. A dynamic growth model involving a production function. In: Lutz FA, Hague DC, eds. The Theory of Capital. New York: Macmillan; 1963.

46. Costinot, Arnaud, Vogel, Jonathan, Matching and Inequality in the World Economy. Journal of Political Economy (forthcoming).

47. Davis S. Cross-country patterns of changes in relative wages. In: NBER Macroeconomic Annual. Cambridge: MIT Press; 1992;239–292.

48. Dessein Wouter, Santos Tanos. Adaptive organizations. Journal of Political Economy. 2006;114(5):956–995.

49. DiNardo John, Fortin Nicole, Lemieux Thomas. Labor market institutions and the distribution of wages, 1973–1992: a semiparametric approach. Econometrica. 1996;64:1001–1044.

50. DiNardo John E, Pischke Jorn-Steffen. The returns to computer use revisited: Have pencils changed the wage structure too? Quarterly Journal of Economics. 1997;112:291–303.

51. Dornbusch Rudiger, Fischer Stanley, Samuelson Paul A. Comparative advantage, trade, and payments in a Ricardian model with a continuum of goods. American Economic Review. 1977;67(5):823–839.

52. Dustmann Christian, Ludsteck Johannes, Schönberg Uta. Revisiting the German wage structure. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 2009;124(2):809–842.

53. Ellwood David. The sputtering labor force of the twenty-first century: can social policy help? In: Krueger Alan B, Solow Robert M, eds. The Roaring Nineties: Can Full Employment be Sustained?. New York: Russell Sage Foundation and Century Foundation Press; 2002.

54. Feenstra Robert, Hanson Gordon. The impact of outsourcing and high-technology capital on wages: estimates for the United States, 1979–1990. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 1999;114(3):907–940.

55. Firpo, Sergio, Fortin, Nicole, Lemieux, Thomas, 2009. Occupational Tasks and Changes in the Wage Structure. UBC Working Paper, September.

56. Fitzenberger, Bernd, Kohn, Karsten, 2006. Skill wage premia, employment, and cohort effects: are workers in Germany all of the same type? University of Freiburg Working Paper, June.

57. Freeman Richard. The Overeducated American. New York: Academic Press; 1976.

58. Freeman Richard. Demand for education. In: Ashenfelter Orley, Layard Richard, eds. Handbook of Labor Economics. North Holland 1986;357–386. vol. I. (Chapter 6).

59. Garicano, Luis, 2000. Hierarchies and the organization of knowledge in production, 108, 874–904.

60. Garicano Luis, Rossi-Hansberg Esteban. Organization and inequality in a knowledge economy. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 2006;121(4):1383–1435.

61. Gathmann Christina, Schonberg Uta. How general is human capital? a task-based approach. Journal of Labor Economics. 2010;28(1):1–49.

62. Goldin Claudia, Margo Robert. The Great compression: the wage structure in the United States at mid-century. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 1992;107:1–34.

63. Goldin Claudia, Katz Lawrence. The Race between Education and Technology. Cambridge: Harvard University Press; 2008.

64. Goos Maarten, Manning Alan. Lousy and lovely jobs: the rising polarization of work in Britain. Review of Economics and Statistics. 2007;89(1):118–133.

65. Goos Maarten, Manning Alan, Salomons Anna. The polarization of the European labor market. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings. 2009;99.

66. Goos Maarten, Manning Alan, Salomons Anna. Recent changes in the European employment structure: the roles of technological change, Globalization and Institutions. Mimeo: Katholieke Universiteit Leuven; 2010.

67. Grossman Gene, Rossi-Hansberg Esteban. Trading tasks: a simple theory of offshoring. American Economic Review. 2008;98(5):1978–1997.

68. Hamermesh Daniel. Changing inequality in markets for workplace amenities. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 1999;114.

69. Heckman James J, Lochner Lance, Taber Christopher. Explaining rising wage inequality: explorations with a dynamic general equilibrium model of labor earnings with heterogeneous agents. Review of Economic Dynamics. 1998;1:1–58.

70. Heckman James J, Sedlacek Guilherme. Heterogeneity, aggregation, and market wage functions: an empirical model of self-selection in the labor market. Journal of Political Economy. 1985;93:1077–1125.

71. Hellwig Martin, Irmen Andreas. Endogenous technical change in a competitive economy. Journal of Economic Theory. 2001;10(1):1–39.

72. Hirsch Barry T, Schumacher Edward J. Match bias in wage gap estimates due to earnings imputation. Journal of Labor Economics. 2004;22(3):689–722.

73. Hounshell David A. From the American System to Mass Production, 1800–1932: The Development of Manufacturing Technology in the United States. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press; 1985.

74. Ikenaga Toshie. Polarization of the Japanese labor market–adoption of ICT and changes in tasks required. Japanese Journal of Labour Studies. 2009;584:73–90.

75. Ikenaga Toshie, Kambayashi Ryo. Long-term trends in the polarization of the Japanese labor market: the increase of non-routine task input and its valuation in the labor market. January: Hitotsubashi University Institute of Economic Research Working Paper; 2010.

76. Jaeger David A. Reconciling the old and new Census Bureau education questions: recommendations for researchers. Journal of Business and Economics Statistics. 1997;15:300–309.

77. James John A, Skinner Jonathan S. The resolution of the labor-scarcity paradox. The Journal of Economic History. 1985;45(03):513–540.

78. Jensen J Bradford, Kletzer Lori G, Bernstein Jared, Feenstra Robert C. Tradable services: understanding the scope and impact of services offshoring. In: Brookings Trade Forum: Offshoring White-Collar Work. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution; 2005;75–133.

79. Jensen, J. Bradford, Kletzer, Lori, Measuring tradable services and the task content of offshorable services jobs. In: Katharine Abraham, Mike Harper, James Spletzer (Eds.), Labor in the NewEconomy, University of Chicago Press, Chicago (forthcoming).

80. Oldenski, Lindsay, 2009. Export versus FDI: A Task-Based Framework for Comparing manufacturing and services. Georgetown University Working Paper.

81. Johnson George. The demand for labor by education category. Southern Economic Journal. 1970;37:190–204.

82. Juhn, Chinhui, 1994. Wage inequality and industrial change: evidence from five decades. NBER working paper no. 4684.

83. Juhn Chinhui, Murphy Kevin M, Pierce Brooks. Wage inequality and the rise in returns to skill. Journal of Political Economy. 1993;101:410–442.

84. Juhn Chinhui, Murphy Kevin, Topel Robert H. Why has the natural rate of unemployment increased over time? Brookings Papers on Economic Activity. 1991;0(2):75–126.

85. Katz Lawrence, Autor David. Changes in the wage structure and earnings inequality. In: Ashenfelter O, ed. The Handbook of Labor Economics, vol. Amsterdam: III. Elsevier; 1999.

86. Katz Lawrence, Murphy Kevin. Changes in relative wages: supply and demand factors. Quarterly Journal of Economics 1992;(CVII):35–78.

87. Katz Lawrence, Loveman Gary W, Blanchflower David G. A comparison of changes in the structure of wages in four OECD countries. In: Freeman Richard, Katz Lawrence, eds. Differences and Changes in Wage Structures National Bureau of Economic Research. University of Chicago Press 1995.

88. Kremer, Michael, Maskin, Eric, 1996. Wage inequality and segregation by skill. NBER Working Paper No. 5718, August.

89. Lee David S. Wage inequality in the US During the 1980s: rising dispersion or falling minimum wage? Quarterly Journal of Economics. 1999;114.

90. Lemieux Thomas. Increased residual wage inequality: composition effects, noisy data, or rising demand for skill? American Economic Review. 2006a;96:461–498.

91. Lemieux, Thomas, 2006b. Post-secondary education and increasing wage inequality. NBER Working Paper No. 12077.

92. Lemieux Thomas. The changing nature of wage inequality. Journal of Population Economics. 2008;21.

93. Lemieux Thomas, Bentley MacLeod W, Parent Daniel. Performance pay and wage inequality. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 2009;124(1):1–49.

94. Levy Frank, Murnane Richard J. The New Division of Labor. New Jersey: Princeton University Press; 2004.

95. Manning Alan. We can work it out: the impact of technological change on the demand for low-skill workers. Scottish Journal of Political Economy. 2004;51(5):581–608.

96. Mazzolari, Francesca, Ragusa, Giuseppe, 2008. Spillovers from high-skill consumption to low-skill labor markets. University of California at Irvine Working Paper, May.

97. Meyer Bruce D, Sullivan James X. Changes in the consumption, income, and well-being of single mother headed families. American Economic Review. 2008;98(5):2221–2241.

98. Michaels, Guy, Natraj, Ashwini, Van Reenen, John, 2009. Has ICT polarized skill demand? Evidence from eleven countries over 25 years. London School of Economics Centre for Economic Performance Working Paper, December.

99. Mokyr Joel. The lever of riches: technological creativity and economic progress. Oxford University Press 1992.

100. Moretti, Enrico, 2008. Real wage inequality. NBER Working Paper No. 14370, September 2008.

101. Murphy Kevin M, Graig Riddell W, Romer Paul M. Wages, skills and technology in the United States and Canada. In: Helpman E, ed. General Purpose Technologies. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press; 1998.

102. Nordhaus William D. Two centuries of productivity growth in computing. Journal of Economic History. 2007;67(1):128–159.

103. Peri, Giovanni, Sparber, Chad, 2008. Task specialization, immigration and wages. CReaM Discussion Paper Series No. 02/08.

104. Pierce Brooks. Compensation inequality. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 2001;116:1493–1525.

105. Pierce, Brooks, 2001. Compensation inequality. Quarterly Journal of Economics 116, 1493–1525.Pierce, Brooks, Recent trends in compensation inequality. In: Katharine Abraham, Mike Harper, JamesSpletzer (Eds.), Labor in the New Economy, University of Chicago Press, Chicago forthcoming).

106. Piketty Thomas, Saez Emmanuel. Income Inequality in the United States, 1913–1998. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 2003;118:1–39.

107. Pissarides Christopher A, Ngai L Rachel. Structural change in a multisector model of growth. American Economic Review. 2007;97:429–443.

108. Reshef, Ariell, 2009. Skill biased technological change in services versus the rest: an estimate and interpretation. University of Virginia Working Paper.

109. Rodriguez-Clare, Andres, Ramondo, Natalia, 2010. Growth, Size and Openness: A Quantitative Approach, January.

110. Romer Paul. Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy. 1990;98(S5):71–102.

111. Rosen Sherwin. Hedonic prices and implicit markets: product differentiation in pure competition. Journal of Political Economy. 1974;82:34–55.

112. Rosen Sherwin. The economics of superstars. American Economic Review. 1981;71:845–858.

113. Rosen Sherwin. Authority, control, and the distribution of earnings. Bell Journal of Economics. 1982;13:311–323.

114. Saint-Paul Gilles. On the distribution of income and workers under intrafirm spillovers with an application to ideas and networks. Journal of Political Economy. 2001;109:1–37.

115. Saint-Paul Gilles. Innovation and Inequality: How Does Technical Progress Affect Workers. Princeton: Princeton University Press; 2008.

116. Sattinger Michael. Comparative advantage and the distributions of earnings and abilities. Econometrica. 1975;43:455–468.

117. Sattinger Michael. Assignment models of the distribution of earnings. Journal of Economic Literature. 1993;31:831–880.

118. Simsek Alp, Ozdaglar Asuman E, Acemoglu Daron. Generalized Poincaré-Hopf theorem for compact nonsmooth regions. Mathematics of Operations Research. 2007;32:193–214.

119. Spitz-Oener Alexandra. Technical change, job tasks, and rising educational demands: looking outside the wage structure. Journal of Labor Economics. 2006;24(2):235–270.

120. Teulings Coen N. The contribution of minimum wages to increasing inequality. The Economic Journal. 2003;113:801–833.

121. Teulings Coen N. The wage distribution in a model of assignment of skills to jobs. Journal of Political Economy. 1995;103:280–315.

122. Tinbergen Jan. Substitution of graduate by other labor. Kyklos. 1974;27:217–226.

123. Tinbergen Jan. Income Difference: Recent Research. Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing Company; 1975.

124. Weiss Matthias. Skill-biased technical change: is there hope for the unskilled? Economics Letters. 2008;100(3):439–441.

125. Welch Finis. Black-white differences in returns to schooling. American Economic Review. 1973;63:893–907.

126. Wilson Charles A. On the General Structure of Ricardian Models with a Continuum of Goods: Applications to Growth, Tariff theory, and technical change. Econometrica. 1980;48(7):1675–1702.

127. Zeira Joseph. Workers, machines and economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 1998;113:1091–1113.

128. Zeira, Joseph, 2006. Machines as engines of growth center for economic policy research, Discussion Paper 5429, 2006.


*We thank Amir Kermani for outstanding research assistance and Melanie Wasserman for persistent, meticulous and ingenious work on all aspects of the chapter. We are indebted to Arnaud Costinot for insightful comments and suggestions. Autor acknowledges support from the National Science Foundation (CAREER award SES-0239538).

1In many cases, this model is extended to more than two skill groups (see., e.g., Card and Lemieux, 2001a,b; Acemoglu et al., 2001). Atkinson (2008) refers to the Tinbergen education-race model as the Textbook Model.

2In addition to Tinbergen (1974, 1975), see Welch (1973), Freeman (1976), Katz and Murphy (1992) and Autor et al. (1998, 2008) on the canonical model. Acemoglu (2002a) develops several implications of the canonical model and relates these to other approaches to the relationship between technology and skill premia.

3Later analyses have not confirmed this conclusion, however. See Goldin and Katz (2008).

4Autor et al. (2003), Goos et al. (2009) and Autor and Dorn (2010) provide related task-based models. The model we propose builds most directly on Acemoglu and Zilibotti (2001) and is also closely related to Costinot and Vogel (forthcoming), who provide a more general approach to the assignment of skills tasks and derive the implications of their approach for the effect of technical change on wage inequality. Similar models have also been developed and used in the trade literature, particularly in the context of outsourcing and offshoring. See, for example, Feenstra and Hanson (1999), Grossman and Rossi-Hansberg (2008), Rodriguez-Clare and Ramondo (2010), and Acemoglu et al. (2010).

5We also offer an extension to the model in which workers have multiple skills and choose the allocation of their skills across tasks given a fixed time budget.

6A more detailed account of several other trends related to labor market inequality and more extensive references to the literature are provided in Katz and Autor (1999). Goldin and Katz (2008) provide an authoritative account of the evolution of labor market inequality and the supply and demand for education in the United States from the dawn of the twentieth century to the mid 2000s. Card and DiNardo (2002) offer a skeptical perspective on the literature linking trends in wage inequality to the evolution of skill demands. See also the recent overview papers by Autor et al. (2008) and Lemieux (2008).

7The ACS is the successor to the Census’ long form questionnaire, which collected detailed demographic data from a subset of Census respondents. The long form was retired after the 2000 Census. The ACS is conducted annually and currently contains a 5 percent population sample. The ACS survey questions closely follow the Census long form.

8Beginning with DiNardo et al. (1996), many studies (e.g., Autor et al., 1998; Lemieux, 2006b; Autor et al., 2008) have further weighted samples by workers’ hours and weeks worked when computing sample statistics. Statistics calculated using these weights therefore correspond to the average paid hour of work rather than the wage paid to the average worker. We break with this tradition here because we view the conceptual object of interest for this chapter to be the distribution of prices (or wages) that workers’ skills command in the labor market rather than the interaction between these prices and workers’ realized choice of hours. To the extent that we have experimented with the weighting scheme, we have found that the choice of weights—hours versus bodies—has only second-order effects on our substantive results. Thus, our use of the bodies rather than hours-weighting scheme is of notional but not substantive importance.

9The major redesign of the earnings questions in the CPS ORG in 1994 led to a substantial rise in non-response to these questions as well as other potential consistency issues that are only imperfectly addressed by our processing of the data. For example, the earnings non-response rate in the CPS ORG increased from 15.3 percent in 1993 to 23.3 percent in the last quarter of 1995 (the first quarter in which allocation flags are available in the redesigned survey), and reached 31 percent by 2001 (Hirsch and Schumacher, 2004). The contemporaneous rise in the earnings imputation rate in the March survey was comparatively small. This redesign may be an important factor in accounting for the significant discrepancies in inequality trends in the May/ORG and March samples beginning in 1994 (see Lemieux, 2006b; Autor et al., 2008).

10The Census samples comprise 1 percent of the US population in 1960 and 1970, and 5 percent of the population in 1980, 1990, and 2000.

11These 40 groups consist of five education categories (less than high school, high school graduate, some college, four-year college degree, post-college schooling), four potential experience levels (0 to 9 years, 10 to 19 years, 20 to 29 years, and 30 to 39 years), and two genders. Full-time, full-year workers are those who work at least 40 weeks per year and at least 35 hours per week. The construction of the relative wage series follows Katz and Murphy (1992), Katz and Autor (1999), and Autor et al. (2008). We follow closely the conventions set by these prior studies to facilitate comparisons. The Data Appendix provides further details.

12This series is also composition adjusted to correctly weight the changing gender and experience composition of college and non-college labor supply. Our construction of this figure follows Autor et al. (2008) Figure 4b, and adds three subsequent years of data. See the Data Appendix for details.

13One should not blame the entire rise in US earnings inequality on Richard Freeman, however. His book correctly predicted that the college glut was temporary, and that demand would subsequently surpass the growth of supply, leading to a rebound in the college premium.

14The estimated falls in real wages would also be overstated if the price deflator overestimated the rate of inflation and thus underestimated real wage growth. Our real wage series are deflated using the Personal Consumption Expenditure Deflator produced by the US Bureau of Economic Analysis. The PCE generally shows a lower rate of inflation than the more commonly used Consumer Price Index (CPI), which was in turn amended following the Boskin report in 1996 to provide a more conservative estimate of inflation (Boskin et al., 1996).

15Moretti (2008) presents evidence that the aggregate increase in wage inequality is greater than the rise in cost-of-living-adjusted wage inequality, since the aggregate increase does not account for the fact that high-wage college workers are increasingly clustered in metropolitan areas with high and rising housing prices. These facts are surely correct, but their economic interpretation requires some care. As emphasized above, our interest in wage inequality is not as a measure of welfare inequality (for which wages are generally a poor measure), but as a measure of the relative productivities of different groups of workers and the market price of skills. What is relevant for this purpose is the producer wage—which does not require cost of living adjustments provided that each region produces at least some traded (i.e., traded within the United States) goods and wages, and regional labor market wages reflect the value of marginal products of different groups. To approximate welfare inequality, one might wish however to use the consumer wage—that is the producer wage adjusted for cost of living. It is unclear whether housing costs should be fully netted out of the consumer wage, however. If high housing prices reflect the amenities offered by an area, these higher prices are not a pure cost. If higher prices instead reflect congestion costs that workers must bear to gain access to high wages jobs, then they are a cost not an amenity. These alternative explanations are not mutually exclusive and are difficult to empirically distinguish since many high education cities (e.g., New York, San Francisco, Boston) feature both high housing costs and locational amenities differentially valued by high wage workers (see Black et al., 2009).

16Years of schooling correspond to one of eight values, ranging from 7 to 18 years. Due to the substantial revamping of the CPS educational attainment question in 1992, these eight values are the maximum consistent set available throughout the sample period.

17We use the CPS May/ORG series for this analysis rather than the March data so as to focus on hourly wages, as is the convention for Mincerian wage regressions.

18Pioneering analyses of harmonized US income tax data by Piketty and Saez (2003) demonstrate that the increases in upper-tail inequality found in public use data sources and documented below are vastly more pronounced above the 90th percentile than below it, though the qualitative patterns are similar. Burkhauser et al. (2008) offer techniques for improving imputations of top incomes in public use CPS data sources.

19Whether the measured rise in inequality in the 1970s is reliable has been asubject of some debate because this increase is detected in the Census and CPS March series but not in the contemporaneous May CPS series (cf. Katz and Murphy, 1992; Juhn et al., 1993; Katz and Autor, 1999; Lemieux, 2006b; Autor et al., 2008). Recent evidence appears to support the veracity of the 1970s inequality increase. Using harmonized income tax data, Piketty and Saez (2003) find that inequality, measured by the top decile wage share, started to rise steeply in the early 1970s.

20The more pronounced fall at the female tenth percentile in the distribution that includes hourly wages reflects the fact that a substantial fraction (13 percent) of all female hours worked in 1979 were paid at or below the federal minimum wage (Autor et al., 2009), the real value of which declined by 30 log points over the subsequent 9 years. It is clear that the decline in the minimum wage contributed to the expansion of the female lower tail in the 1980s, though the share of the expansion attributable to the minimum is the subject of some debate (see DiNardo et al., 1996; Lee, 1999; Teulings, 2003; Autor et al., 2009). It is noteworthy that in the decade in which the minimum wage was falling, female real wage levels (measured by the mean or median) and female upper-tail inequality (measured by the 90/50) rose more rapidly than for males. This suggests that many forces were operative on the female wage structure in this decade alongside the minimum wage.

21An additional discrepancy between the weekly and hourly samples is that the rise in the 90th wage percentile for males is less continuous and persistent in the hourly samples; indeed the male 90th percentile appears to plateau after 2003 in the May/ORG data but not in the March data. A potential explanation for the discrepancy is that the earnings data collected by the March CPS use a broader earnings construct, and in particular are more likely to capture bonus and performance. Lemieux et al. (2009) find that the incidence of bonus pay rose substantially during the 1990s and potentially contributed to rising dispersion of annual earnings. An alternative explanation for the March versus May/ORG discrepancy is deterioration in data quality. Lemieux (2006b) offers some limited evidence that the quality of the March CPS earnings data declined in the 1990s, which could explain why the March and May/ORG CPS diverge in this decade. Conversely, Autor et al. (2008) hypothesize that the sharp rise in earnings non-response in the May/ORG CPS following the 1994 survey redesign may have reduced the consistency of the wage series(especially given the sharp rise in earnings non-response following the redesign). This hypothesis would also explain why the onset of the discrepancy is in 1994.

22The larger expansion at low percentiles for females than males is likely attributable to the falling bite of the minimum wage during the 1980s (Lee, 1999; Teulings, 2003). Autor et al. (2009) report that 12 to 13 percent of females were paid the minimum wage in 1979.

23A second important difference between the two periods, visible in earlier figures, is that there is significantly greater wage growth at virtually all wage percentiles in the 1990s than in the 1980s, reflecting the sharp rise in productivity in the latter decade. This contrast is not evident in Fig. 9 since the wage change at the median is normalized to zero in both periods.

24Dustmann et al. (2009) and Antonczyk et al. (2010) provide detailed analysis of wage polarization in Germany. Though Germany experienced a substantial increase in wage inequality during the 1980s and 1990s, the pattern of lower-tail movements was distinct from the US. Overturning earlier work, Boudarbat et al. (2010) present new evidence that the returns to education for Canadian men increased substantially between 1980 and 2005.

25Ranking occupations by mean years of completed schooling instead yields very similar results. Moreover, occupational rankings by either measure are quite stable over time. Thus, the conclusions are not highly sensitive to the skill measure or the choice of base year for skill ranking (here, 1980).

26These series are smoothed using a locally weighted regression to reduce jumpiness when measuring employment shifts at such a narrow level of aggregation. Due to smoothing, the sum of share changes may not integrate precisely to zero.

27Despite this apparent monotonicity, employment growth in one low skill job category—service occupations—was rapid in the 1980s (Autor and Dorn, 2010). This growth is hardly visible in Fig. 10, however, because these occupations were still quite small.

28The choice of time period for this figure reflects the availability of consistent Harmonized European Labour Force data. The ranking of occupations by wage/skill level is assumed identical across countries, as necessitated by data limitations. Goos, Manning and Salomons report that the ranking of occupations by wage level is highly comparable across EU countries.

29The patterns are very similar, however, if we instead use the Census/ACS data, which cover the period 1959 through 2007 (see Tables 3a and 3b for comparison).

30These correlations are weighted by occupations’ mean employment shares during the three decade interval.

31Of course, computerization has reduced the value of these tasks at the margin (reflecting their now negligible price).

32Bartel et al. (2007) offer firm-level econometric analysis of the process of automation of routine job tasks and attendant changes in work organization and job skill demands. Autor et al. (2002) and Levy and Murnane (2004) provide case study evidence and in-depth discussion.

33While many codifiable tasks are suitable for either automation or offshoring (e.g., bill processing services), not all offshorable tasks are routine in our terminology. For example, call center operations, data entry, and journeyman programming tasks are readily offshorable since they are information-based tasks that require little face-to-face interactions among suppliers and demanders. These tasks are not generally fully codifiable at present, however.

34Pissarides and Ngai (2007), Acemoglu and Guerrieri (2007), Weiss (2008) and Reshef(2009) also provide theoretical perspectives on the rise of service employment in industrialized economies, focusing on unbalanced productivity growth as in the classic analysis by Baumol (1967). The model in Autor and Dorn (2010) is similarly rooted in unbalanced growth, though Autor and Dorn focus on unbalanced productivity growth across tasks rather than sectors. See also Manning (2004) and Mazzolari and Ragusa (2008) for models of rising service demand based on substitution of market versus household provision of domestic services.

35The literature studying the relationship between technological change, job tasks, skill demands, employment polarization, and wage structure shifts is young but expanding rapidly. In addition to the papers cited above, see especially Spitz-Oener (2006), Antonczyk et al. (2009), Dustmann et al. (2009), Firpo et al. (2009), Ikenaga (2009), Michaels et al. (2009), Black and Spitz-Oener (2010), and Ikenaga and Kambayashi (2010).

36By contrast, task measures collected at the level of the individual worker offer much additional insight. Such measures are available in the German IAB/BIBB survey used by DiNardo and Pischke (1997), Spitz-Oener (2006), Dustmann et al. (2009), and Gathmann and Schönberg (2010) among others. Autor and Handel (2009) also use individual task measures collected by the PDII survey instrument and demonstrate that these measures offer substantial additional explanatory power for wages relative to occupation level data from O*NET.

37The ALM DOT task measures were subsequently used by Autor et al. (2006, 2008), Goos and Manning (2007), Peri and Sparber (2008), Goos et al. (2010), and Autor and Dorn (2009, 2010). Many additional details of the construction of the DOT task measures are found in ALM (2003) and Autor et al. (2008). Borghans et al. (2008) also use task measures from the DOT, some of which overlap ALM and others of which do not.

38We employ a sparse set of O*NET scales that, in our view, most closely accord with the task constructs identified by the conceptual model (see the Data Appendix). Firpo et al. (2009), and Goos et al. (2009) use O*NET task measures to construct measures of routine and abstract tasks, as well as off shorability. The set of tasks used by both papers is highly inclusive, and in our view creates substantial overlap among categories. For example, several task measures used in the off shorability index created by Firpo et al. (2009) are also logical candidates for inclusion in the routine category (e.g., controlling machines or processes); and several of the items used as indices of non-off shorability are also logical candidates for the abstract/non-routine cognitive category (e.g., thinking creatively). Our off shorability measure starts from the measure constructed by Firpo et al. (2009), but drops nine of its 16 O*NET scales that may substantially overlap the routine and, more significantly, non-routine cognitive categories. The Data Appendix provides further details on our measures.

39The statistics in the table are employment-weighted means and standard deviations across the detailed occupations within each larger category. The count of detailed occupations in each category is provided in the table.

40Tasks with these attributes score low on our off shorability scale.

41Males with some-college make up the residual category. These statistics are calculated using our Census and ACS data.

42This decline is fully accounted for by falling employment in clerical and administrative rather than sales occupations.

43The Eurostat data are based on the harmonized European Labour Force survey, and are available for download at www.eurostat.org. The ten countries included in the series in the paper are Denmark, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, the Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, and the United Kingdom. The Eurostat data include many additional EU countries, but not on a consistent basis for this full time interval. The series presented in Fig. 15 are weighted averages of occupational shares across these ten countries, where weights are proportional to the average share of EU employment in each country over the sample period. The Eurostat data for young workers include workers aged 15–39 while the US sample includes workers aged 16–39.

44While our four categories above group sales occupations with clerical occupations, the Eurostat data aggregate sales with service occupations, and this aggregation carries over to our figure. Elementary occupations, as defined by Eurostat, include a mixture of service and manual labor positions. The ordering of countries in Fig. 16 follows the ordering used in Fig. 11.

45image is the change in industry k’s employment share during time interval t, image is the average employment share of industry k over the sample interval, image is the change in occupation j’s share of industry k employment during time interval t, and image is occupation j’s average share of industry k employment during that time.

46These sectors are:extractive industries; construction; manufacturing, transportation and utilities;wholesale trade; retail trade; finance, insurance, and real estate; business services; personal services and entertainment; professional services; and public administration.

47For females, this fact is partially obscured in the long change between 1979–2007 because female service employment contracted sharply in the first decade of this interval and expanded thereafter. Looking separately by decade, however, it is clear that the contraction and subsequent expansion of female employment between 1979 and 2007 are both due to within-industry shifts.

48Moreover, due to the major restructuring of the Census occupational classification scheme in 1980, we have found that it is infeasible to develop a satisfactory occupational classification scheme that is both detailed and consistent for the full 1959 through 2007 interval. Thus, while it is feasible to apply a more detailed industry scheme for the full sample, we cannot perform a parallel exercise with occupations.

49All estimates are performed using the Census/ACS data to provide the maximal time window. We use full-time, full-year log weekly earnings as our dependent variable since this variable is better measured than hourly earnings in the Census/ACS data. Models estimated using the March CPS (full-time, full-year), May/ORG CPS (all hourly earnings) and Census/ACS hourly earnings measure all produce substantively similar results.

50A quadratic in years of schooling performs almost identically to the five education dummies.

51Although the task measures are assigned at the level of occupation dummies, it is possible for their partial R-squared value to exceed the dummies, since the partial R-squared is calculated on the residual variance after the wage variable has been orthogonalized with respect to both the experience quartic and the task measures.

52Firpo et al. (2009) find a significant role for off shorability in explaining wage polarization, though this effect is smaller than the estimated technology effect. Papers by Blinder (2007), Jensen et al. (2005); Jensen and Kletzer (forthcoming), and Blinder and Krueger (2008) develop innovative measures of off shorability. The efficacy of these measures relative to other task scales in predicting patterns of wage and employment polarization awaits testing.

53It is straightforward to extend the canonical model to include several skill groups, with each group allocated to asingle occupation (or to producing a single good). Most of the features of the canonical model emphasized here continue to apply in this case, particularly when the elasticity of substitution between different groups is the same. When there are different elasticities of substitution between different factors, the implications of the canonical model become richer but also more difficult to characterize and generalize.

54This production function is typically written as image, where AL, and AH are factor-augmenting technology terms and γ is the distribution parameter. To simplify notation, we suppress γ (i.e., setit equal to 1/2).

55In this interpretation, we can think of some of the “tasks” previously performed by high skill workers now being performed by low skill workers. Nevertheless, this is simply an interpretation, since in this model, there are no tasks and no endogenous assignment of tasks to workers. One could alternatively say that the H and L tasks are imperfect substitutes, and hence an increase in the relative supply of H labor means that the H task is used more intensively but less productively at the margin.

56Weiss (2008) considers a model in which ongoing skilled-labor augmenting (though of course not skill biased) technical change first raises then lowers the relative wage of skilled labor. Autor and Dorn (2010) also consider a setting where this can occur if the goods produced by high and low skill workers are gross complements.

57Our estimates are very similar, though not identical, to those of Katz and Murphy, who find an elasticity of substitution of 1.4 and atime trend of 3.3 percent.

58This point is explored by Card and DiNardo (2002), Autor et al. (2008), and Goldin and Katz (2008).

59This invariance property applies when considering wage ratios or, equivalently, the variance of log wages. The variance of wage levels will positively covary with the skill premium in this model.

60Lemieux (2006a) shows that the rising share of the US labor force composed of prime age college graduates in the 1990s and 2000s contributed to the increase in residual (and, implicitly, overall) dispersion of earnings during these decades. Specifically, Lemieux observes that, education constant, earnings dispersion tends to be higher among more experienced workers, and this is particularly true for experienced college-educated workers. As the highly educated baby boom cohorts began to reach their prime years in the 1990s, this force increased the dispersion of wages and wage residuals. Lemieux concludes that a large share of the net rise in residual inequality between 1973 and 2006 can be explained by this compositional effect.Autor et al. (2005, 2008) suggest caution in interpreting this result because the composition-based explanation for rising wage dispersion does not fit the asymmetric expansion of the upper tail and compression of the lower tail. The composition exercise implies that the rising share of prime age college employment during the 1990s and 2000s should have increased dispersion in the lower tail of the earnings distribution (overall and residual), whereas the opposite occurred (Fig. 8). Conversely, these compositional shifts are not predicted to raise dispersion in the upper-tail of the distribution, yet this is where the rise in dispersion was concentrated. This misalignment between facts and predictions underscores the limitations of this approach.

61Wages for a skill group can of course fall if its supply becomes relatively more abundant. This is clearly not the explanation for declining wages of non-college workers, however.

62The precedent of this approach is the assignment model, introduced in Tinbergen (1974), and further developed in Rosen (1974, 1981, 1982), Sattinger (1975, 1993), Heckman and Sedlacek (1985), Teulings (1995), Saint-Paul (2001) and Garicano (2000). The task-based approach has been used more recently in several papers studying the impact of technology and international trade on the labor market, including Feenstra and Hanson (1999), Acemoglu and Zilibotti (2001), Spitz-Oener (2006), Goos and Manning (2007), Grossman and Rossi-Hansberg (2008), Autor and Dorn (2009, 2010), Firpo et al. (2009), Acemoglu et al. (2010), Rodriguez-Clare and Ramondo (2010), and Costinot and Vogel (forthcoming).

63Alternatively, the canonical model can be interpreted as an approximation whereby this assignment is fixed during the period of study.

64The assignment models mentioned in footnote 62 provide highly flexible task-based models, but are generally not tractable and do not offer a simple framework in which the interaction between technology and the allocation of tasks across different skills can be readily analyzed.

65The assignment literature, and in particular the recent important paper by Costinot and Vogel (forthcoming), considers a similar model with a continuum of skills (as well as a continuum of tasks as in our framework). Under a comparative advantage (log super modularity) assumption, which generalizes our comparative advantage assumption below, Costinot and Vogel (forthcoming) characterize the labor market equilibrium in terms of two ordinary differential equations, one determining the match between skills and tasks and the other determining the wage as a function of assignment. They show that a variety of changes in the patterns of comparative advantage will lead to unambiguous comparative static results. The framework of Costinot and Vogel (forthcoming) can thus also be used to study issues similar to those exposited below. As with other assignment models, one would need to impose additional structure on the pattern of comparative advantage to obtain sharp predictions.Our framework is also related to growth models in which technical progress expands the range of tasks in which machines can be used instead of labor. See, for example, Champernowne (1963), Zeira (1998, 2006), Hellwig and Irmen (2001) and Acemoglu (2009). Finally, Saint-Paul (2008) provides a rich exposition of both conventional and unconventional models of technological change and considers their nuanced implications for wage levels and wage inequality.

66In particular, our model is isomorphic to a Ricardian trade model a la Dornbusch et al. (1977), with each skill group representing a country(i.e., a single factor, three-country model with a continuum of goods). Wilson (1980) provides a generalization of the Dornbusch, Fischer and Samuelson model to an arbitrary number of countries and more general preferences. Wilson’s approach can be used to extend some of the results here to more than three skill groups and to more general preferences than those in Eq. (11).

67Alternatively, the unit cost of producing task IH should be the same with medium and high skill workers, i.e., image. We then obtain (23) using (26). Similarly, (24) can be obtained from image using (27).

68Or in fact, one could replicate a model with two tasks using a continuum of tasks, for example, assuming that αL (i) = 1 if iI and 0 otherwise, and αH (i) = 0 if iI and 1 otherwise (or a smooth approximation to this that would satisfy Assumption 1).

69One could, however, draw a parallel between changes in (factor-augmenting) technology in this model and changes in the distribution parameter, ?, in the canonical model (recall footnote 54). Unlike factor-augmenting technologies, shifts in the distribution parameter can reduce the wages of the skill group whose corresponding multiplier is reduced.

70Juhn (1994) develops a model in which middle skill workers are closer substitutes for low than high skill workers. A decline in demand for middle skill workers consequently places greater downward pressure on low than high skill wages.

71Autor and Dorn (2010), for example, offer a closely related but distinct interpretation of the same patterns. In their model, advancing information technology displaces non-college workers performing routine tasks in production of goods, leading these workers to supply manual labor to service tasks instead. This is equivalent to substitution of skills across tasks in the current model. In Autor and Dorn (2010), this supply effect initially depresses wages in low skill services. But as the price of automating routine tasks becomes ever cheaper, the opportunity for further substitution of skills across tasks is eventually exhausted when essentially all non-college workers have exited goods production. At this point, the imperfect substitutability in consumption between goods and services outputs drives wage setting in services as in Baumol (1967). If the substitution elasticity between goods and services is less than or equal to unity, wage inequality between college workers (who supply abstract tasks to goods production) and non-college workers (who supply manual tasks to service production) either asymptotes to a constant or reverses direction—leading to wage and employment polarization. The Autor and Dorn (2010) hypothesis, as well as the framework developed here, can explain the rapid growth in service occupation employment starting in the 1980s, a period when routine-intensive occupations were in decline (see Fig. 13).

72Acemoglu and Zilibotti (2001) showed that the response of factor-augmenting technology to supplies works exactly in the same way in this task-based model as in the canonical model studied in Acemoglu (1998, 2002b). In particular, because the special case studied in Acemoglu and Zilibotti (2001) is equivalent to a version of the canonical model with an elasticity of substitution equal to two, technology adjusts in the long run in that model to make the relative demand for skills entirely flat. It is straightforward to extend this result, again in the model with only high and low skill workers, so that technology adjusts more or less than this amount. Hence, all of the results in Acemoglu (1998, 2002b) generalize for factor-augmenting technical change in this task-based environment.

73The qualifier “absolutely” is introduced, since in Acemoglu (1998, 2002b), bias refers to changes in technologies affecting relative prices, whereas in this more general framework, the focus is on the price level of a factor. To obtain sharp results on relative price changes, one needs to restrict the focus to factor-augmenting changes (see Acemoglu (2007)). In what follows, all of the references to biased technical change refer to factor price levels, and thus one could insert the qualifier “absolute” though we will not do so as to simplify terminology.

74When θ is a continuous multidimensional variable (a vector), there is a straightforward generalization of this definition (see Acemoglu (2007)). All of the results we discuss here are valid in this general case, but to simplify the exposition, we will not introduce the necessary notation.

75Recall in particular from Proposition 2 that dIH/d ln AH < 0 and d ln (wH/wM) /d ln AH > 0, and thus wM/wH will fall.

76Nor is this notion far-fetched. Skill levels in production and clerical occupations, as measured by the college employment or wage-bill share, have risen as employment in these occupations has declined (Autor et al., 1998). A plausible interpretation of this pattern is that educated workers have comparative advantage in the set of non-routine tasks in these occupations that remain.

77Here, abstract occupations are professional, managerial and technical occupations; routine occupations are sales, clerical, administrative support, production, and operative occupations; and service occupations include protective service, food preparation, cleaning, buildings and grounds, and personal care and personal services.

78As above, because the allocation of workers to tasks is endogenous, the wages paid to a set of workers previously performing a given task can fall even as the wages paid to the workers now performing that task rise. Our framework therefore suggests that a regression of wages on tasks currently performed, or their change over time, would be difficult to interpret.

79A recent working paper by Firpo et al. (2009) also develops an innovative method for measuring the impact of changing task prices on wage structure. Using a simple statistical model of occupational wage setting, they predict that occupations that are specialized in tasks that have declining market value should see a reduction in both mean occupational wages and the variance of occupational wages (and vice versa for tasks with rising prices). This latter (variance) effect stems from the interaction between a falling task price and a fixed distribution of task efficiencies within an occupation; as the market value of a given task falls, the variances of wages paid to workers with differing productivities in that task compresses along with it. An issue that needs further study in their approach is that changes in task prices will presumably lead to changes in self-selection into occupations, as implied by our model (and more generally by the assumption that workers are making maximizing choices). This should also affect occupational wage means and variances. Firpo, Fortin and Lemieux’s exploratory analysis finds a significant role for both routine-task displacement and, to a lesser extent, offshoring in contributing to US wage polarization between 1984 and 2001. In addition, their analysis emphasizes the contribution of declining labor union penetration and shifts in demographic composition to wage polarization.

80We should caveat, however, that female workers have also been substantially displaced over the last two decades from a different set of middle skill tasks (in particular, administrative support and clerical jobs), without seemingly experiencing the adverse wage and employment consequences observed among men.

..................Content has been hidden....................

You can't read the all page of ebook, please click here login for view all page.
Reset
18.227.26.217