Chapter 40
Setting up a company or financing start-ups

A really big adventure!

All groups were once upon a time start-ups, and some were even set up in such improbable places as a maid’s room (NRJ), a garage (HP) or a university dormitory (Facebook). The most talented of entrepreneurs, the luckiest, the hardest working, with the ability to learn from failures and with vision, will succeed in creating a group that survives, but the vast majority will fail. Fortunately, this fact does not prevent new entrepreneurs, every year, from embarking on this adventure. We’ve written this chapter for them so that they can avoid making bad financial choices that could put their entrepreneurial adventure in danger. As for anyone else who reads it, we hope that we’ll have sown a tiny seed which perhaps one day will grow into something bigger.

Section 40.1 Financial particularities of the company being set up

In our view, there are five:

1. The extreme volatility of capital employed, which means very high risk

Many entrepreneurs1 who launch businesses have an idea or a product or a service but do not yet have an economic model that would enable them to cover their costs and get a reasonable return on their capital invested. When Larry Page and Sergey Brin developed their algorithms that were to give rise to Google, their aim was to come up with a more efficient search engine than those already in existence. They were not sure that they would succeed and they had no idea of how they could make this tool pay. It was only some years later that the idea of associating advertising with searches was born, resulting in a particularly efficient economic model.

This fundamental uncertainty about the relevance of a concept and the ability to find a money-earning demand for it is not specific to the Internet sector. The same situation can be found in the fields of biotechnology, industrial innovation and new services, as well as in commerce.

This is the reason why only 29% of companies created in the US survive 10 years after their inception, and 23% in France.

image

Source: Entrepreneur Weekly, Small Business Development Center, Bradley University, University of Tennessee Research, January 2014

Far from being linear, the development of a start-up2 goes through successive stages, which are all possible occasions for failure and/or a change in direction. An entrepreneur has an idea. Will he be able to raise the funds necessary for creating the prototype? If so, will it be possible to create functions that will give the product a competitive advantage? If so, will the entrepreneur find customers prepared to acquire the product at a price that more than covers costs? If so, will it be possible to shift to a mass-production phase without losing the quality of the prototype? If so, etc.

A “no” does not necessarily mean the end of the story, but perhaps a departure in a new direction after specific corrections have been made, or possibly having to go back to the drawing board. So new entrepreneurs have to be psychologically strong and have solid finances!

2. The crucial role of the founder

An enterprise is often set up by one person (Marcel Dassault, Steve Jobs, Richard ­Branson) or a small group of individuals who personally take a very high level of risk, giving up a situation in which they are well established or renouncing the possibility of such a situation, for what for many of them will in the end turn out to be nothing more than a pipe dream. But they bring a project, a vision and a charisma that is indispensable for facing the unknown, adversity and challenges, and indispensable for convincing others (employees, investors) to follow them. Without the founder, the company would simply not exist.

From a financial point of view, a person starting up a company is the polar opposite of the ideal investor described by the CAPM in Chapter 19. He focuses on a single asset and takes all of the risks. The concept of diversification is something about which he has no idea. For him, it is all or nothing. He has a tiny chance of taking home the big prize and a huge risk of losing everything. But the entrepreneur does not reason in terms of probability like the financial manager. His aim is not financial. It is, above all, human. This is a completely different world.

He generally feels very passionate about his company – it’s his creation – which is a far cry from the cold detachment of the financial manager for whom everything is just a question of risk and return. As we will see, this character trait of the entrepreneur is not without danger when his desire to control pushes him to take on too much debt or to put the brakes on the company’s growth.

3. The need for external financing

Very few start-ups immediately generate positive cash flow. Most often, they initially make losses and some have to wait several years before they are able to record their first euro of sales. And when they do start recording positive earnings, investments (in fixed assets and working capital) are rarely fully covered by cash flows.

Since their free cash flow is negative, it is imperative that they find external financing, as generally the entrepreneur does not have sufficient assets to finance his entrepreneurial adventure on his own.

4. A more active role for investors

Investors hope that they have invested in the next Snap or Sigfox, while remaining aware that out of 10 investments that they make, seven to eight will yield nothing, one or two will earn a reasonable return and the tenth will earn 10 or 100 times the investment, saving all of the rest. Given that they are taking very high risks, they will monitor their investments very closely, providing the entrepreneur with advice and contacts in order to help him to steer the company in the right direction. The entrepreneur, for his part, is very much in favour of a high level of involvement by investors as they bring what he lacks – experience, contacts, distance, advice on taking difficult decisions and … capital. The loneliness of the entrepreneur is not a myth.

Since the company will raise funds several times before it succeeds in generating positive cash flows, investors have every interest in ensuring that the company follows its road map so as to be able to form an opinion before it takes any decision to reinvest. Their close involvement alongside the manager is thus not disinterested. It is made a lot easier by the fact that, generally, there are not very many of them.

5. A highly speculative valuation which is thus volatile

Unsurprisingly, the extreme volatility of capital employed can be seen in the share price, even without the leverage effect, with very sharp share price variations. These variations are the sign of high risk that is specific to this stage of the company’s development. This is illustrated by the share price performances of Néovacs, a biotechnology start-up, and Sanofi, one of the world leaders in the pharmaceutical sector. Néovacs really took off in 2007 and has since then raised around €60m through eight capital increases. In July 2017, its market capitalisation stood at €41m, compared with €103bn for Sanofi. Néovacs had not recorded substantial sales figures up until 2016.

image

Source: NYSE Euronext

The sudden changes in Néovacs’s share price indicate disappointing results or breakthroughs in its medical research programme.

Section 40.2 Some basic principles for financing a start-up

1. Equity capital, more equity capital and even more equity capital

When the economic model of the company is not clearly established and its exploitation does not require assets to be held which have a value that is independent of the activity (real estate, commercial lease), the only reasonable way for a company to finance itself is with equity capital.

Debt, because of the regular payment of interest and the repayment of capital, is quite unsuitable when cash flow is unpredictable and negative over an undetermined period. Entrepreneurs need time to test their products or services, correct errors, make adaptations in line with feedback from the first customers, drop 80% of what’s been done if necessary and head off in another direction. Entrepreneurs are completely wrapped up in their adventures and can’t allow themselves to be distracted or have their timeframes dictated by debt, ticking away like a time bomb.

We have seen too many talented entrepreneurs seeking to avoid being diluted in the capital of their companies by issuing too much debt too early. This often takes the form of convertible bonds, as the entrepreneur thinks that they will naturally be converted. At this stage of the company’s development, the challenge is not to avoid dilution or to minimise it, but to demonstrate that the company is viable. Better to have a small stake in a company that has had the time it needs to prove that it is viable, than a large stake in a company that is heading for bankruptcy or whose liabilities have to be restructured, as in this case the entrepreneur dilution will be massive.

We cannot stress this point enough.

Once the economic model has been found and its viability has been more or less assured, the company can then take out debt.

It is only if the start-up uses assets whose value is independent of its activity – such as vehicles or equipment with a secondary market – that it can finance them partially using debt. This is the case in sectors like retail, transport and restaurants. The initial investment is often higher than in the Internet or personal services sectors. Debt then makes it possible to get sufficient financing together, which would be difficult using only equity. If this is the case, it should be as long-term as possible, ideally through a leasing agreement so as to avoid putting pressure on the entrepreneur.

2. One or several rounds of financing?

Between 2007 and 2016, Néovacs, the biotechnology start-up mentioned above, raised €60m in equity from venture capital funds or the public (it has been listed since 2010) in eight capital increases. Nearly one per year. Wouldn’t it have been simpler to carry out a single capital increase of €60m in 2007, thus giving the company peace of mind with regard to its financing?

No. This would not have been in the interests of either the investors or the entrepreneur.

The former because they are reluctant to give the entrepreneur a blank cheque and will only give him the financial resources necessary for getting to the next step of the entrepreneurial adventure: development of a prototype, opening and operation for a few months of the first store, reaching 100 000 members for a social network, etc. If the step is successfully reached, a new round of financing will be organised with the same investors and/or new ones, giving the company the financial resources necessary for reaching the next step. Here again, investors will most often only consider committing to a new round of financing if this new step is reached.

If the next step is not reached, investors will step in and decide whether any corrective measures introduced by the entrepreneur look like they are sufficiently solid to warrant continuing the adventure in this new direction and participating in a new (last?) round of financing. If not, the adventure will probably stop there.

This system using several rounds of financing enables investors to control the entrepreneur, to resolve potential conflicts of interest and to allocate their funds to the most promising projects. The interest for entrepreneurs, after an initial failure, is to persevere, come what may, as long as the funds that are being used are not being provided by them. The fear for investors would be that entrepreneurs get themselves into more and more difficulties, wasting funds that could be better used on other projects run by other teams. Here we can see the mechanisms of agency theory, discussed in Chapter 26.

For the entrepreneur, massive fundraising for forecasted financing requirements over several years of activities is not a panacea either. As the company has not yet proved anything – or very little – the issue price of shares is likely to be very low. On the other hand, in a succession of financing rounds, since each one marks the success of a step, the entrepreneur and the investors in the previous rounds will be in a good position to negotiate a higher share price at each round, thus limiting the dilution of the shareholders and also the entrepreneur.

3. Goodwill at the start or at the exit?

Goodwill is the difference between the value of equity and the amount of equity invested. Its conceptual basis is the ability of the firm to generate, over a certain period, returns that are higher than those required by investors, given the risk (see Chapter 31).

The entrepreneur often considers that he is contributing funds (although not a lot), the idea and the ability to implement the idea. Investors, for their part, only contribute funds. Accordingly, it will only seem logical to the entrepreneur to receive better treatment than the investors when shares and voting rights are being allocated, enabling him to retain a majority of voting rights in his project. This is why often, during the first round of financing, there is a higher issue price for shares for investors than for the founders. The difference is often considerable, especially if there is a lot of buzz around the concept of this new company. We’ve seen investors pay 100 times more for their shares than the entrepreneurs, which is a considerable amount of goodwill for a company that has yet to prove itself!

This practice is not without danger. As soon as the emerging company, after a few quarters of activity, is unable to stick to its roadmap and fails to meet its first targets, the question of a second round of financing is raised very quickly, while the funds raised in the first round are in the process of being totally depleted.

The relationship between the entrepreneur and the investors could deteriorate rapidly. The value of the share will then be between the price paid by the entrepreneur for his shares, and that paid by the investors for theirs. In other words, the investors have made a capital loss because of the entrepreneur who has not delivered what was promised in the business plan, while the entrepreneur has made a capital gain thanks to the goodwill paid by the investors, who discover that there was no real foundation for this goodwill. Although all of the shareholders will have to get together to study how to get things back on track, and to correct or call into question all or part of the strategy implemented until now, there is the risk that any such meeting will be marred by a poisonous atmosphere. This can result in a deadlock at a time when it is vital that things keep moving.

The initial investors, unhappy with the situation, will then find it very difficult to agree to participate in a second round of financing, even though the subscription of new shares will enable them to lower the average cost price of their shares. They often prefer to accept their losses and dilution and move on to other opportunities, rather than go back to their investment committees to explain that they were wrong the previous time about the relevance of the concept and the price paid, but that this time, they’re right, even though the entrepreneur has just acknowledged a first failure. We are now no longer in the realm of pure rationality but have moved into the realm of behavioural finance! (See Section 15.5.)

Since our entrepreneur probably doesn’t have the resources to finance the new direction of the company, he will have to find new investors. The task of convincing them will be particularly arduous, as the signal sent by the failure of the initial investors to participate in this new round of financing is extremely negative. There is a high probability of this search for financing ending in failure. If the search for funds is fruitful, the shares in the second round of financing will be issued at a lower price and the initial shareholders, relying on the ratchet mechanism that we will look at in Section 40.4, will ask for additional shares, as if they had subscribed their shares at the same price as the investors in the second round. The entrepreneur will then be massively diluted.

This is the lesser of two evils, because if the search for new investors yields no results, the entrepreneur will be forced to sell the company in very bad conditions, or to liquidate it, which is what happens most frequently.

We could consider, in order to avoid such situations, not asking investors to pay goodwill at the start during the first rounds of financing, but getting them to pay it when they exit, on the basis of the results achieved. Concretely, the shares would be issued when the company is set up, at the same price for all shareholders. Entrepreneurs will get investors to give them call options on a part of their new shareholding at a symbolic exercise price, or stock options, or warrants which will enhance the value of their shares in the future.

But there will be conditions to this enhancement – achieving a target financial performance (sales, earnings), development goals (technical or commercial developments) and most often a given level of investor returns (IRR achieved in the event of sale or a new round of financing). Goodwill will then be paid by investors in the form of dilution of their rate of return, only if it is effectively delivered.

In the very likely event of something going wrong along the way, the situation can be looked at coolly and calmly by the initial shareholders who, since they have all paid the same price for their shares, will have the same interests at heart.

However, we won’t hide the fact that this will be difficult to accept for a passionate entrepreneur, who sees himself as a new Louis Vuitton or Jack Ma (Alibaba) and who hasn’t necessarily given the subject much thought.

More fundamentally, it raises the issue of the motivation and the incentive of the entrepreneur whose role in “his” company risks being symbolic, while the accretive instruments are not exercised, which will only happen in a few years. The risk is that he may consider himself more as an employee than as an entrepreneur, and that would mean certain death for the emerging company! An entrepreneur should never behave like an employee. He should always be thinking about his project, night and day, like a soul possessed! It is true that he could be given a majority of voting rights, either in the articles of association or contractually, but that may not be enough for some. Yes, we’re still in the realm of behavioural finance!

The whole question can be summed up as follows: “Goodwill, yes, but not too much”, so as to retain potential for enhancement of the share, capital increase after capital increase, and to avoid deadlocks or the implementation of ratchet clauses with disastrous effects for the entrepreneur. In the end, an overly optimistic business plan is not in the interests of the entrepreneur, who could find himself sitting on a hand grenade from which he himself has pulled the pin!

Section 40.3 Investors in start-ups

1. Investors in equity capital

The first among them is the entrepreneur himself, with his life savings, sometimes topped up by a bank loan that is secured by his home. He can spend the first months of his adventure with an incubator which will provide him with premises and services remunerated by a few percentage points of capital. The idea then becomes a project.

Friends and family are often among the initial investors, probably less motivated by the idea of making money, but more by loyalty! This type of investment is referred to as love money, which usually raises a few tens of thousands of euros.

Crowdfunding can be used by the entrepreneur to raise funds through specialised Internet platforms (kickstarter.com, wiseed.com, etc.) from a very large number of private investors, the most motivated of whom will invest a few hundred or a few thousand euros each. This will enable him to test his concept on a large scale. However, he will be lucky to raise a few hundred thousand euros in this way.

Business angels are often former company managers and shareholders. They invest a few tens or hundreds of thousands of euros per project. They also provide advice to the entrepreneur and give them access to their networks. When it started out, Twitter was financed by (very lucky) business angels.

Venture capital funds can provide the entrepreneur with larger amounts of financing, from €0.5m to several tens of millions of euros, if the project has very high development potential.

Some industrial groups have created internal investment funds (or joint funds for several groups in the same industry sector) with the dual aim of financing innovation and keeping a strategic watch on developments in their sector, such as Novartis, Intel, Orange or Schneider. In such cases, we refer to corporate venture.

Raising funds on the stock market by listing a company is a real possibility for companies, especially in the high-tech, Internet, biotech and medtech sectors.

Each type of investor plays a role at the different stages of the development of the young company:

image

2. Investors in debt

There are practically no investors in debt prepared to finance start-ups and, as we saw in Section 40.2, it is not in the interest of the entrepreneur to take out debt until he has demonstrated the validity of his business model.

It is only if the start-up uses or generates assets that have a value that is independent of its operations (vehicles, real estate, business) that it can make use of leasing (see Chapter 21). If it generates sales, it can finance its working capital using discounting or factoring (Chapter 21 ). An unallocated bank loan (i.e. financing the company in general rather than specific assets) will only be found if the entrepreneur provides guarantees with a value that is independent of his project. In some countries, state bodies can guarantee loans granted by commercial banks to start-ups.

3. Other sources of financing

These are more marginal and are often a form of supplementary financing, like subsidies, repayable advances in the event of success, honour loans granted by associations or foundations, competitions for start-ups organised by local authorities or foundations, grants by local authorities, research tax credits for companies carrying out R&D, etc.

Section 40.4 The organisation of relationships between the entrepreneur 
and the financial investors

The relationship over time between the investors and the entrepreneur(s) is set out in the shareholders’ agreement signed at the time when the funds are handed over. See ­Chapter 41 for standard clauses of a shareholders’ agreement which are not used in the case of a start-up.

A shareholders’ agreement is the result of a negotiation and sets out the balance between demand for and supply of venture capital at the time that it is signed. It also reflects the power of attraction of a given start-up project or of a given entrepreneur.

1. Clauses binding the founder-managers

Any investor in a start-up will tell you that the main motivation behind his investment is the quality of the founding team. Accordingly, it is not surprising that investors set, as a condition for investing, the condition that the managers commit themselves fully and over the long term to this adventure. We also find clauses preventing the founders from holding other positions in other companies or from selling their shares during a certain period (lock-up); clauses that make provision for the loss of their shares and other incentives if they leave the company before a certain period (vesting), along with agreements not to compete; and clauses that give the company the intellectual property rights created by the founders.

Over and above the shareholders’ agreement, we also see arrangements that create incentives for the founding managers, in such a way that even if they are heavily diluted by several capital increases, they remain highly motivated – stock options, call options, subscription warrants, etc.

2. Clauses that are the consequence of goodwill being paid at the start

If goodwill was paid at the start, the investors will want to prevent the founders from selling the young company too soon, on the basis of a valuation that enables them to recover only a part of their investment while the founders could make a comfortable capital gain (see Exercise 2 for an illustration). In order to avoid this situation, provision can be made that the income from the sale of the company goes first to the investors, in the amount of their investment (sometimes capitalised using a minimum rate of return), and is then shared out between investors and founders whose interests are then aligned.

Similarly the investors will insist on a ratchet clause, intended to protect them in the event that, during subsequent financing rounds, new shares are issued at a lower price than the price that they paid. You may find it surprising that venture capitalists seek to avoid or limit a loss when they invest on the riskiest segment of companies. This is only the flip side of what the entrepreneur wants, i.e. for the investors to pay for goodwill before the relevance of the concept and the viability of the business model had been proved.

It is difficult for an entrepreneur, who has succeeded in getting goodwill out of the investors, to reject such a clause, which will only be applied if the valuation that he has defended turns out to be excessive. The investor will rightly query his confidence in his valuation.

If the ratchet mechanism is implemented, the company will issue additional new shares to the investors at a symbolic price, so that they hold as many shares as if they had subscribed to the previous capital increase at the price of the capital increase under way. If it is fully applied (it can come with conditions that soften the application), it often results in the founders being heavily diluted, which then raises the issue of their motivation. This is why a new investor may require that this clause only be partially exercised by the investors from the previous round. An example is provided in Exercise 4.

A pay-to-play clause may limit the exercise of the ratchet clause to investors subscribing the new round of fundraising.

3. Clauses related to the liquidity of the investment

There are different clauses that seek to ensure that investors are able to sell their stakes in such a way as to reap the benefits of their investment. This is, moreover, one of the stated aims of an investment fund, which itself is often required, at the latest when it is wound up, to distribute the income from its investments.

Accordingly, investors can get the founders to agree to the sale of all of their shares in the company after a certain period, if the majority shareholders have not provided them with sufficient liquidity for their investment. A sale of the majority of the shares will enable them to get a better price than if they had only offered a (generally) minority stake for sale (see Chapter 31). Having said that, implementing this clause is very difficult because if the entrepreneur doesn’t want to sell despite having pledged to, he will not be very convincing when trying to get a buyer to make an offer.

Very often, the investors want to be able to sell all or part of their shares before the founders sell theirs, in the case of an IPO or a planned sale by the founders. If they are not given this priority, they may ask for the option to sell the same percentage of their stakes as the founders in the event of a sale (tag-along clause) or if there is a change in control over the company. A drag-along clause is nearly always introduced to provide a group of majority shareholders representing a given percentage of the capital with the option of forcing the other shareholders to sell their shares on the same terms as those offered to them by a buyer. Such a buyer may condition its offer on obtaining all of the capital and in this case, the majority shareholders will not want to have to cope with being blackmailed by a minority shareholder.

4. Clauses related to control by investors over company decisions

Demonstrating that they are keen to be more closely associated with the running of the young company and the risks that they are prepared to take, investors often require a level of information that is accurate, wide, frequent and adapted to the situation and the activity of the company.

Additionally, provision can be made that certain important decisions (such as modification of the articles of association, hiring of key staff, modification of the company’s strategy, acquisitions or disposals, etc.) can only be taken by a qualified majority, giving investors a de facto veto right.

Section 40.5 The financial management of a start-up

There are two principles that underlie the financial management of a start-up: keep a very close watch on the cash position and plan the next round of fundraising very well.

Cash on the assets side of the balance sheet, when there is no monthly cash income, measures the number of months of survival of the company before it is obliged to carry out another round of fundraising. This is called the burn rate. How much time does the company have to reach its next step or to shift from plan A, which has failed, to plan B, which has to be invented and implemented?

Unless the existing shareholders have the financial resources necessary to cover the financing of the next round and agree to do so, the manager of the start-up would be well advised to launch the process of looking for new investors six to nine months at the latest before his cash runs out. Since a round of financing most often covers requirements for the next 12 to 24 months, it comes around quickly. The search for new investors and the conviction needed are very time-consuming, especially for a manager who doesn’t have a financial director to help him.

Launching a new round of financing early is often too early: the company has not yet shown that it has reached a new step in its development since the last round of fundraising. Waiting until later means taking the risk of running out of cash during the final phase of negotiations with investors, at the risk of having to admit defeat.

Section 40.6 The particularities of valuing young companies

It is obviously very difficult to value a company that has not yet proved the relevance of its business model, which has a high probability of disappearing in the short term, and for which projections are so uncertain that sometimes one might ask whether they’re worth the paper they’re printed on.

One might thus think that the real option method seen in Chapter 30 is particularly well suited to valuing the young company because the way it works in stages is very similar to the successive stages of development that the young company must go through. In practice, this is not the case at all and it is practically never used in this field. Drawing up a business plan that makes sense and that is also optimistic is complicated, but asking an entrepreneur to draft different versions, including one which leads to bankruptcy, is counter-productive. Do we really want to demoralise and discourage the entrepreneur at a time when he needs to be boosted in order to meet the challenges he is facing? Of course not!

Valuation by discounting free cash flows (see Chapter 31) is not very widespread, even though the basic raw material for this method, the business plan, is often available. In order to avoid using this method, investors raise the pretext of the extreme volatility of business plans for start-ups, given that there is very little chance of new companies sticking to them and the fact that they reflect the best of possible outcomes, rather than the most likely. Conceptually, though, there is nothing that prevents this method from being used by looking at the probabilities of several projections.

As for the multiples method (see Chapter 31), given that its use is conditional on the existence of comparable listed companies, it is de facto unusable for valuing very young companies, which are all different from each other and very rarely listed on the stock exchange. Additionally, the fact that most of them have negative earnings would render the operation impossible.

Venture capital professionals have developed a method that is rather pragmatic and efficient, if a bit simplistic, which they use for valuing young companies, known as the venture capital method. As you will see, it is a hybrid of the multiples and discounted free cash flows methods.

We start by estimating the probable value of the company’s equity in four to seven years, when it will have reached a level of maturity to allow it either to be listed or to be sold to a third party, most frequently an industrial player. This timeframe corresponds to the exit of the venture capitalist and to the fact that the company is no longer a start-up (hopefully) but a developing company. This future value is calculated by applying the P/E ratio today, observed for companies in this stage of development, to net earnings forecast in the business plan at this period (for more on the P/E ratio, see Chapter 22 ); for example, 15 times net earnings of €8m, i.e. €120m.

Secondly, and in order to determine the present value, this future value of equity is discounted to a value today, using a high discount rate since the company is at an early stage of its development.3 The rates most frequently observed are as follows:

Phase Discount rate Equivalent to multiply the investment by Over … years
Start-up 60% 11.2 7
First round 50%  7.6 5
Second round 40%  3.8 4
Third round 30%  2.2 3
Before IPO 20%  1.4 2

So, for a pure start-up, with a business plan period of seven years, the value today of the equity is €120m/(1 + 60%) = €4.5m. This result is post-money as it assumes that the company has found the financing necessary for developing its activities. If today it needs €1.5m, the value of its equity is €4.5 - €1.5 = €3m. The investor who contributes these funds gets 33% (1.5/4.5) of the company’s equity. If the company’s capital is made up of a million shares, he will have to be issued with 500 000 new shares at a unit price of €3.

The reader will not be surprised at how high these rates are and he or she will have difficulty reconciling them with those provided by the CAPM in Chapter 19 or with the average IRR obtained by venture capital funds (between 15% and 30%), and rightly so, as they are of another order.

If they appear to be high, it is because they integrate the risk of the start-up going bankrupt. They are applied to a level of earnings that does not correspond to the average of different scenarios, but to a business plan that reflects, by construction, the success of the company. However, over a five-year period, one out of two companies will have disappeared and out of those that are left, a large number will not have lived up to expectations. Accordingly, the high discount rate takes into consideration the risk that the projections will turn out to have been too optimistic, which is most often the case.

The rate of return required by the investor also takes into account the illiquidity of the investment (see Chapter 19) and also remunerates the non-financial contributions by the investor (operational or managerial advice, network access, etc.).

Our rather simplistic model assumes that a single round of fundraising was necessary before reaching a stage where the company could be sold or listed. Let’s assume that there is a second round of fundraising of €5m in year three. At the time of this fundraising, the post-money valuation of the company made by the second investor, who would require a rate of return of 40%, would be: €120m/(1 + 40%)4 = €31.2m, which results in a percentage for this second investor of 5/31.2 = 16%.

The terminal value remains €120m since it assumes, if it is to be achieved, a second round of fundraising. Our first investor will be diluted by this second capital increase. Accordingly, he thus needs to hold a larger part of the capital after his contribution of funds, to set off the dilutive effect of the second capital increase and to obtain his rate of return of 60%. This stake is calculated as follows: 33%/(1 – 16%) = 39.3%. Instead of 500 000 new shares issued in the first round of financing, which would give 33% of the share capital to our first investor, 647 000 new shares4 should be issued. Since the latter is still bringing €1.5m to the table, this means that the shares are issued at a unit price of €1.5m/0.647m = €2.32, and no longer €3, when there is no subsequent dilution.

If, in seven years’ time, the value of the company’s equity capital is indeed €120m, our first investor, who took a 39.3% stake in the capital when the company was started up, which was then diluted three years later to 33%, can sell his stake for €40m. For an investment of €1.5m made seven years earlier, he has, in fact, obtained his rate of return of 60% per year. As for the second investor who invested €5m in the third year and who got 16% of the capital, the sale of these shares in year seven for 16% × €120m = €19.2m gives him his required rate of return of 40% per year.

The venture capital method is also used backwards. A purchase price of shares is offered to you and you want to find the implicit rate of return of this investment if the business plan is met and given your estimation of the final value of the company. You then compare it with the minimum rate of return that you estimate is justified, given the risk of the investment, in order to take your investment decision. Here we find the IRR of Chapter 17.

Section 40.7 Example inspired by a real case: Example.com

The simplified joint stock company Example SAS was set up eight years ago by two friends with the aim of developing a new-generation social network around the website Example.com, which offers a very powerful yet simple tool based on complex algorithms which had required years of development.

The first round of financing brought together friends and business angels, who contributed €0.6m. Dilution of capital was only 17% thanks to a high level of goodwill, since the managers only contributed €0.1m. This situation is explained by the following: in addition to the quality of the entrepreneurs, algorithms had been pre-developed, giving a clear idea of the development potential, a worldwide market was being targeted and ambitions were high, and finally the entrepreneurs had declined to be paid a salary during the first two years.

On the basis of the launch of the alpha version of the site Example.com one year later, which demonstrated that the algorithms were correct, Example SAS carried out a second capital increase of €1m, which was followed by the original investors, at a share price that was 50% higher. Because Example SAS was keen to speed up its development, which would involve increasing its losses and its working capital requirements, it made the choice to carry out this capital increase relatively quickly, even though its cash position would have enabled it to defer it for a year. Sometimes it is better to stand fast than to run and to avoid financial stress that could have operational consequences. For example, it is easier to recruit a good IT developer when your cash can cover 24 months of cash burn rather than three!

A third capital increase was carried out one year later, which raised €1.9m. Five new investors (mainly business angels) participated in this capital increase alongside some of the original investors. The launch of the beta version of the site and the development of the community, which was growing at 30% per month, played a determining role in the success of this operation.

Example preferred to wait until the last moment to carry out its fourth capital increase, which at €6m was a large one, nearly double the equity raised previously. When it was finalised, Example SAS only had three months of cash left! The iPad version had just been launched with success and the community had reached 460 000 members, which works out at a monthly growth rate of 18%. The share price could thus be maximised: +40% compared with the capital increase carried out 18 months previously, resulting in dilution of only 30%, but growth in book equity of 1250%. This should be the last capital increase before profits start rolling in.

The funds raised enabled Example to test two revenue models, premium and advertising, which had been partially successful but which failed to lead to equilibrium. Four years later, a final capital increase of €2m was subscribed, at a price per share that was 60% lower than that of the previous capital increase. The challenge for Example will be to break into two new markets that are seen as buoyant markets – the university and the media markets. This is a shift that will require a resizing of the company and a change in profile for a large portion of its workforce. Initial results are promising.

Today, there are 3 million Example users worldwide, with 50% in the USA, 25% in France, and the rest of the world accounting for the last quarter. The two founders, who had brought 1% of the funds raised, hold 35% of the shares and the investors, who brought 99% of the funds, hold 65% of the shares.

Summary

 

Questions

 

Exercises

 

Answers

 

 

Notes


Bibliography

..................Content has been hidden....................

You can't read the all page of ebook, please click here login for view all page.
Reset
3.21.159.82